Dynamic consequences of the 1997 NFC Award: provincial social sector expenditures.
Sabir, Muhammad
INTRODUCTION
An adequate provision of social services is a concurrent function
of federal and provincial governments. However, in Pakistan, the
financing and delivery of social services largely prevails in the hands
of provinces and major sources of revenues in the hand of federal
government, which creates vertical imbalances. Federal transfers are the
mechanism for their correction and these are constituted through the
National Finance Commission (NFC) Awards. The last NFC Award was
constituted in 1997 and it changed both the size of divisible pool and
the share of federal and provincial governments in the divisible pool.
The changed provincial shares have based on higher tax revenue
collection, which was not materialised during the following four-year
period after the award. Therefore, provincial governments experienced
the shortfall in the federal transfers during last four years after the
award and have experienced a lower growth in transfers than projected in
1997 NFC Award. This is in contrast with the provincial experience
during 1991 NFC Award, in which provinces had received higher revenue
transfers from federal government than projected.
The shortfall in federal transfers put uneasy pressure on
provincial finances and left provincial governments with three options:
increase efforts to mobilise higher revenues from own resources,
curtailed expenditure and finally increase borrowing. On the one hand,
in the presence of poor macroeconomic performance and persistence
drought especially in the last year minimises the scope of increase in
efforts to mobilise higher revenues from provincial own resources
minimised the scope for first option. On the other hand, to protect some
heads of public expenditures, 1997 NFC Award bifurcates public
expenditure into priority and non-priority expenditures. Current
expenditure on social sector, debt servicing and development expenditure
were called priority expenditures while the remaining current
expenditures included expenditures on law and order, community services,
general administration were called non-priority expenditures. The idea
of this bifurcation is to protect priority expenditures in case of any
shortfall in revenues. Four-year experiences demonstrate that
debt-servicing obligations were fulfilled by provinces and the shortfall
in revenues generally translated on development expenditures. However,
ambiguity occurs in case of social sector expenditure that leads to the
following question. Have social sector expenditures been protected
during the four period or not? Alternatively, what is the impact of 1997
NFC Award on social sector expenditures?
The estimated expenditure response of provincial governments after
the 1997 NFC Award is the focus of this paper. Estimating responsiveness
raises an interesting empirical question, which has been largely ignored
in intergovernmental transfers literature. The question is whether the
expenditure response to changes in the design of intergovernmental
transfers is symmetrical. In other words, is its magnitude the same for
both social services expenditures and other expenditures? Previous
empirical studies have not distinguished whether the social services
expenditures or other expenditures affected largely in case of any
increase or decrease in the federal transfers to provinces. This paper
hypothesises that provincial responses in case of change in design of
federal transfers are asymmetric. Asymmetric provincial expenditure
response may occur for a number of reasons. Primarily, expenditure on
social services is generally considered as a source of poverty
reduction. Second, expenditure on social services especially at primary
or basic level is considered to be subject to high external benefits.
Third, social services expenditures are the focal point of Social Action
Plan (SAP I&II). Finally, one of the main objectives of the 1997 NFC
Award was to protect priority expenditures including social services
expenditures. The 1997 NFC Award offers a good opportunity to test
asymmetric response hypothesis for provincial government expenditures.
The next section provides descriptive statistics on provincial
expenditure trends, a comparative structure of provincial resources
before and after 1997 NFC Award. Then a micro-theoretic model of
provincial expenditures is developed and estimated. Finally, some
concluding comments are offered.
COMPARATIVE GROWTH IN PROVINCIAL REVENUES AND EXPENDITURES
This section offers summery statistics of comparative growth rates on provincial revenues and expenditures before and after 1997 NFC Award.
It reports a set of combined aggregated descriptive statistics of four
provinces. (1)
Provincial revenues can be divided into two broad categories; own
revenues receipts and federal transfers and grants. Table 1 shows that
growth in provincial general revenues declined after the 1997 NFC Award.
This is the outcome of both change in design of federal transfers to the
provinces and low tax collection. The overall decline in the growth of
provincial general revenue receipts is more than 9 percent, which is
largely the outcome of sizeable decline (over 10 percent) in federal
transfers. Federal tax assignment experienced the largest decline in
growth of over 19 percent. After 1997 NFC Award growth in provincial tax
receipts declined by 4 percent due to poor performance in agriculture
sector mainly because of drought. However, increase in growth rate of
federal development and non-development grants diluted the impact of
lower growth in other sources of revenues.
