An analysis of allocative efficiency of wheat growers in Northern Pakistan.
Bashir, Muhammad ; Khan, Dilawar
I. INTRODUCTION
For the last couple of years several agricultural and trade experts
have been advocating if Pakistan has to compete in the international
market for export of agricultural products then it needs to decrease the
cost of production. In the light of Agreement on Agriculture of WTO,
member countries are required to provide increased market access,
decrease domestic support and tariff. These agreements are likely to
increase the cost of production of various agricultural products for
farmers producing these products, and make international competition
tougher for export of agricultural commodities.
There are three possible ways to decrease the cost of
production--by decreasing cost of inputs, by developing cost effective
high yielding technologies or by improving management practices. There
is little hope for decrease in the cost of inputs. Over the recent years
prices of the petroleum products, were revised upward several times and
this trend is likely to continue in future. Similarly, there was
increase in the prices of gas, electricity and other agricultural
inputs. Historically, in Pakistan, increase in prices of agricultural
inputs has been much higher than the increase in prices of agricultural
outputs [Pakistan (1988)]. Under these circumstances there is little
hope of decease in prices of agricultural inputs. As far as development
of new agricultural technologies, particularly high yielding varieties,
is concerned it is a long-term process. It takes several years to
develop a new variety and in its formal approval for distribution to
farmers. Nevertheless, there is room for decreasing cost of producing
through improvement in the management practices. When economists talk
about improvement in the management practices they talk in terms of
'technical efficiency' and 'allocative efficiency'.
Technical efficiency has been defined as firm's ability to produce
maximum output given a set of inputs and technology. Allocative (or
price) efficiency measures firm's success in choosing optimal
proportions, i.e. where the ratio of marginal products for each pair of
inputs is equal to the ratio of their market prices. Technical
efficiency plus allocative efficiency constitute economic efficiency.
In Pakistan several studies have tried to measure technical
efficiency of farms but little work has been done to estimate allocative
efficiency. According to these studies farmers' technical
efficiency, in Pakistan ranges from 57 to 88 percent [see Ali and
Chaudhry (1990); Shah, et al. (1995); Shafiq and Rehman (2000); Bashir,
et al. (1994); Ahmad and Qureshi (1999); Abroad and Shami (1999) and
Battese, et al. (1986)].
Generally, in Pakistan, input recommendations for various crops are
blanket, irrespective of soil type, water availability, marketing costs
and financial status of farmer. Research trials are undertaken on
agricultural research stations and the recommendations are made for a
wide area, based on these trials, Each year prices of several inputs are
revised but there is seldom any change or revision in the recommended
level of inputs. Under these circumstances there is need to explore
whether farmers are allocating their resources optimally, or how
efficient they are allocatively.
This study was directed in Peshawar valley to determine the wheat
grower's allocative efficiency. Peshawar valley is known for its
rich soil, hard working farmers and diversity of crops and orchards
grown in the area. Majority of farmers is small and medium sized and
most of agricultural farms are irrigated by the canal-irrigated system.
II. REVIEW OF LITERATURE
The general way to estimate allocative efficiency, in cross
sectional data is to test the equality between the estimated Marginal
Value Product (MVP) and Marginal Factor Cost (MFC). Lau and Yotopolous
(1982) proposed profit function to estimate both technical and
allocative efficiency. Yotopolous and Lau (1979) and Jamison and Lau
(1982) found that Indian farmers were profit maximisers. In contrast,
Junankar (1980) observed that Indian farmers were not maximising profit.
Stefanou and Saxena (1988), using a generalisation of the Yotopolous and
Lau approach, allowed training variables, education and management
experience, to influence efficiency directly.
