"Macroeconomic factors and Pakistani equity market".
Nishat, Mohammed ; Shaheen, Rozina
Abstract
This paper analyzes long-term equilibrium relationships between a
group of macroeconomic variables and the Karachi Stock Exchange Index.
The macroeconomic variables are represented by the industrial production
index, the consumer price index, [M.sub.1], and the value of an
investment earning the money market rate. We employ a vector error
correction model to explore such relationships during 1973:1 to 2004:4.
We found that these five variables are cointegrated and two long-term
equilibrium relationships exist among these variables. Our results
indicated a "causal" relationship between the stock market and
the economy. Analysis of our results indicates that industrial
production is the largest positive determinant of Pakistani stock
prices, while inflation is the largest negative determinant of stock
prices in Pakistan. We found that while macroeconomic variables
Granger-caused stock price movements, the reverse causality was observed
in case of industrial production and stock prices. Furthermore, we found
that statistically significant lag lengths between fluctuations in the
stock market and changes in the real economy are relatively short.
1. INTRODUCTION
The growing importance of stock markets around the world has
recently opened a new avenue of research into the relationship between
stock market development and economic growth. It is one of the most
enduring debates in economics that whether financial development causes
economic growth or whether it is a consequence of increased economic
activity. Schumpeter (1912) argued that technological innovation is the
force underlying long-run economic growth, and that the cause of
innovation is the financial sector's ability to extend credit to
the "entrepreneur". Joan Robinson, on the other hand,
maintained that economic growth creates a demand for various types of
financial services to which the financial system responds, so that
"where enterprise leads finance follows" (1952, p. 86).
Empirical investigations of the link between financial development in
general and stock markets in particular and growth have been relatively
limited. Goldsmith (1969) reports a significant association between the
level of financial development, defined as financial intermediary assets
divided by GDP, and economic growth. He recognized, however, that in his
framework there was "no possibility of establishing with confidence
the direction of the causal mechanisms (p. 48)." A number of
subsequent studies have adopted used the growth regression framework in
which the average growth rate in per capita output across countries is
regressed on a set of variables controlling for initial conditions and
country characteristics as well as measures of financial market
development [see King and Levine (1993a); Atje and Jovanovic (1993);
Levine and Zervos (1996); Harris (1997) and Levine and Zervos (1998)
among others].
A more difficult question arises with respect to whether the
forward-looking nature of stock prices could be driving apparent
causality between stock markets and growth. Current stock market prices
should represent the present discounted value of future profits. In an
efficient equity market, future growth rates will, therefore, be
reflected in initial prices.
2. PAKISTAN'S EQUITY MARKET
Since its independence in 1947, a multitude of problems have stood
in Pakistan's way of realising its true economic potential.
Included in the social and political problems are recurring fights among
various religious sects, an ever-increasing population and archaic
bureaucratic procedures. Economic problems have included
counter-productive tax rates, debilitating customs duties that stymied
foreign investments, and the Pakistani government's strategic
approach that kept the economy as well as the stock market closed to
foreigners.
Although Pakistan continues to struggle with socio-political
problems, it has recently made tremendous strides in the economic front
via reforms that were introduced in the early part of 1991. The most
significant of the reforms was perhaps the opening of the economy to
foreign investment on very liberal terms and allowing, for the first
time in independent Pakistan's history, direct and indirect
investments by foreign nationals and institutional investors in
Pakistan's equity markets. These reforms have produced positive
results. Pakistan's industrial exports and foreign investment today
are growing at the country's fastest rate ever. The country's
foreign exchange reserves skyrocketed to $12327.9 million in 2003-04
from $2279.2 million in 1998-99. Similarly, several Pakistani stocks are
now traded on international markets. Also, foreign brokerage houses are
now being allowed through joint ventures with Pakistani investment
bankers to participate in primary as well as secondary markets in
Pakistan. Given the newfound interest in the Pakistani stock markets, an
intriguing question is how these markets have performed over the years.