The provincial expenditures growth rates portray an interesting
picture. According to which without exception each and every component
of provincial current expenditures experienced slow growth after 1997
NFC Award. This is the outcome of the government policy to reduce public
expenditure at all levels, coupled with low growth in general revenue
receipts. Another interesting aspect is the higher growth in other
services related expenditures component of development expenditures.
The Key Elements of the 1997 NFC Award
1997 NFC Award was innovative in nature and changed
intergovernmental fiscal transfers mechanism at large scale. This award
differed with the previous awards in many ways and introduced some new
ideas in the design of federal transfers. First and the foremost, this
award recognised the common resource pool problem faced by Pakistan. The
recognition of common pool problem is new in the literature of fiscal
federalism and also highlighted by De Mello and Luiz (2000) in the
context of other developing countries. This recognition in Pakistan led
toward the formation of the National Resource Picture, which was based
on the projected values of all sources of revenues included tax, non-tax
revenues and borrowing of both tiers of governments.
The other major step, which we already highlighted, is bifurcation
of expenditures into priority and non-priority expenditures. Priority
expenditures contained expenditures on defence, debt servicing, social
services and development. The reaming head of expenditures including
economic services, community services, general administration etc. were
categorised as non-priority expenditures. The basic idea behind this
bifurcation was to protect priority expenditures in case of any decline
in resources, without damaging the national interest of the country.
The estimation of provincial shares was based on a four step
methodology. As the first step, provincial expenditures were projected
till 2001-02, based on the benchmarks chosen by provincial
representatives. Secondly, national resources were projected for the
same period. Based on these projections, provincial share was then
estimated, which is equivalent to all provincial current expenditures
and fifty percent of development expenditures. Finally, to address
horizontal imbalances constitutional subventions were allocated to
relatively backward provinces NWFP and Balochistan.
Table 2 highlights the change in provincial share in divisible pool
since the separation of East Pakistan. Table 2 conveyed that 1991, NFC
Award increased the share of provinces by including federal excise duty
on tobacco and sugar. Another, important point which emerges from Table
2 is that provinces had gotten 80 percent of two major federal taxes
"Sales Tax" and "Income and Corporation Tax", which
were the focus of tax and tariff reforms initiated in early 90s.
In contrast, 1997 NFC Award included all federal taxes in divisible
pool and decreased the provincial share from 80 percent to 37.5 percent,
which is less than half of previous share. This change was based on
optimistic targets based on certain macroeconomic projections like GDP growth, inflation etc. and higher expectations from tax and tariff
reforms. However, during the four-year period these expectations did not
materialise due to many external and internal shocks, which largely
affected federal tax collection.
Table 3 highlights both the effect of these external and internal
shocks, and the impact of change in design on real federal transfers to
the provinces. The projected amount of federal transfers and
constitutional subventions at constant rupees of 1980-81 were Rs 40.9
billion but in reality, it turned out only Rs 32.3 billion. The
shortfall increased with passage of time and reached its peek during
2000-01, in which projected, real transfers were Rs 55.6 billion but
provinces received only Rs 38.3 billion.
To quantify the impact of change in design of federal transfers we
projected federal transfers by using the formula of 1991 NFC Award based
on projected revenues of 1997 NFC Award. Table 3 also reveals that if
the pervious formula of 1991 NFC Award were to continue then provinces
would get higher revenues as a result of higher share of buyont taxes.
Similarly, the impact of change in design also increased in the later
years.
Table 4 presents the two types of descriptive statistics. First, it
highlights the shortfall, which occurred in federal transfers due to low
tax collection. This is the difference between actual federal transfers.
The shortfall increased after the nuclear blast and reached its peak
during 2000-01. In real terms the impact of low tax collection increased
from Rs 8.6 billion to Rs 17.3 billion more than double just in a
four-year period. The impact of low tax collection was dominated on
divisible pool transfers.
Second, Table 4 highlights the impact of 1997, NFC Award on federal
transfers. This is the difference between 1997 NFC Award projected
federal transfers to the provinces and estimated transfers based on
projected revenues of 1997 NFC Award by using the formula of the 1991
NFC Award. According to this, provinces can get Rs 3.8 billion more than
actual transfers in real terms during 1997-98 which further increased to
over Rs 10 billion during the year 2000-01. This large difference
occurred due to higher growth in sales tax and, income and corporate
tax. Consequently, the provinces were largely affected by the low tax
collection as compared to change in design.