The approach suggested by Lau and Yotopolous (1982) uses an average
profit function and cannot handle flexible functional forms. In
contrast, the approach proposed by Kopp and Diewert (1982), and
Zieschang (1983) permits flexible functional forms and utilises the
information in the frontier cost function. Their approach draws on using
the Farrell's notion of efficiency and the generalisation suggested
by Kopp (1981). It decomposes the deviations from a frontier cost
function into technical and allocative components. This approach and the
approach suggested by Lau and Yotopolous bases upon duality theory and
do not require the direct knowledge of frontier technology or its
parameters. For the situations where duality does not hold (e.g.
uncertainty and dynamic analysis, see Taylor (1986) for details) this
approach may not be very useful. Moreover, in the approach of Lau and
Yotopolous, it is not clear whether the error in the profit function
comes from deviations from the production or from price inefficiency.
Schmidt and Lovell (1979) suggested an alternative approach, using the
behavioural assumption that the firm seeks to minimise cost. Using this
approach Ali (1986), Kalirajan and Shand (1986) and Kumbhakar (1987)
found that farmers are both technically and allocatively inefficient.
Schmidt and Lovell's method treats the error in the
production, and price in a systematic way and requires data on farm
specific prices. Also, in case of dual approach farm specific prices are
needed. In developing countries prices of important commodities are
fixed by governments, hence dual approach on cross sectional data may
not work. However, in case of Peshawar Valley it may not happen because
significant variations were found in the transportation cost as well as
in the use of various agricultural inputs.
III. METHODOLOGY
This study was conducted in an irrigated area of Peshawar Valley.
Three districts--Peshawar, Mardan and Charsadda---were the universe of
the study. The data was collected through a pre-structured questionnaire
from January to June 2005 through several visits. In each district five
villages were selected through a multistage stratified sampling. Two
hundred respondents were interviewed for the study. The sampling
proportion from the sample villages was selected by the following
formula:
[n.sub.k] = n[N.sub.k] / [15.summation over (K=1)] [N.sub.k]
Where, [n.sub.k] is the proportion of the sample in the [k.sub.th]
village, n is the size of the sample and [N.sub.k] is the number of farm
households of the [k.sub.th] village. The total operated area of the
respondent farmers was taken for the study.
Econometric Model
When specifying an econometric model the choice of functional form
often poses a problem since the economic theory does not usually provide
a precise guide. The choice of functional form can have important
implications for subsequent statistical tests, forecasts, and policy
analysis [Hall (1978); Mizon (1977) and Godfrey and Wickens (1981)]. It
is also argued that specification of model should be guided by
visualisation of the true process and this is determined by nature, not
by econometricians. In order to identify a true functional form, which
best fits the data of this study, the attention was drawn to translog
production function. The translog production function is a member of de
Janvry's generalised power production function family. In this
functional form the percent change in the input ratio with respect to
percent change in the marginal rate of substitution is not constant
along the isoquant but varies from point to point. The translog
production function can be generalised to include any number of input
categories, and each pair of input may have a different elasticity of
substitution. The general form of the function is
LnY = [[beta].sub.0] + [n.summation over (i=1)] [[beta].sub.i]
ln[x.sub.i] + [n.summation over (i=1)] [n.summation over (j=1)]
[[beta].sub.ij] ln[x.sub.i] [lnx.sub.j]
Where Y is the output, [x.sub.i] are inputs and [[beta].sub.0],
[[beta].sub.i], [[beta].sub.ij] are the parameters to be estimated.
Sometimes, squared terms of [x.sub.i] are also included [Christensen,
Jorgenson, and Lau (1973)]. For translog the shape of isoquant heavily
depends upon [[beta].sub.ij]'s; if these are equal to zero, the
translog model would reduce to the Cobb-Douglas model.
So, the most restricted form of translog production function is the
Cobb-Douglas or log linear (ln-ln) form.