To answer this question we examine the return generating process of the
Karachi Stock Exchange (KSE). The KSE is the largest and most active
stock exchange in Pakistan, accounting for between 65 percent and 70
percent of the value of the country's total stock transactions. It
has been declared as the "Best Performing Stock Market of the World
for the year 2002". On October 01, 2004, 663 companies were listed
with the market capitalization of Rs 1,495.12 billion (US$ 25.23
billion) having listed capital of Rs 390.41 billion (US$ 6.59 billion).
The KSE 100 Index touched at 5245.82 on October 01, 2004. KSE has been
well into the 3rd year of being one of the Best Performing Markets of
the world as declared by the international magazine "Business
Week". Similarly the US newspaper, USA Today, termed Karachi Stock
Exchange as one of the best performing bourses in the world.
Time series data over a reasonably long period are available on the
KSE. The KSE is also well established emerging equity markets and thus,
provides a showcase for other emerging markets in the world. The
empirical evidence regarding the direction of causality between stock
prices and macro variables is not conclusive. Nishat and Saghir (1991)
and Hussain and Mahmood (2001) examined causality between stock prices
and macro variables in Pakistan. Nishat and Saghir (1991) observed a
unidirectional causality from stock prices to consumption expenditures
whereas Hussain and Mahmood (2001) observed a unidirectional causality
from macro variables to stock prices. Mookerjee (1988) and Ahmed (199)
reported a unidirectional causality from stock prices to investment
spending for India and Bangladesh respectively.
The objective of this paper is to analyze the long-term
relationship between the KSE and certain relevant macroeconomic factors.
It employs a vector error correction model (VECM) [Johansen (1991)] in a
system of five equations to investigate the presence of cointegration
(and, by implication, long-term equilibrium relations) among these
factors.
This paper's contributions are as follows. First, by embracing
a study period that extends beyond 1990, the study by Nishat and Saghir
(1991) does not cover the period of 1990s, the post reforms period.
Moreover this paper employs different set of macroeconomic variables as
compared with Hussain and Mahmood (2001) to find the causal relationship
between macroeconomic activity and stock prices. The current paper
provides interpretations of multiple cointegrating relationships in a
system of equations [unlike the single cointegrating vector models of
Baillie and Bollerslev (1989); Hafer and Jansen (1991); Diebold,
Gardeazabel, and Yilmaz (1994); Engsted and Tanggaard (1994); Harris,
McInish, and Schoesmith (1995); Mukherjee and Naka (1995); Chinn and
Frankel (1995); Lo, Fund, and Morse (1995); Cushman and Lee (1996); and
Dutton and Strauss (1997); Nishat and Saghir (1991) and Hussain and
Mahmood (2001))]. Also, we demonstrate the effects of macro-economic
factors on the Pakistani stock market by constructing the impulse
responses as well as variance decompositions.
The paper proceeds along the following lines. Section 2 presents
the asset valuation model and its implications for pricing of
macroeconomic factors. Section 3 discusses the data and the methodology.
Section 4 reports results, and Section 5 offers conclusions.
2.1. The Asset Valuation Model and Pricing of Macroeconomic Factors
Stock Prices and interest Rates
The intuition regarding the relationship between interest rates and
stock prices is well established, suggesting that an increase in
interest rates increases the opportunity cost of holding money and thus
substitution between stocks and interest bearing securities, and hence
falling stock prices. Moreover, any change in an asset's cash flows
(CF) should have a direct impact on its price Thus, the asset's
expected growth rates which influence its predicted cash flows will
affect its price in the same direction. Conversely, any change in the
required rate of return (RRR) should inversely affect the asset's
price. The required rate of return has two basic components-the nominal
risk-free rate and the premium commensurate with the asset's risk.
The nominal risk-free rate in addition is comprised of the real rate of
interest and the anticipated inflation rate. We expect a positive
correlation between the nominal interest rate and the risk-free rate of
the valuation model. Thus, a change in nominal interest rates should
move asset prices in the opposite direction.