DYNAMIC CONSEQUENCES OF THE 1997 NFC AWARD
The treatment of the 1997, NFC Award to this point has been
explicitly based on descriptive statistics. Although these statistics
provided a broad picture of the implications of 1997 NFC Award but this
broad picture is incomplete without any empirical findings.
Unfortunately, we do not have many empirical studies that bring to bear
on the matter of intergovernmental transfers. There is a substantial
descriptive literature addressing the many aspects of the
intergovernmental transfers with respect to fiscal competition among the
sub-national governments [Musgrave (1997)], market incentive of
federalism [Qian and Weingast (1997)], intergovernmental transfers and
deadweight losses in tax system [Smart (1996)], and finally coordination
failure [De Mello and Luiz (2000)]. However, this body of work really
does not shed much light on the normative question of dynamic
consequences of any change in designed mechanism of intergovernmental
transfers on provincial finances.
In an interesting study that is of relevance here, Ghaus and Pasha
(1996) find evidences of strategic interaction in intergovernmental
transfers and provincial expenditures. They developed an econometric
model for Pakistan to evaluate the consequence of the NFC Award 1991.
The model thoroughly studied the fiscal relationship between the
provinces and federal government and, highlighted the key features of
provincial finances. However, their study did not bifurcate expenditure
and just estimated the overall impact of transfers on total expenditure.
In contrast, this paper has developed a model to analyse the impact of
intergovernmental transfers and other federal grants on social sector
expenditures.
Methodological Framework
The methodological framework based on the assumption that
politicians/officials want to maximise the utility of the typical
consumer (median consumer) in their jurisdiction subject to budget
constraint. For the sake of simplicity, consumption basket of typical
citizen (median consumer) can be divided into two broad groups; publicly
provided goods and services (A), and privately provided goods and
services (B). Utility was assumed to depend positively on the quantity
of goods and services provided by the provincial government (A) and on
the level of consumption of private goods (B).
U = U ([Q.sub.A], [Q.sub.B])
The goods and services provided by provincial government can be
split into social services and, other goods and services
U = U ([Q.sub.S], [Q.sub.O], [Q.sub.B])
The quantity of demand of each good and services depends upon the
expenditure on it. In the case of private goods and services,
expenditure would be equal to real per capita disposable income of the
consumer or (y - R), where y is the real per capita income and R is the
real per capita revenue received by the government. Similarly, in the
case of publicly provided goods and services, expenditure would be equal
to provincial expenditure on social services (SE) and other services
(OE). Therefore, the utility function can be rewritten as
U = U (SE, OE, Y - R) ... (1)
R includes both tax and non-tax revenues, while SE and OE consist
of both recurring, and development expenditures on publically provided
social services and other services. We exclude the payments for
servicing of debt, as these do not benefited citizens directly through
provision of services.
The sources of revenues for provincial governments except its own
revenues are federal transfers from divisible pool, development and
non-development grants and borrowings. Therefore, the budget constraint
of the provincial government (at current prices) can be expressed as:
[p.sub.2](SE + OE) = [p.sub.1]R + [bar.T] + [bar.B] + G ... (2)
Where Y = real per capita income.
R = real per capita provincial revenue (include both tax and
non-tax revenues).
SE = real per capita social sector expenditures (both recurring and
development).
OE = real per capita other expenditures (both recurring and
development).
[P.sub.1] = General Price Level (CPI).
[P.sub.2] = price index of public expenditure.
T = per capita total intergovernmental transfers.
B = per capita borrowing by the provincial government.
G consisted of two types of grants from federal government to
provincial governments. These are lump sum grants (heavily consists of
development grants) and deficit grant (heavily consists of
non-development and non-obligatory grants). Therefore, by definition,
total flow of grants was given as:
G = [G.sub.O] + m[[p.sub.2](SE + OE) - [p.sub.1]R - [bar.T] -
[G.sub.O]],0 [??] m [??] 1 ... (3)
Where m = proportion of the revenue deficit financed by deficit
grants.