To compare the ln-ln model against the linear model Godfrey and
Wicken's (1981) Lagrange Multiplier (LM test) was used. This
approach is capable of selecting or rejecting both models, or selecting
one rather than the other. The test statistic is
[S.sup.*] = [TR.sup.2] ~ [chi square] (1)
Calculation required to compute the test statistics are given in
the appendix. [S.sup.*] has a Chi-squared distribution [[[chi
square].sub.(1)]] with one degree of freedom. T is the size of sample
and [R.sup.2] in the uncertered [R.sup.2] obtained from regression
explained in the appendix. The value of test statistic was close to zero
for both linear and log linear forms. So, under this test neither linear
nor ln-ln form could be rejected. After this another specification test,
Sargan (1964) criteria, was applied to make a choice between linear and
ln-ln forms. Under Sargan criteria the test statistic is
S = [([[??].sub.u]/g [[??].sub.v]).sup.T]
Where [[??].sub.u] and [[??].sub.v] are standard deviations of
error terms obtained when the ordinary least squares (OLS) is run on
linear and In-In forms respectively. T is the sample size and g is the
geometric mean of dependent variable. Sargan's criteria is if S
<1, then ln-ln model is preferred. The calculated value of S was
1.5684 implying ln-ln specification better suits to the data under
study.
Both Cobb-Douglas and translog are ln-ln forms, We need to further
test which one will suit to our data. Cobb-Douglas is the most
restricted form of translog. When all interaction coefficients
([[beta].sub.ij]'s) are zero translog reduces to Cobb-Douglas form.
So, we need to test whether all [[beta].sub.ij]'s are zero. For
this purpose an F-test [Koutsoyiannis (1977)] was used. The hypotheses
were
[H.sub.o] = All 36 restrictions are true
[H.sub.1] = Not all restrictions are true
The statistic was computed as under:
[F.sup.*] = [summation][e.sup.2.sub.r] - [summation]
[e.sup.2.sub.u]]/C/[summation][e.sup.2.sub.u]/(T - K)
Where [SIGMA][e.sup.2.sub.r] and [SIGMA][e.sup.2.sub.u] are sum of
residuals squared from restricted and unrestricted model estimated by
OLS method, C is the number of restrictions and T-K is the degree of
freedom for unrestricted model. [F.sup.*] has F distribution. The
calculated F was 2.36 with C = V1 =36 and T-k = 155; p-value being
0.0014. Therefore [H.sub.o] was rejected. The restricted translog model
is as under:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Description of variables is given in the section "Results and
Discussion"
Byerlee (1987) proposed that for policy purpose, it would be a
useful exercise to further divide the allocative inefficiency into two
categories (a) constrained case where allocative gains are measured by
reallocating 'i' inputs within a constant cost level, and (b)
the unconstrained case where allocative gains accrue due to movement
along the expansion path until the marginal cost on expenditure is equal
to marginal revenue.
For the present study, keeping in view more policy relevance,
constrained allocative errors of farmers were considered. It is assumed
that an individual farmer has fixed land, labour and cash outlay and his
objective is to maximise his output by extending the given cash outlay.
Let estimated production frontier is:
Y = f(x, b)
Where x is vector of inputs, b is estimated vector of coefficients
and Y is output of individual farmer.
Let farmer's outlay [C.sub.o] is
[C.sub.o] = [m.summation over (j=1)] [V.sub.j] [X.sub.j]
Where [v.sub.j] in the price of jth input [X.sub.j] and
'm' denotes the number of variables purchased.
Farmer's output maximising problem can be expressed as:
Maximise f(x, b)
Subject to
[C.sub.o] = [SIGMA] [v.sub.j][X.sub.j]
The first order condition for constrained output maximisation
problem will be:
[f.sub.l]/ [f.sub.i] = [v.sub.l]/[v.sub.i]
Where [f.sub.1] and [f.sub.i] denote the first order derivatives of
Y with respect to [x.sub.l] and [x.sub.i] respectively. Where as
[v.sub.l] and [v.sub.i] are their prices. Cost constrained output (Y) of
the farmer can be obtained by substituting the cost constrained
maximising input levels ([x.sub.l.sup.*].... [x.sub.m.sup.*]) in the
production frontier. Allocative efficiency of each individual farmer was
determined by calculating the ratio of predicted output (Y) from
estimated production function to cost constrained maximum output (y).