Stock Prices and Inflation Rate
Actual inflation will be positively correlated with unanticipated
inflation, and will ceteris paribus move asset prices in the opposite
direction. It may be argued that the effect on the discount rate would
be negated if cash flows increase at the same rate as inflation.
However, cash flows may not go up with inflation. DeFina (1991), among
others, suggests that pre-existing contracts would deny any immediate
adjustments in the firm's revenues and costs. Indeed, one might
argue that cash flows should initially decrease if output prices lag
input costs in response to rising inflation.
Stock Prices and Output Growth
Industrial production presents a measure of overall economic
activity in the economy and affects stock prices through its influence
on expected future cash flows [Fama (1990)]. Thus, we would expect a
positive relationship between stock prices and industrial production.
Stock Prices and Money Supply
The direction of impact of money supply on stock prices needs to be
determined empirically. On the one hand, it can be argued that monetary
growth, due to its positive relationship with the inflation rate [Fama
(1982)], will adversely affect stock prices. On the other hand, it may
also be argued that monetary growth brings about economic stimulus,
resulting in increased cash flows (corporate earnings effect) and
increased stock prices. One may also add that in the case of Pakistan
the money stock might very well convey information about Pakistan's
risk-free rate, which is otherwise masked by the government control of
nominal interest rate in much of our study period. When the interest
rate is pegged by the government, underlying pressure from agents'
liquidity preference which is ordinarily reflected in the interest rate
is instead reflected in changes in the money stock. Since the money
supply has a negative relationship with interest rates, this implies a
direct relationship between the former and the stock price.
3. METHODOLOGY AND DATA
3.1. Data
Hardouvelis (1987); Keim (1985); Litzenberger and Ramaswamy (1982)
empirically investigated whether the main economic indicators (e.g.,
inflation, interest rates, treasury bond's returns, trade balance,
dividend returns, exchange rates, money supply, and crude oil prices)
are effective to explain the share returns. If there was a
co-integration relation between macroeconomic indicators and share
returns, there would be a causal relation between these variables, too.
Otherwise, share returns cannot be explained by main macroeconomic
variables. In this study, the relationships between share returns and
selected macroeconomic variables have been examined for the Pakistani
equity market
The variables which we use to represent Pakistan's stock
market and its output, inflation, money stock and interest rate are
respectively the KSE Index, the Industrial Production Index, the
Consumer Price Index, a narrowly defined money supply (comparable to
[M.sub.1]), and the money market rate in the inter bank market. This
Quarterly data covers the period of 1973:1 to 2002:4. All variables
except interest rates are transformed into natural logs. Logged values
of the nominal stock index, industrial output, inflation, and money are
denoted as SPIL, IIPL and CPIL, and interest rate as MR.
All data sets were extracted from the International Financial
Statistics (IFS). Similar sets of variables have been used by Chen, et
al. (1986); Darrat and Mukherjee (1987); Hamao (1988); Brown and Otsuki
(1988); Darrat (1990); Lee (1992) and Mukherjee and Naka (1995).
3.2. Empirical Methodology
This section outlines Johansen's (1991, 1995) vector
error-correction model (VECM) for testing for cointegration between
integrated time-series. In estimating the VECM we first consider whether
each series is integrated of the same order, to do this we consider the
standard Augmented Dickey-Fuller test. Assuming that each series
contains a single unit root, and thus each series is integrated of order
one, the potential for co-movement between series exists, suggesting the
existence of a long-run relationship amongst these variables. Thus, we
can test for cointegration that is the existence of at least one
long-run stationary relationship between these series, using the method
of Johansen (1991, 1995), which involves investigation of the
p-dimensional vector autoregressive process of k-th order:
[DELTA][Y.sub.t] = [mu] + [k-1.summation over (i=1)][[GAMMA].sub.i]
[DELTA][Y.sub.t-1] + [PI][Y.sub.t-k] + [[epsilon].sub.t] (1)
where [DELTA] is the first difference lag operator, Y, is a (p x 1)
random vector of time series variables with order of integration equal
to one, I(1), [mu] is a (p x 1) vector of constants, [[GAMMA].sub.i]
are (p x p) matrices of parameters, [[epsilon].sub.t] is a sequence of
zero-mean p-dimensional white noise vectors, and H is a (p x p) matrix
of parameters, the rank of which contains information about long-run
relationships among the variables.