Deficit grant was played a very significant role in the provincial
finances before 1991 but after that, this option was curtailed in the
1991 NFC Award. However, lump sum grants are still provided to the
provinces for their development projects. Substituting (3) into (2) we
obtain,
[p.sub.2](SE + OE) = [p.sub.1]R + [bar.T] + [[bar.G].sub.O] +
[G.sub.D] + [bar.B] ... (4)
After addition of ply on both sides of the equation (4) budget
constraint can be written as:
[P.sub.1](Y - R) + [p.sub.2]SSE + [p.sub.2]OSE = [p.sub.1]Y +
[bar.T] + [[bar.G].sub.O] + [G.sub.D] + [bar.B] ... (5)
Based on the above set of equations, a utility maximisation problem
can be set up as follows:
l(R, SE, OE, [lambda]) = U(Y - R, SE, OE) + [lambda][I -
[p.sub.1](Y - R) - [p.sub.2] (SE + OE)] ... (6)
Where I = [P.sub.1] Y + T + [G.sub.O] + [G.sub.D] + B
The first order conditions are as follows:
[partial derivative]l/[partial derivative]R = - [partial
derivative]U/[partial derivative](Y - R) + [lambda][p.sub.1] = 0 ... (7)
[partial derivative]l/[partial derivative]SE = [partial
derivative]U/[partial derivative]SE - [lambda][p.sub.2] = 0 ... (8)
[partial derivative]/[partial derivative]OE - [partial
derivative]U/[partial derivative]OE - [lambda][p.sub.2] = 0 ... (9)
[partial derivative]l/[partial derivative][lambda] = I -
[p.sub.1](Y - R) - [p.sub.2](SE + OE) = 0 ... (10)
The above derivation based on micro-theoretic approach provides the
information on the signs of partial derivatives of the function, but it
needs an explicit utility function for estimation purposes. In the
analysis of consumer behaviour, many utility functions were used and
among them, we chose the analogous Stone-Geary utility function for the
estimation of the model.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)
The Stone-Geary utility function has particular advantages over
other functions. The most important advantage of the Stone-Geary utility
function is the inclusion of [y.sub.0], [SE.sub.0], and [OE.sub.0],
which are "minimum survival bundles" and ensure the
subsistence level of consumer demand for public and private goods and
services. Substituting the derivatives of utility function into (7), (8)
and (0) respectively, yields
[P.sub.1](Y - R) = (1 - [[alpha].sub.1] -
[[alpha].sub.2])U/[lambda] + [P.sub.1][Y.sub.0] ... (12)
[P.sub.2]SE = [[alpha].sub.1]U/[lambda] + [P.sub.2][SE.sub.0] ...
(13)
[P.sub.2]OE = [[alpha].sub.2]U/[lambda] + [P.sub.2][OE.sub.0] ...
(14)
Substituting the value of [p.sub.2]SE, [p.sub.2]E and
[p.sub.1](Y-R) from (12), (13) and (14) into (5) we obtained
U/[lambda] = [p.sub.1] (Y - [Y.sub.0] + T + [G.sub.0] + B/1-m -
[p.sub.2](S[E.sub.0] + O[E.sub.0]) ... ... (15)
Minimum bundle of income [y.sub.0] was assumed to be partly
constant and partly rises with income y.
[y.sub.0] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1] y
Therefore, Equation 19 can be written as:
U/[lambda] = (1 - a.sub.1])[p.sub.1] Y-[a.sub.o][p.sub.1] + T
[G.sub.0] + B/1-m - [P.sub.2] = (S[E.sub.0] + O[E.sub.0]) ... ... (16)
After substituting the value from equation 16 into 12, 13 and 14,
we finally have the following system of equation for estimation:
[p.sub.2] SE = [[alpha].sub.1](1 - [[alpha].sub.1])[p.sub.1] Y -
[[alpha].sub.0][[alpha].sub.1][p.sub.1 + [[alpha].sub.1](T + [G.sub.0])]
+ [[alpha].sub.1]/1-m B +
{(1 - [[alpha].sub.1])S[E.sub.0] - [[alpha].sub.1]
O[E.sub.0]}[p.sub.2] ... ... ... ... (17)
[p.sub.2] OE = [[alpha].sub.2](1 - [[alpha].sub.1])[p.sub.1] Y -
[[alpha].sub.0][[alpha].sub.2] [[alpha].sub.1] [p.sub.1 +
[[alpha].sub.2](T + [G.sub.0])] + [[alpha].sub.2]/1-m B +
{(1 - [[alpha].sub.2])O[E.sub.0] - [[alpha].sub.2]
S[E.sub.0]}[p.sub.2] ... ... ... ... (18)
[p.sub.1]R = ([[alpha].sub.1] + [[alpha.sub.2])(1 -
[[alpha].sub.1])[p.sub.1]Y + [[alpha].sub.0]([[alpha].sub.1] +
[[alpha].sub.2])[p.sub.1] - (1 - [[alpha].sub.1] - [[alpha].sub.2])(T +
[G.sub.0]) -
(1 - [[alpha].sub.1] - [[alpha].sub.2)/1-m B + (1 - [[alpha].sub.1]
- [[alpha].sub.2])(S[E.sub.0] + O[E.sub.0])[p.sub.2] ... ... (19)
Equations (17) and (18) are the desired expenditure equations.