IV. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
There were high variations in the yield among sample farmers
depending upon the use of inputs and farmers management practices.
Average wheat yield of farmers surveyed was 905 kg per acre; minimum
being 305 kg and maximum being 1575 kg per acre. Summary statistics of
variables is given in Table 1.
Variables Used in the Analysis
Variables used in the analysis are defined as under:
Wheat Yield (Y): Wheat yield per acre in Kgs. It is dependent
variable
Normal Plowings (NPL): Total number of plowings using tine cultivator and/or with animals using local plow per acre.
Disc Plowings (DPL): Total number of plowings by disc plow per
acre.
Ratio of Wheat Acreage Following Fallow Land (RWFL): Wheat acreage
of a farmer following fallow lands divided by the total wheat acreage of
that farmer.
Ratio of Wheat Acreage Sown by the Recommended Sowing Method (RSM):
Wheat acreage planted by recommended sowing method by a farmer divided
by total wheat acreage of wheat farmer.
Nitrogen (N): Kg of Nitrogen (nutrients) applied per acre.
Phosphorous ([P.sub.2][O.sub.5]): Kg of [P.sub.2][O.sub.5] applied
per acre.
Management (MG): Total number of schooling years plus age of a
farmer divided by 2.
About one third of the wheat crop area was sown during the optimum
range of sowing time. Only seven percent of the sample farmers were
found using certified seed and twenty seven percent practiced weed
control. Sowing time, weed control and use of certified seed are
important variables, which can significantly affect the wheat
productivity [Byerlee (1987); Hobbs (1985)]. A limitation of the study
relates to the use of irrigation water. To capture the effect of
irrigation water on wheat yield we have used the variable "number
of irrigations". Quantity of water for each irrigation can vary
from farm to farm or even from field to field. However, there were also
some timely rains during the wheat-growing period.
Restricted translog production function was used to estimate the
production coefficients. Results are given in Table 2.
Allocative efficiency of individual farmer was estimated by
calculating the ratio of predicted output (Y) from estimated production
function to cost constrained maximum output. Detailed procedure is
explained in the methodology section. The average allocative efficiency
of sample farmers was 72 percent ranging from 51 to 88 percent. Majority
of sample farmers was centred around the mean allocative efficiency.
To see whether cash constrained solution satisfies the marginal
conditions for maximisation, the following relationship was compared.
P[partial derivative]F/[partial derivative[x.sub.i] = [v.sub.i]
Where P is the price of output, P[partial derivative]f/[partial
derivative][x.sub.i] is the marginal product of input i and [v.sub.i] is
the price of input i. Forsund, et al. (1980) defined this condition for
scale efficiency.
To analyse the allocative efficiency of each input, percentage
deviations of actual input levels from cost constrained optimum levels
were computed. Sixty two percent of farmers were using less nitrogen
than optimum level required to obtain maximum output given the cost
outlay. Similarly, eighty three percent of farmers were using less
phosphorous than the optimum level. However, the use of tillage was
/bund higher than the optimum level. Fifty six percent of farmers were
efficient in use of tillage and 67 percent in use of irrigation water.
Factors Affecting Allocative Efficiency
Theoretically, factors affecting the allocative efficiency are
experience of the farmer, his level of education, level of awareness
about improved technology and availability of cash. During discussion
with farmers, at the time of data collection, these theoretical
considerations were further supported. Level of awareness included the
sum total extension contacts, discussions with other farmers about input
use, number of times the farmer listened to agricultural programs on the
radio in a week during the wheat growing period, number of times the
farmer watched agricultural programs on TV, and reading of agricultural
magazine. An index was constructed for level of awareness. Farm size was
used as proxy for cash availability, i.e. cash available to a farmer.
Dependent variable is the allocative efficiency of the wheat growers. A
linear relationship was assumed between dependent and independent
variables. Results of OLS regression are summarised in Table 3.