As is well known, the VECM expressed in equation (1) reduces to an
orthodox vector autoregressive (VAR) model in first-differences if the
rank (r) of [PI] is zero, whilst if [PI] has full rank, r = p, all
elements in [Y.sub.t] are stationary. More interestingly, 0<r<p,
suggests the existence of r cointegrating vectors, such that there exist
(p x r) matrices, [alpha] and [beta] each of rank r and such that [PI] =
[alpha][beta]', where the columns of the matrix, [alpha] are
adjustment (or loading) factors and the rows of the matrix fl are the
cointegrating vectors, with the property that [beta]'[y.sub.t] is
stationary even though [Y.sub.t] may comprise of individually I(1)
processes. Tests of the hypothesis that the number of cointegrating
vectors is at most r (r = 1, ..., p) are conducted using the likelihood
ratio (trace) test statistics for reduced rank in the context of the
restrictions imposed by cointegration on the unrestricted VAR involving
the series comprising [Y.sub.t].
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Table I presents the unit root tests for our data. The tests of a
unit root in levels using the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) method are
estimated using two specifications: a constant and trend; and a constant
only. The unit root tests for first-difference stationarity are
conducted with just a constant term. The results suggest that all series
contain a single unit root, which requires first-differencing to achieve
stationarity. Given that all series are integrated of the same order, we
are able to consider whether they are determined by some common set of
fundamentals, that is whether a stationary linear combination exists
between these variables.
The lag lengths in Vector Autoregression (VAR) are determined by
the Akaike Information Criterion, and these are decided at one lag
(Table 2), further, these lag lengths also ensure that the errors
exhibit no remaining autocorrelation. Test statistics are calculated
allowing for an intercept and trend term in both the cointegrating
equation and the VAR.
4.1. Testing for Granger Causality
The procedure for testing statistical causality between stock
prices and the economy is the direct "Granger-causality" test
proposed by C. J. Granger in 1969. Granger causality may have more to do
with precedence, or prediction, than with causation in the usual sense.
It suggests that while the past can cause/predict the future, the future
cannot cause/predict the past. According to Granger, X causes Y, if the
past values of X can be used to predict Y more accurately than simply
using the past values of Y. In other words, if past values of X
statistically improve the prediction of Y, then we can conclude that X
"Granger-causes" Y. It should be pointed out that given the
controversy surrounding the Granger causality method, our empirical
results and conclusions drawn from them should be considered as
suggestive rather than absolute. This is especially important in light
of the "false signals" that the stock market has generated in
the past.
The steps in testing whether macroeconomic factors "Granger
cause" stock prices are as follows. First, we regress share price
index with each macroeconomic variable in two variables equation then we
obtain residuals. In next step, we regress lagged values of shares price
index with lagged vales of residuals, lagged valued of specific
macroeconomic variable at first difference and lagged values of shares
price index at first difference. This is the unrestricted regression.
After we run this regression, we obtain the unrestricted residual sum of
squares, [RSS.sub.UR]. Second, we run the regression by eliminating the
lagged valued of specific macroeconomic variable at first difference,
this is the restricted regression After we run the regression, we obtain
the restricted sum of squares, [RSS.sub.R]. The null hypothesis is bi =
0 for all values of i. To test this hypothesis, the F-test is applied,
as shown below:
F = [RSS.sub.R] - [RSS.sub.UR] k-[k.sub.0]RSS/N- k
If the F-value exceeds the critical F-value at the chosen level of
significance, the null hypothesis is rejected, in which case the lagged
macroeconomic variable belongs in the regression. This would imply that
macroeconomic variable "Granger cause" or improve the
prediction in stock prices. We then use the same steps to test whether
the stock prices causes "Granger-causes" in macro economy
(Table 3). These results indicate that in short run, only industrial
production does" Granger cause" in stock prices. Both the
monetary aggregate and market rates have minor short-term impact on
stock prices. But in long run all macroeconomic variables except
inflation have significant impact on stock price fluctuations. (Tables 4
and 5).