Divided both equations by [p.sub.2] we have following functional form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (20)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)
After 1991 NFC Award value of m became zero
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (22)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (23)
The value of D91 is 1 prior to 1991 NFC Award otherwise zero and,
value of D92 is 1 after the 1991 NFC Award, other wise zero
Due to the limitation on availability of the basic data (for
example, the data of provincial gross domestic products are not
available), we are unable to conduct a province wise analysis.
Therefore, the above model has been estimated for the four provincial
governments combined. Annual budget statements of the individual
provinces have been used to generate the aggregate database for key
provincial budgetary magnitudes.
Equations (22) and (23) were estimated for the period, 1972-73 to
2000-01. Results of estimation are as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
All estimated signs are consistent with the developed model. Each
coefficient, except the income (y) in other expenditure (OE) equation is
significantly different from zero at a five-percent significance level
with a t-test. The value of adjusted R2 indicates that the first model
explain almost 98 percent variation and second model explain almost 84
percent variation in provincial social and other expenditures. The
estimated coefficients of Equations 22 and 23 can be used to draw the
inferences about the behaviour of provincial governments.
According to the estimates of Equations 22 and 23, impact of any
increase or decrease in federal transfers is relatively higher on social
sector expenditures. One rupee increase or decrease in either real
federal transfers or lump sum grants or borrowing can affect 18.51
paisas to social sector expenditures and 16.35 paisas to other
provincial expenditures in real terms. In general, these estimated
coefficients of federal transfers reflect that almost 35 percent real
provincial service related expenditures depends on federal transfers.
The remaining 65 percent of federal transfers are translated on either
debt servicing or reduction in efforts of resource mobilisation. The
fact of low resource mobilisation efforts at provincial level is also
reflected from the coefficient of income, which has the meager values of
0.026 and 0.015. In other words, one rupee increase in income translated
to less than three paisas in real social sector expenditures and less
than two paisas in other services related expenditures.
The NFC Award 1991 truncated the option of deficit grants for the
provincial budget deficits, which was previously available and fully
utilised by the provinces. This truncation of deficit grants reflected
through the behaviour of the provinces in the utilisation of the debt.
To capture the effect of truncation of deficit grants on utilisation of
debt, we used two interactive dummies D91 (one for 1972-73 to 1990-91
otherwise zero) and D92 (zero for 1972-73 to 1990-91 otherwise one). The
coefficient of debt interacted with D91 reveals that until 1991 a large
component of debt translated into provincial expenditures, in the areas
of either expenditure on social services or other services. However,
elimination of deficit grants changed the provincial behaviour after
1991. Provinces used borrowings in a way similar to federal transfers
and grants. This change is largely affected other services related
expenditures. The coefficient of debt reduced after 1991 from 0.3266 to
0.1851 in social services and from 0.4215 to 0.1635 in other services
related expenditures. This change clearly demonstrates that the
provincial government started utilisation of debt to finance debt
servicing.
Finally, inflation negatively affects real social and other
expenditures largely. The impact of inflation is higher on other
expenditures as compared to social services. The other contributors in
growth of provincial expenditures are captured through DUM12 and DUM23
both are positive and significant. In the growth of social sector
expenditures, major contributors were the five-point programme, Social
Action Programme-I, while drought affected social sector expenditure
negatively. In contrast, other expenditures were higher during 1992-93
and 2000-01. 1992-93 was the base year for SAP-I and 2000-01 is the
drought year. During drought year provinces, spend more on social safety
nets and other schemes of water managements.
Given the above result, we are now in the position to conduct
comparative analysis on the dynamic consequences of 1997 NFC Award on
provincial real social sector and other services related expenditures.
Table 5 provides the estimated shortfall in provincial real social and
other services related expenditures due to shortfall in federal
transfers. The estimates shows that the impact of low tax collection is
greater on real social sector expenditures as compared to other services
related expenditures. In 1997-98, low tax collections dented social
services expenditures by more than Rs 1.5 billion and its impact further
increased to over Rs 3.2 billion in 2000-01. In contrast, the impact of
change in design was not significant in 1997-98. However, in 2000-01
impact of change in design also increased to Rs. 1.8 billion.