The coefficients of education and awareness are positive and
significant at I percent level of significance. It means that allocative
efficiency of farmers is directly related with the levels of education
and information. The coefficient of farm size was positive and
significant at 10 percent level of significance. Most of the allocative
inefficiencies were observed in use of fertilisers. Fertilisers were not
available at the village level. These had to be purchased from the local
markets, which were located at a distance of 3 to 10 miles from the
research sites; other inputs were available at the village level. Use of
herbicides was not popular among farmers.
V. CONCLUSION
Level of fertiliser use in Peshawar valley is much below the
optimum level. The use of tillage and irrigation were marginally higher
than the profit maximising level, To encourage the use of fertiliser
there is need to improve the input supply system, to provide credit
facilities and to motivate farmers through appropriate extension
methods.
Comments
I must congratulate Dr Muhammad Bashir and Mr Dilawar Khan for
undertaking research on a very important topic. The authors have used
farm level data to estimate growers' allocative efficiency in
Northern Pakistan. They have benefited from a sizeable and very rich
literature on the topic. However, I have few suggestions that would help
improving the quality and usefulness of the study if incorporated.
In the study area, like other areas of Pakistan, farming is a
multi-output multi-input enterprise. Therefore, we can talk about the
overall allocative efficiency as well as efficiency in case of
individual enterprises (crops, livestock or others) and with respect to
certain input(s). The author should make it clear in the beginning of
the paper and should not leave it for the reader to infer from the
results presented. It is the discussion on page 9 which hints that the
allocative efficiency of wheat growers is being estimated. It would be
better to incorporate the enterprise in the title modifying it as
"An Analysis of Wheat Growers' Allocative Efficiency in
Peshawar Valley".
In the methodology section, it is mentioned that the village level
sample was selected proportionately to respective population. It would
have been better if sample proportions were based on number of farm
households in each village rather than population.
The authors justify the use of a translog production function for
the study that most of the agricultural economists have used it. This is
not a good reasoning; the function must have desirable properties that
provide justification for its wide use by the researchers. The statement
of these properties would be a better argument.
The period during which farm survey was conducted is mentioned as
January to June 2005. It looks that either the survey is multi visit
survey or the data does not belong to wheat crop 2004-2005. The authors
need to make it dear.
The second para on page 8, as it appears gives the impression that
the model has been tested using Lagrange Multiplier and Sargen
"S" statistics and found In-In specification better fits the
data. It is not possible that the authors tested the model before even
specifying it. The para needs to be revised. Moreover, the Cobb Douglas
functional form is also a In-In form why did not it fit better for the
study under discussion.
The authors have used the restricted translog model without
mentioning restricted in what sense. Later at page 11 it is stated that
a constrained translog production function was used to estimate the
production function. The authors should be explicit whether the
restricted and constrained production function terminology is being used
alternatively or are they using the terms in some different sense.
The estimated translog production function includes a variable on
management (MG) among other independent variable and is defined as the
average of schooling years and farmers' age. In this way the same
weight is attached to age and schooling years. Why not include them
separately, as the data is available on both the variables.
Soon after the table giving estimated coefficients for constrained
translog production function (which were never explained), the authors
stated the average allocative efficiency of sample farmers was 72
percent without even mentioning that such efficiencies were computed
using such and such procedure or formula.
The first sentence in the last paragraph on page 13 mentions that
the authors realised during the discussion with farmers, at the time of
data collection, that important factors affecting allocative efficiency
are age (experience), education, awareness about technology, and
availability of cash. The authors must have benefited from research
addressing determinants of allocative efficiency and therefore, included
questions regarding these important variables in the questionnaire,
therefore these studies should be also referred and given credit instead
of giving whole credit to the discussion with farmers (who might not
even know what allocative efficiency is).