The test results presented in Table 8 support the existence of two
cointegrating vectors between the share price index and industrial
production, inflation and long-term interest rates at 5 percent (1
percent) significance level. Thus, we proceed in estimating a vector
error-correction model and report the cointegrating vectors, [beta],
from the VECM and the coefficients, [alpha], which show the speed of
return to equilibrium. Additionally, we normalize the cointegrating
vector so that the coefficient on the share price index is unity, thus
allowing us to examine the relationship between this variable and the
financial and macroeconomic variables (Table 8).
Table 8 presents the cointegrating vectors and speed of adjustment
parameters between the variables. The results show significant long-run
relationships between share price index and industrial production,
inflation and interest rates with all parameters in the cointegrating
vector significant. This result would tend to support the view that the
changes in stock price index are linked to general macroeconomic risk
factors, and suggests the value premium largely arises due to rational,
non-diversifiable risk, and not from sub-optimal behaviour by market
agents. These two results suggest that, inherently value and growth
stocks may respond to different stimuli, such that value stocks, whose
investor-type is more likely to be dominated by large institutional
holders, will respond more directly to interest rate changes (that is,
the change in the return of a competing asset), while growth stocks,
which may be additionally held by investors who adopt non-rational
trading strategies, typically referred to as 'noise' traders,
such as those following a 'fad', may respond more directly to
general economic well-being. Inflation has a negative and significant
relationship with the stock prices.
The lower section of Table 8 shows the corresponding
error-correction coefficients in the VECM. These represent the speed of
adjustment back to long-run equilibrium and the results again show
similarities in the behavior of stock price index and macroeconomic
variables.
Variance Decompositions
This section examines the variance decompositions of the estimated
models. The Variance decompositions show which macroeconomic factors can
provide explanatory power for variation in stock prices over periods of
one, four and eight years, thus extending from the short-to medium-run.
Variance decompositions are constructed from a VAR with orthogonal
residuals and can directly address the contribution of macroeconomic
variables in forecasting the variance of stock prices [Sims (1980);
Litterman and Weis (1985)]. Cointegration implies that the variance
decomposition in levels approximates the total variance of stock prices,
that is [R.sup.2] [right arrow] 1, however, a limitation of the variance
decomposition approach is the dependency on the ordering of the
explanatory variables. The presence of common shocks and co-movements
among the variables implies that ordering is important. This should
place the "most exogenous" variables last. Since SPI is our
primary variable, we place it first. The other three variables are
ordered IIPL, CPIL, [M.sub.1] and MR.
The results from variance decomposition show that any one of the
factors explains a substantial amount of variation in the stock prices
over both the short- and medium-run. More specifically, over the
time-horizon on one, four and eight years, industrial production
accounts for 2.5 percent, 9.5 percent and 12.7 percent of variation in
the stock prices, inflation rate explains 0.15 percent, 0.89 percent and
0.94 percent of variation respectively. Marker rate accounts for 0.23
percent, 2.6 percent and 4.12 percent of the variations and money stock
explains the 0.84 percent, 5.97 percent and 9.5 percent o variation in
stock prices over the time period of one, four and eight years
respectively (Table 9).
While analyzing impulse responses of the SPI, shocks to the
variables are assumed to be one standard deviation above zero (i.e., a
large, but not uncommon positive shock). The largest effect is from
consumer price, where a positive shock forces the market down by 17.5
percent over six years. This is consistent with our hypothesis. Similar
results have been reported by Fama and Schwert (1977); Fama (1981);
Geske and Roll (1983); Chen, et al. (1986) and Lee (1992) for the
U.S.A., Darrat and Mukherjee (1987) for India, Hamao (1988) and
Mukherjee and Naka (1995) for Japan, and Darrat (1990) for Canada.