Other services related expenditures also experienced a greater
decline in later years. Decline in other real provincial services
related expenditures is lower than real social sector expenditures. In
1997-98 the combined impact of low tax collection and change in design
on other expenditures was around Rs 2 billion, which rose to
approximately Rs 4.5 billion in 2000-01.
However, a comparison of social services and other expenditures in
absolute terms did not portray the true picture. Therefore, we estimated
relative impact of these changes on social and other services related
expenditures. Table 6 highlights the relative comparative statistics,
which clearly shows the impact of low tax collection and change in
design is much greater on social services expenditures.
According to the estimates of Table 6 combined impact of low tax
collection and change in design was around 15 percent in 1997-98 that
further increased to 37.5 percent in 2000-01. However, the combined
impact of low tax collection and change in design on other services
related expenditures was roughly 12 percent in 1997-98 that increased to
roughly 21 percent in 2000-01.
CONCLUSION
In contrast to the objective of the 1997 NFC Award, bulk of the
shortfall in federal transfers to provinces translated into real social
sector expenditures, which experienced slow growth and a large deviation
from the trend. According to the estimates based on micro-theoretic
model, any decline in real transfers largely affected real social sector
expenditures. In a nut shell, bifurcation of public expenditure into
priority and non-priority expenditures in the 1997 NFC Award failed to
protect social sector expenditures.
REFERENCES
De Mello Jr., and R. Luiz (2000) Fiscal Decentralisation and
Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations: A Cross-Country Analysis. World
Development 28:2, 365-380.
Ghous, A. F. Aisha (1996) Intergovernemntal Revenue Sharing in
Pakistan. Social Policy and Development Centre. (Research Report No. 8.)
Ghous, A. F. Aisha, and Hafiz A. Pasha (1994) Dynamic Budgetary
Consequences of the 1991 NFC Award. The Pakistan Development Review
33:4, 627-645.
Musgrave, Richard A. (1997) Devolution, Grants, and Fiscal
Competition. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 : 4, 65-72.
Pakistan, Government of (1996) Report of the National Finance
Commission. National Finance Commission, Secretariat. Islamabad.
Qian, Yingy, and Barry R. Weingast (1997) Federalism as a
Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives 11:4, 83-92.
Smart, Michael (1996) Taxation Incentives and Deadweight Loss in a
System of Intergovernmental Transfers. Department of Economics and
Institute for Policy Analysis, University of Toronto, (Working paper
number ut-ecipa-msmart-96-03) July 22.
Comments
The current division of fiscal powers in the Federation of Pakistan
is one of the major causes of weakness in domestic resource mobilisation
efforts. The revenue-sharing arrangements derived from the Government of
India Act 1935 laid down the formula for distribution of revenue from
divisible sources. After independence in 1947 these provisions were
incorporated into successive constitutions, delineating the respective
revenue-raising powers of the federal and provincial governments.
An analysis of revenue sharing arrangements in Pakistan indicates
that the constitutional division of legislative, administrative and
financial powers between the constituent units of the Federation like
many other countries opted in favour of Federal form of Government have
not produced a congenial environment for policymaking on improvement in
relations between the federal and provincial governments. At both levels
of government, groups wielding substantial political and bureaucratic power have influenced policy-making and policy implementation.
The fundamental weakness of 1991 National Finance Commission (NFC)
Award was that it assigned generous revenues to the provincial
governments without properly assessing its implication on domestic
resource mobilisation efforts and financial requirements of the federal
government to meet its constitutional obligations. Thus, implementation
of 1991 Award has created a situation similar to that faced by
Government of India after the promulgation of Government of India Act
1919. Under the 1919 revenue sharing arrangements States share in
divisible pool has created financial imbalance between the Centre and
the State Governments. The increased flow of shared resources to State
Government weakened the Central Government financial position to the
extent that the Central Government had to borrow from the State
Governments, which undermined the Central Government Authority. The
Government of India Act 1921 and subsequently Government of India Act
1935 were to correct the imbalance. The 1991 NFC has created a similar
situation.