The dependent variable in regression estimated to identify the
factors affecting allocative efficiency is never made explicit. There
will be an allocative efficiency estimate w.r.t to each input included
in the model and for each of them different factors may be important.
The discussion of results and the concluding section are too brief
to make much sense. In addition, there are certain typo mistakes
throughout the paper and need to be removed. Some of the references
listed are not cited anywhere in the paper and dates for some of the
cited studies differ from those given in the references.
Muhammad Iqbal
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Appendices
I. Godfrey and Wicken's Specification Test
Godfrey and Wickens (1981) developed this test for testing the
adequacy of linear and log linear functional forms specification.
Following are the possible outcomes under this test.
(1) Select both the forms
(2) Reject both the forms
(3) Select one form and reject the other
Procedure is illustrated as under:
1. Assume the linear regression equation is
[M.sub.1] : [y.sub.t] = [k.summation over (j=1)] [[beta].sub.ti]
[X.sub.ti] + [u.sub.t] t = 1, ..., T
and log linear relationship is
[M.sub.2] : [lny.sub.t] = [k.summation over (j=1)] [[beta].sub.ti]
ln [X.sub.ti] + [v.sub.t] t = 1, ..., T
Where, [y.sub.t] are observation on outputs and [x.sub.ti]'s
are physical inputs (I = 1, ..., k) and [[beta].sub.ti] (i = 1, ..., k)
is the vector of coefficients including intercept term and [u.sub.t] and
[v.sub.t] are random errors in expressions [M.sub.1] and [M.sub.2]
respectively.
2. Run the regression [M.sub.1]
3. Compute variables [Q.sub.t], [A.sub.t] [B.sub.t]. [C.sub.t] and
[D.sub.t] as follows
[Q.sub.t][[y.sub.t] ln [y.sub.t] - [y.sub.t] + 1] - [k.summation
over (j=1)][[beta].sub.i][X.sub.ti] ln [X.sub.ti] - [X.sub.t]]
[A.sub.t] = ln y - [[Q.sub.t] [u.sub.t]/[[??].sup.2.sup.u]]
[B.sub.t] = [[2 [6.sub.u]].sup.-1] [[u.sup.2.sub.t] -
[[??].sup.2.sub.u]]
[C.sub.ti] = [X.sub.ti] - 1] [u.sub.t]/[[??].sup.2] i = 1, ..., k
[D.sub.t] = u / [[??].sup.2]
4. Regress a vector of 1's on [A.sub.t], [B.sub.t], [C.sub.ti]
and [D.sub.t]
5. Compute the test statistic [S.sup.*] = [TR.sup.2]
6. [S.sup.*.sub.is] distributed Chi-square [X [(1).sup.2] with one
degree of freedom. If [S.sup.*] is significant reject [M.sub.l],
otherwise not.
The above six steps can be followed for specification of [M.sub.l]
REFERENCES
Ahmad, Munir, and S. Qureshi (1999) Recent Evidence on Farm Size
and Land Productivity: Implications for Public Policy. The Pakistan
Development Review 38, 1135-1153.
Ahmad, Munir, and T. Shami (1999) Production Structure and
Technical Efficiency Analysis of Sericulture in Pakistani Punjab.
Asian-Pacific Journal of Rural Development 2, 15-31.
Ali, M. (1986) The Determinants of Inefficiency in Basmati Rice Production in Pakistan Punjab: Frontier Profit Function Approach.
Unpublished Ph. D. Thesis. Department of Agricultural Economics,
University of Philippines at Los Banos, Philippines.
All, M., and M. A. Chaudhry (1990) Inter-Regional Farm Efficiency
in Pakistan's Punjab: A Frontier Production Function Study. Journal
of Agricultural Economics 41, 62-74.
Bashir, M., K. Muhammad, and M. N. Khan (1994) An Analysis of
Technical Efficiency of Wheat Growers in Irrigated Areas of D. I. Khan.
Sarhad Journal of Agriculture 11, 245-251.