The next largest effect is from industrial production, where a
positive shock leads to about a 10 percent increase in stock prices over
six years. The same relationship is found by Fama (1981, 1990); Chen, et
al. (1986); Geske and Roll (1983) and Lee (1992) in the U.S.A., by
Mukherjee and Naka (1995) in Japan, and by Darrat (1990) in Canada,
among others. Smaller effects are found from the other three variables.
Shocks to stock prices lead to virtually no change in stock prices.
Shocks to money lead to a small increase in stock prices. Shocks to
market interest rate lead to a small short-run increase in stock prices,
which dissipates over time. This is somewhat at odds with the valuation
model. However, recall that the nominal rate includes an expected
inflation component, which is negatively correlated with stock prices.
5. SUMMARY AND CONCLUDING REMARKS
This paper analyzes long-term equilibrium relationships between a
group of macroeconomic variables and the Karachi Stock Exchange Index.
The macroeconomic variables are represented by the industrial production
index, the consumer price index, [M.sub.1], and the value of an
investment earning the money market rate. We employ a vector error
correction model to explore such relationships in order to avoid
potential misspecification biases that might result from the use of a
more conventional vector Autoregression modeling technique. We find that
these five variables are cointegrated and two long-term equilibrium
relationships exist among these variables. Analysis of our results
indicates that industrial production is the largest positive determinant
of Pakistani stock prices, while inflation is the largest negative
determinant.
Our results indicated a "causal" relationship between the
stock market and the economy. We found that while macroeconomic
variables Granger-caused stock price movements, the reverse causality
was observed in case of industrial production and stock prices.
Furthermore, we found that statistically significant lag lengths between
fluctuations in the stock market and changes in the real economy are
relatively short. The longest significant lag length observed from the
results was only one quarter (AIC).
The possibility for future research is to further evaluate where
fluctuations in stock prices are coming from. Our results reveal that
stock prices movements are not simply formed by looking at the past
trend in the economy, as the adaptive expectations model would suggest.
Expectations are being formed in other ways, but how?
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
REFERENCES
Brown, S. J. and T. Otsuki (1990) Macroeconomic Factors and the
Japanese Equity Markets: The CAPMD Project. In E. J. Elton and M. Gruber
(eds.) Japanese Capital Markets. New York: Harper and Row.
Chen, N. F., R. Roll, and S. A. Ross (1986) Economic Forces and the
Stock Market. Journal of Business 59, 383-403.
Cushman, D. O., and S. S. Lee (1996) Maximum Likelihood Estimation
of Cointegration in Exchange Rate Models for Seven Inflationary OECD Countries. Journal of International Money and Finance, 15,337-368.
Darrat, A. F. (1990) Stock Returns, Money, and Fiscal Policy.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 25,387-398.
Darrat, A. F., and T. K. Mukherjee (1987) The Behavior of the Stock
Market in a Developing Economy, Economics Letters 22, 273-278.
DeFina, R. H. (1991) Does Inflation Depress the Stock Market?,
Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 3-12.
Dickey, D. A., and W. A. Fuller (1981) Likelihood Ratio Statistics
for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Econometrica 49,
1057-1072.
Fama, E. F. (1981) Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation and
Money. American Economic Review 71,545-565.
Fama, E. F. (1990) Stock Returns, Expected Returns, and Real
Activity. Journal of Finance 45, 1089-1108.
Fama, E. F. and G. W. Schwert (1977) Asset Returns and Inflation.
Journal of Financial Economics 5, 115-146.
Geske, R., and R. Roll (1983) The Fiscal and Monetary Linkage
Between Stock Returns and Inflation. Journal of Finance 38, 7-33.
Hussain. F., and Mahmood. T. (2001) The stock Market and the
Economy of Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 40:2, 107-114.