Soon after the implementation of 1991 NFC award the situation of
public finance necessitated a fundamental re-examination of the issues
relating to revenue sharing arrangements in manner that the distribution
of revenues between the two levels of government should be to adequately
protect priority expenditures on social services, debt servicing and
defence. It was also necessary to build an incentive environment for
higher resource mobilisation by all levels of government.
The 1997 NFC Award may be seen as an effort to correct the
situation. The Award approach of using the National Resource Picture for
making governments revenue and expenditure projections and deriving
thereby the fiscal transfers to the provinces based on their expenditure
needs which cannot be financed from their own resources was an
improvement over the traditional methodology, which involved projecting
benchmark established both provincial current expenditure and own
receipts.
The 1997 NFC Award ensured that the development expenditure needs
of the provincial governments should be financed partially by divisible
pool transfers. The Award assured provinces source of revenue for
planning their budgets. Thus, the Award enhanced the fiscal autonomy of
the provincial governments.
Comparison of 1097 NFC Award with any award should be made
carefully. There are so many caveats. During the 1997 NFC period
Pakistan economy experienced periods of slow growth and many internal
and external shocks. The analysis of consolidated budget (federal and
provincial) of the period indicates that increase in government revenues
was substantially below the award projections. The shortfall in
government revenues has contributed in sizeable reduction in the
divisible resources to the provinces. As a result, growth in government
expenditure, particularly development expenditure was well below the NFC
projection. Expenditure on social sectors was also influenced because of
the shortfall in resources.
The paper has not concentrated to a single issue. It focuses on
many topics without much clarity. Nevertheless, it provides enough
thinking for discussion and future research on the subject.
Muhammad Aslam Khan
Planning Commission, Government of Pakistan, Islamabad.
(1) Horizontal analysis is beyond the purview of this paper.
(2) DUMI has values 1 for 1985-86, 1.25 for 86-87, 1.5 for 87-88
and 0.75 for 88-89 for five point programme, 0.25 for 1903-04, .40 for
94-95, 0.5 for 95-96 and 0.25 for 96-97 for SAP-I and 0.75 in 2000-01
for drought.
(3) DUM2 has 1 in 1992-93 base year of SAP-1 and 1 in 2000-01 for
drought.
Muhammad Sabir is an Economist at the Social Policy and Development
Centre (SPDC), Karachi.
Author's Note: The author gratefully acknowledges the comments
and suggestions of Dr Hafiz A. Pasha, Director, Regional Bureau for Asia
and Pacific, UNDP, and also the PSDE conference participants, specialty
Qazi M. Alimullah, formerly Secretary, Government of Pakistan, and M.
Aslam Khan of the Planning and Development Division, Government of
Pakistan.
Table 1
Pre- and Post-1997 NFC Award Growth Rate of Revenues and
Expenditures (Aggregate of Four Provinces Combined)
Pre 1997 Post 1997
NFC Award NFC Award Difference
FY 1998
FY 1992 to to FY
FY 1997 2001 In Growth
ACGR (%) ACGR (%) Rates
General Revenue Receipts 17.8 8.7 -9.1
Total Provincial Own Receipts 11.7 9.4 -2.3
Provincial Tax Receipts 13.3 9.3 -4.0
Provincial Non-tax Receipts 9.9 9.4 -0.5
Federal Transfers and Grants * 19.1 8.5 -10.6
Federal Tax Assignment 26.5 7.0 -19.5
Federal Non Development Grants 57.4 62.0 4.6
Federal Development Grants -9.7 5.5 15.2
Current Expenditure 15.6 9.7 -5.9
Debt Servicing 11.1 5.8 -5.2
Service-related Expenditure 16.9 10.5 -6.4
Social Sectors 18.0 5.7 -12.3
Other Sectors 16.0 14.3 -1.8
Development Expenditure 2.0 8.7 6.7
Social Sectors 7.3 -2.9 -10.2
Other Sectors -2.9 20.0 22.9
Source: Various Provincial Annual Budget Statements.
* Included devisable pool transfers, straight transfers and
Profit from Hydroelectricity.
ACGR = Annual Compound Growth Rate.
Table 2
Provincial Share in Federal Taxes
Divisible Pool NFC 1974 NFC 1991 NFC 1997
A. Income Tax and
Corporation Tax 80% 80% 37.5%
B. Other Direct Taxes -- -- 37.5%
C. Sales Tax 80% 80% 37.5%
D. Central Excise Duty 37.5%
--Tobacco -- 80%
--Sugar 80%
E. Import Duties -- -- 37.5
F. Export Duties --
--Cotton 80% 80%
Source: Pakistan (1997).