Battese, G. E., S. J. Malik, and M. A. Gill (1986) An Investigation
of Technical Inefficiencies of Production of Wheat Farmers in Four
Districts of Pakistan. Journal of Agricultural Economies 47, 37-49.
Byerlee, D. (1987) Maintaining the Momentum in Post-Green
Revolution Agriculture: A Micro-level Perspective from Asia. University
of Michigan. (MSU International Development Paper No. 10)
Christensen, L. R., D. W. Jorgenson, and L. J. Lau (1973)
Transcendental Logarithmic Production Frontiers. Review of Economics and
Statistics 55:1, 28-45.
Forsund, F. P., C. A. K. Lovell, and P. Schmidt (1980) A Survey of
Frontier Production Functions and their Relationship to Efficiency
Measurements. Journal of Economics 13:1, 5-25.
Godfrey, L. G., and M. R. Wickens (1981) Testing Linear and
Log-linear Regressions for Functional Forms. Review of Economic Studies
18, 487-96.
Hall, R. E. (1978) Stochastic Implications of the Life
Cycle-Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence. Journal of
Political Economy 78, 1971-87.
Hobbs, P. R. (1985) Agronomic Practices and Problem for Wheat
Following Cotton and Rice in Pakistan. In Wheat for More Tropical
Environments. Proceedings of the International Symposium, 273-77.
Jamison, D. T., and L. J. Lau (1982) Farmer Education and Farmer
Efficiency. Baltimore: John Hopkins Press.
Junankar, P. N. (1980) Test of Profit Maximising Hypothesis: A
Study of Indian Agriculture. Journal of Development Studies 16, 186-203.
Kalirajan, and R. T. Shand (1986) Estimating Location Specific and
Firm Specific Technical Efficiency: An Analysis of Malaysian
Agriculture. National Centre for Development Studies. The Australian
National University. (Rural Development Working Paper No. 86/6.)
Kopp, R. J. (1981) The Measurement of Productive Efficiency: A
Reconsideration. Quarterly Journal of Economics August, 477-503.
Kopp, R. J., and W. E. Diewert (1982) The Decomposition of Frontier
and Cost Function Deviations into Measure of Technical and Allocative
Efficiency. Journal of Economics 19, 319-331.
Koutsoyiannis, A. (1977) Theory of Econometrics (Second ed.).
Macmillion Publishers Ltd.
Kumbhakar, S. C. (1987) The Specification of Technical and
Allocative Inefficiency in Stochastic Production and Profit Frontiers.
Journal of Econometrics 34, 335-48.
Lau, L, J., and P. A. Yotopoulos (1982) A Test for Relative
Efficiency and An Application to Indian Agriculture. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 61:1, 94-109.
Mizon, G. E. (1977) Inferential Procedures in Nonlinear Models: An
Application of U. K. Industrial Cross-Sectional Study of Factor
Substitution and Return to Scale. Econometrica 45, 1221-42.
Pakistan, Government of (1988) Report on National Commission on
Agriculture. Ministry of Food and Agriculture, Islamabad.
Sargan, J. D. (1964) Wages and Prices in United Kingdom. In P. E.
Hart, G. Mills, and J. K. Whitaker (eds.) Econometric Analysis for
National Economic Planning. London: Butterworth.
Schmidt, P., and C. A. K. Lovel (1979) Estimating Technical and
Allocative Inefficiency Relative to Stochastic Production and Cost
Frontiers. Journal of Econometrics 9:3, 343-56.
Shafiq, M., and T. Rehman (2000) The Extent of Resource Use
Inefficiencies in Cotton Production in Pakistan's Punjab: An
Application of Data Envelopment Analysis. Agricultural Economics 22,
321-330.
Shah, M. K., F, Ali, and H. Khan (1995) Technical Efficiency of
Major Crop in the North-West Frontier Province of Pakistan. Sarhad
Journal of Agriculture 10, 613-621.