International Financial Statistics (Various Issues)
Johansen, S. (1991) Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of
Cointegrating Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models.
Econometrica 59, 1551-1580.
Johansen, S. (1995) Likelihood Based Inference in Cointegrated
Vector Auto-Regressive Models. Oxford University Press.
Lee, B.S, 1992, Causal Relationships Among Stock Returns, Interest
Rates, Real Activity, and Inflation, Journal of Finance, 47, 1591-1603.
Lo, W., H. Fund, and J.N. Morse, 1995, A Note on Euroyen and
Domestic Yen Interest Rates, Journal of Banking & Finance, 19,
1309-1321.
Mukherjee, T. and A. Naka, 1995, Dynamic Linkage Between
Macroeconomic Variables and the Japanese Stock Market: An Application of
a Vector Error Correction Model, Journal of 461-471.
Nishat. M., and M. Saghir, 1991, The stock Market and Pakistan
Economy. Savings and Development 15:2.131- 145
by
Dr. Mohammed Nishat
Professor and Chairman, Department of Finance and Economics
Institute of Business Administration-IBA
University Road, Karachi
Phones: 111-422-422 Ext. 222, Fax: 9243421
Email:
[email protected]
and
Rozina Shaheen
Faculty in Economics
Institute of Business Management-IoBM
Korangi Creek-Karachi
Phones: 111-004-002, Fax: 75190
Email:
[email protected]
Table 1
ADF Unit Root Tests
Variable Test in Levels Test in Levels Test in
with Constant with Constant Differences
and Trend with Constant
D(CPIL) -2.442534 -0.756665 -3.922352
(-3.4491) (-2.8865) (-2.8865)
D(IIPL) -0.525361 -1.097741 -4.521294
(-3.4491) (-2.8865) (-2.8865)
D(SPIL) -1.973879 -2.293806 -5.077564
(-3.4491) (-2.8865) (-2.8865)
D(ML) -1.871893 -1.253285 -4.712205
(-3.4491) (-2.8865) (-2.8865)
D(MR) -2.218669 -2.232175 -6.183154
(-3.4491) (-2.8865) (-2.8865)
Table 2
Akaike Information Criteria
AIC Value Lag
-17.37706 (1 1)
-18.64374 (1 2)
-19.6006 (1 3)
-25.36969 (1 4)
Table 3
Granger Causality Test Results
To show short term relationship between macro variables
and stock prices
Direction of Causality F-Test Statistics
CPIL [right arrow] SPIL 0.5222
CPIL 0.1328
SPIL [right arrow]
IIPL [right arrow] SPIL 8.6331
SPIL [right arrow] IIPL 8.2934
MQL [right arrow] SPIL 1.8198
SPIL [right arrow] MQL 0
MRL [right arrow] SPIL 1.1424
SPIL [right arrow] MRL 0
Table 4
Long term relation ship between macro variables and stock prices
Independent Dependent
Variable Variable Variable Coefficient
RS1(-1) CPIL SPIL -0.0617
RS2(-1) IIPL SPIL -0.0713
RS3(-1) MQL SPIL -0.0659
RS4(-1) MR SPIL -0.0724
Variable Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
RS1(-1) 0.0332 -1.8596 0.0655
RS2(-1) 0.0353 -2.0186 0.0459
RS3(-1) 0.0328 -2.0073 0.0471
RS4(-1) 0.0323 -2.2394 0.0271
RS shows the error term with lag 1
Table 5
Independent Dependent
Variable Variable Variable Coefficient
RSS1(-1) SPIL CPIL -0.0074
RSS2(-1) SPIL IIPL -0.0685
RSS3(-1) SPIL MQL -0.0005
RSS4(-1) SPIL MR -0.3756
Variable Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
RSS1(-1) 0.0028 -2.5649 0.0116
RSS2(-1) 0.0313 -2.1842 0.031
RSS3(-1) 0.0048 -0.1131 0.9101
RSS4(-1) 0.084 -4.4621 0
on ship between stock prices and macro variables
RSS shows the error term with lag 1
Table 6
Cointegration Results
Likelihood Ratio Tests for Cointegrating Rank
5 Percent
Likelihood Critical
Eigenvalue Ratio Value
Hypothesized Lags
Rank (r) interval:
1 to 1
r = 0 0.6893 211.1385 68.52
r [less than or equal to] 1 0.3294 73.1812 47.21
r [less than or equal to] 2 0.1487 26.0213 29.68
r [less than or equal to] 3 0.0392 7.0212 15.41
r [less than or equal to] 4 0.0193 2.2998 3.76
1 Percent
Critical Hypothesized
Value No. of CE(s)
Hypothesized
Rank (r)
r = 0 76.07 None **
r [less than or equal to] 1 54.46 At most 1 **
r [less than or equal to] 2 35.65 At most 2
r [less than or equal to] 3 20.04 At most 3
r [less than or equal to] 4 6.65 At most 4
Notes: The cointegration tests are conducted assuming the presence
of a constant and trend in both the cointegrating equation and test
VAR.