Table 3
Real Federal Transfers to Provinces
(Rs Million)
1997-98 1998-99
Divisible Pool Transfers
Actuals 25,532 24,992
1997 NFC Award Projections 33,280 36,481
Projections As Per 1991 NFC Award * 38,941 43,304
Straight Transfers **
Actuals 4,986 4,602
1997 NFC Award Projections 5,816 5,992
As Per 1991 NFC Projections 5,816 5,992
Constitutional Subvention
Actuals 1,812 1,904
1997 NFC Award Projections 1,814 1,904
As Per 1991 NFC Projections -- --
Total Transfers
Actuals 32,329 31,498
1997 NFC Award Projections 40,910 44,376
As Per 1991 NFC Projections 44,757 49,296
1999-2000 2000-01
Divisible Pool Transfers
Actuals 27,494 30,111
1997 NFC Award Projections 40,822 46,691
Projections As Per 1991 NFC Award * 49,498 58,920
Straight Transfers **
Actuals 5,733 6,369
1997 NFC Award Projections 6,294 6,742
As Per 1991 NFC Projections 6,294 6,742
Constitutional Subvention
Actuals 1,943 1,836
1997 NFC Award Projections 2,040 2,171
As Per 1991 NFC Projections -- --
Total Transfers
Actuals 35,169 38,315
1997 NFC Award Projections 49,156 55,605
As Per 1991 NFC Projections 55,792 65,662
Source: Estimates based on Report of 1997 NFC Award and Federal
Explanatory Memorandums.
* Projected on the basis of Projected Revenues of 1997 NFC Award.
** Included Profit from Hydroelectricity.
Table 4
Change in Real Federal Transfers to Provinces
(Rs Million)
1997-98 1998-99
Divisible Pool Transfers
Impact of Low Tax Collection -7,748 -11,489
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -5,661 -6,823
Total -13,409 -18,312
Straight Transfers
Impact of Low Tax Collection -831 -1,390
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design 0 0
Total -831 -1,390
Constitutional Subvention
Impact of Low Tax Collection -2 0
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design 1,814 1,904
Total 1,812 1,904
Overall Impact
Impact of Low Tax Collection -8,580 -12,879
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -3,848 -4,919
Total -12,428 -17,798
1999-2000 2000-01
Divisible Pool Transfers
Impact of Low Tax Collection -13,328 -16,581
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -8,676 -12,228
Total -22,004 -28,809
Straight Transfers
Impact of Low Tax Collection -561 -373
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design 0 0
Total -561 -373
Constitutional Subvention
Impact of Low Tax Collection -97 -335
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design 2,040 2,171
Total 1,943 1,836
Overall Impact
Impact of Low Tax Collection -13,987 -17,289
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -6,636 -10,057
Total -20,623 -27,347
Source: Estimates based on Table 3.
Table 5
Dynamic Consequences of the 1997 NFC Award for the Provincial
Real Social Sector and Other Services-related Expenditures
(Rs Million)
1997-98 1998-99
Social Sector Expenditures
Impact of Low Tax Collection -1,588 -2,384
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -712 -911
Total -2,301 -3,295
Other Expenditures
Impact of Low Tax Collection -1,403 -2,106
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -629 -804
Total -2,032 -2,910
1999-2000 2000-01
Social Sector Expenditures
Impact of Low Tax Collection -2,589 -3,201
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -1,229 -1,862
Total -3,818 -5,063
Other Expenditures
Impact of Low Tax Collection -2,287 -2,827
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -1,085 -1,645
Total -3,372 -4,472
Source: Author's Estimates.
Table 6
Dynamic Consequences of the 1997 NFC Award for Provincial
Real Social Sector and Other Services-related Expenditures
1997-98 1998-99
Social Sector Expenditures
Impact of Low Tax Collection -10.2% -15.9%
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -4.6% -6.1%
Total -14.8% -22.0%
Other Expenditures
Impact of Low Tax Collection -8.1% -12.5%
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -3.6% -4.8%
Total -11.7% -17.2%
1999-2000 2000-01
Social Sector Expenditures
Impact of Low Tax Collection -17.7% -23.7%
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -8.4% -13.8%
Total -26.1% -37.5%
Other Expenditures
Impact of Low Tax Collection -11.7% -13.2%
Impact of Change in Transfer's Design -5.5% -7.7%
Total -17.2% -20.9%
Source: Author's Estimates.