Stefanou, E. S., and S. Sexena (1988) Education, Experience, and
Allocative Efficiency: A Dual Approach. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 70:2, 338-45.
Taylor, C. R. (1986) A Diagrammatic Exposition of the Pitfalls of
Empirical Application of Duality Theory. Department of Agricultural
Economics, University of Illinois, 86 E 370.
Yotopolous, P. A., and L. J. Lau (1979) Resource Use in
Agriculture: Application of the Profit Function to Selected Countries.
Food Resource Institute Studies 17, 1-115.
Zieschang, K. D. (1983) A Note on the Decomposition of Cost
Efficiency into Technical and Allocative Components. Journal of
Econometrics 23, 401-5.
Muhammad Bashir is Dean, Faculty of Rural Social Sciences, and
Dilawar Khan is a PhD student in the Department of Agricultural
Economics at the NWFP Agricultural University, Peshawar.
Table 1
Summary Statistics of Variables Used in the Analysis
(Number of Observations = 200)
S. No. Variable * Unit Mean Standard Deviation
1. NPL No. 3.757 0.788
2. DPL No. 0.535 0.542
3. RWFL Ratio 0.715 0.462
4. RSM Ratio 0.741 0.421
5. N Kg 26.202 9.312
6. [P.sub.2] Kg 10.451 7.213
[O.sub.5]
7. I No. 4.112 1.213
8. MG Years 22.27 6.51
9. Y Kg 905 2.344
* Variables are defined in the following section.
Table 2
Estimates of the Constrained Translog Production Function
(Number of Observations = 200)
Independent Variable OLS Coefficients T-value
Constant 0.43185 * (3.573)
In NPL 0.3825 *** (1.403)
In DPL 0.0826 (1.288)
In RWFL 0.0798 *** (1.427)
In RSM -0.06746 (-1.132)
fn N 0.05257 * (6.873)
In [P.sub.2] [O.sub.5] 0.08657 * (5.343)
In I 0.49165 * (3.965)
In MG 0.07843 (0.687)
(In NPL)2 0.1065 (0.432)
(In DPL)2 0.21675 (1.194)
(InRWFL)2 0.01273 *** (1.295)
(In RSM}2 -0.035484 ** (-1.753)
(In N)2 0.032793 * (2.897)
(In [P.sub.2] [O.sub.5])2 0.098743 * (2.815)
(In I)2 -0.25173 * (-3.817)
(InMG)2 0.032701 (0.4808)
In RWFL * In N 0.001517 (0.3275)
In RWFL * In (PROS) 0.016782 (0.2717)
In RWFL * In I 0.013452 (0.2617)
In NPL * In DPL 0.02476 *** (1.418)
In NPL * In RSM -0.03541 *** (-1.437)
In SPL * In RSM 0.00000 (0.0000)
In N * In (P205) 0.00398 ** (1.954)
1n N * InI 0.00289 ** (1.815)
In [P.sub.2] [O.sub.5] * In I 0.0000 (0.0000)
Adjusted R2 0.8735
NPL = number of normal plowings.
DPL = number of disc plowings.
RW FL = wheat acreage following fallow land divided
by total wheat acreage.
RSM = wheat acreage sown by recommended sowing method divided
by total wheat Acreage.
N = nitrogen (kg/acre).
[P.sub.2] [O.sub.5] = phosphorous(kg/acre).
I = number of irrigations.
Mg = management: total year of schooling plus age of the Tanner
divided by 2.
*, **, *** Significant at 1 percent, 10 percent and 10 percent
level respectively.
Table 3
Regression Results of Factors Affecting Allocative Efficiency
Independent Variable OLS Coefficients
Constant 0.234
(6.653)
Education 0.287 *
(3.512)
Age 0.140
(0.467)
Awareness 01.38 *
(4.516)
Farm Size 0.059 ***
(1.678)
Adjust R2 0.683
(1) Figures in parenthesis are t-values.
*, *** Significant at I percent and 10 percent levels respectively.