Table 7
Cointegrating Relationships
Cointegrating and Vector Error Correction Model Estimates
Normalized Cointegrating Coefficients
Normalized Cointegrating Coefficients: 1 Cointegrating Equation(s)
SPIL IIPL CPIL ML MR C
1 -9.49093 -6.4244 7.6151 -0.0383 -27.8203
-1.476 -1.629441 -1.48351 -0.0393
Normalized Cointegrating Coefficients: 2 Cointegrating Equation(s)
SPIL IIPL CPIL ML MR C
1 0 21.7395 -12.1162 -0.7445 56.6884
-10.0312 -5.5318 -0.3842
0 1 2.9674 -2.0789 -0.0744 8.90415
-1.0391 -0.573 -0.0398
Table 8
Vector Error Correction Coefficients and t statistics
Error D(SPIL) D(CPIL) D(IIPL)
Correction:
Coint. -0.0144 0.0056 0.0534
Eq(0) (-1.6996) (4.5085) (5.6987)
Coint. 0.0047 -0.0051 0.1495
Eq(1) (-0.3186) (-2.4807) (-14.8835)
Error D(MR) D(ML) AIC
Correction:
Coint. -0.1843 -0.0032 -7.8188
Eq(0) (-1.4843) (-1.883)
Coint. 0.5527 -0.0051 -8.5631
Eq(1) (-2.8305) (-1.8048)
Table 9.
Variance Decomposition
Variance Decomposition of IIPL
Period S.E. SPIL IIPL CPIL ML MR
4 0.2391 2.4405 92.231 0.6001 2.7915 1.9359
16 0.3511 9.529 77.7843 0.7212 8.0098 3.9552
32 0.3741 12.6867 70.9655 0.8459 11.2663 4.2354
Ordering: IIPL CPIL MR SPIL ML
Variance Decomposition of CPIL
Period S.E. SPIL IIPL CPIL ML MR
4 0.2391 0.1585 19.0342 69.6531 3.9130 7.2410
16 0.3511 0.8927 13.1956 57.0717 22.0701 6.7697
32 0.3741 0.9439 8.9301 46.8661 38.7802 4.4794
Variance Decomposition of ML
Period S.E. SPIL IIPL CPIL ML MR
4 0.2391 0.8436 1.4844 3.4614 92.1443 2.0659
16 0.3511 5.9727 1.4635 7.9747 82.1611 2.4278
32 0.3741 9.5101 1.4629 10.3900 76.5004 2.13636
Ordering: IIPL CPIL MR SPIL ML
Variance Decomposition of MR
Period S.E. SPIL IIPL CPIL ML MR
4 0.2391 0.2288 4.8745 12.1202 1.3793 81.3971
16 0.3511 2.5894 6.9382 13.4663 2.5354 74.4705
32 0.3741 4.1201 7.4148 13.2788 2.5869 72.5994
Ordering: IIPL CPIL MR SPIL ML