P-star model: a leading indicator of inflation for Pakistan.
Qayyum, Abdul ; Bilquees, Faiz
The P-star inflation model is based on the long-term quantity
theory of money and puts together the tong-term determinants of the
price level and the short-run changes in current inflation. The P-star
model-based indicator has replaced the previous monetary policy
procedures in a number of countries because it offers by far more
information and predictive power than monitoring movements in money
supply and the rate of monetary growth. In this paper we used the P-star
model to calculate the leading indicator of inflation, and also to test
the forecasting performance of the P-star model-based leading indicator
of inflation. The results of the study show that compared to the simple
autoregressive model and the M2 growth augmented model, the P-star model
can be used to obtain the leading indicator of inflation in Pakistan
because it has additional information about the future rate of
inflation. Therefore, this paper provides a useful tool to the
policy-makers to assess the future movement of inflation in Pakistan.
1. INTRODUCTION
Forecasting based on leading indicators has a long history in
economics. Much of the earlier work concentrated on developing
indicators of macroeconomic variables such as inflation [Clements and
Hendry (1998)]. Since the emergence of the phenomenon of 'missing
money' in the 1970s, the stability and predictability of the rate
of inflation has emerged as one of the main objectives of the monetary
policy the world over. Therefore, a number of central banks, for example
New Zealand (1990), Canada (1991), UK (1992), Sweden (1993), Finland
(1993), Australia (1993), Spain (1994) and Czechoslovakia (1998), among
others, have changed their previous monetary policy procedures and
shifted to publicly announced inflation targeting in the 1990s, using
the P-star model as an indicator of inflation [Hallman, et al. (1991)].
The P-star model-based indicator offers by tar more information and
predictive power than monitoring increments in money supply and the rate
of monetary growth, as under the previous procedures.
Since it is defined as the money per unit of real potential output,
deviations between the actual price (P) and P-star, the price gap,
indicates future acceleration or deceleration of inflation, provided P
and P-star are cointegrated. While in all the standard models of
inflation the output gap is a major explanatory variable for inflation,
in the P-star approach, the deviations of the velocity of money from
"trend" levels also matter for price level determination.
The P-star inflation model is based on the long-term quantity
theory of money and puts together the long-term determinants of the
price level and the short-term changes in current inflation. In this
paper we intend to use this model to identify the long-run equilibrium
price level as a variable determined by current money supply, potential
income, and the equilibrium rate of money circulation. This will be
followed by tracking forecasting performance of the P-star model based
leading indicator of inflation.
In the literature the reactions to the forecasting performance of
the P-star model are mixed. While Hallman, et al. (1989, 1991) and
Christano (1989) show that the P-star performs better than other models,
Pecchenino and Rasche (1990) find that the P-star model implies
unreasonable dynamic behaviour. Hoeller (1991) in his study of the
P-star model on all OECD countries reports that the results of the model
were not impressive in the case small OECD countries. However, Kool and
Tatom (1994) attribute such results for the smaller countries to the
fact that the smaller countries tend to import inflation, and when
adjusted for this factor they report improvement in results.
The outline of the paper is as follows: we shall explain the P-star
model of inflation indicator, discuss methodology to measure potential
output and trend velocity and data used to estimate the model in Section
2; leading indicator of inflation in Pakistan is estimated in Section 3,
the regression results and causality analysis are presented in Section
4. followed by a comparison of the tracking and forecasting performance
of the model in Section 5. Section 6 concludes the paper.
2. THE P-STAR MODEL OF INFLATION
Following Hallman, et al. (1989, 1991) we develop the P-star model
of inflation based on the famous equation of exchange in the family of
quantity theory of money, i.e.,
PY = MV ... (1)
Where P is the price level, M is a monetary aggregate, V the income
velocity of money and Y is output at constant prices. This model links
the behaviour of price level to the growth of money supply depending on
two basic propositions; that the real output fluctuates around potential
real output ([Y.sup.*]), and the income velocity of money has
equilibrium level ([V.sup.*]). By using long run equilibrium values of
real output and velocity we can obtain equilibrium level of aggregate
price level, [P.sup.*] by the following identity;
[P.sup.*] = M x [V.sup.*] / [Y.sup.*] (2)
Taking logs on the both sides we can rewrite Equation 2 as:
[p.sup.*] = (m + [v.sup.*] - [y.sup.*]) (3)
In the theory it is assumed that actual price level (p) tends to
move towards the equilibrium price level ([p.sup.*]). The p-star model
postulates that the difference between the actual and long run
equilibrium price level acts as a good predictor of inflation. The
leading indicator of inflation in this study is defined as:
[[pi].sup.*] = p - [p.sup.*] = (v - [v.sup.*]) - (y - [y.sup.*])
(4)
Therefore this model can be used to directly predict movements of
the rate of inflation. It implies that if actual inflation ([pi])
exceeds the predicted inflation by this model ([[pi].sup.*]), then
P-star model predicts that the inflation will fall in future until it
reaches the equilibrium rate ([[pi].sup.*]) and vice versa.
The price gap however does not contain information about the
dynamics of adjustment of p to [p.sup.*]. Therefore, in this paper, an
error correction model of the adjustment process is adopted and the
general dynamic specification of the model is given by Equation 5 as:
[DELTA]p = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1] ([p.sub.t-1] -
[p.sup.*.sub.t-1]) + [n.summation over (i=[1.sub.1])] [[beta].sub.i]
[DELTA][p.sub.t-i] + [[epsilon].sub.t] ... (5)
The coefficient [[alpha].sub.1] is the speed of adjustment of
prices to [P.sup.*] and the coefficients of [[beta].sub.i] represent the
lag of the actual rate of inflation.
The critical issue in this model is the estimation of potential
output and the equilibrium values of income velocity of money. A number
of techniques available to obtain the value of potential output can be
categorised into two broad groups; the economic theory based approach
and the statistical approaches. Braun (1990) used the economic theory
based approach to derive the value of potential output by combining a
Phillip's curve based estimate of the natural rate of unemployment
with Okun's law. These estimates are also adopted by Ebrill and
Fries (1990) and Pacchenino and Rasche (1990). Ebrill and Fries (1990)
calculate the velocity gap as the residuals from a co-integrating
equation explaining long-run velocity by the own and competing rates of
return on M2. Christiano (1989), Hannah and James (1989) and Hallman, et
al. (1991) used a linear time trend to calculate potential output. Among
the statistical approaches Bomhoff (1990), Kuttner (1992), and Fisher
and Fleissing (1995) used the Kalman Filter, whereas Hoeller and Paret
(1991), Gibbs (1995), and MeMorrow and Roeger (2001), among others, used
Hodrick-Prescort filter approach [Hodrick and Prescort (1980)]. This
study also uses the widely applied Hodrick-Prescort filter approach to
estimate equilibrium output and velocity. This method basically uses a
long run symmetric moving average to de-trend the particular series.
Technically the HP filter is a two-sided linear filter i.e.,
Minimise [T.summation over (t=1)] [(ln Y - ln
[Y.sup.*.sub.t]).sup.2] (6)
the sum of the squared deviations of a variable (in this case,
output), [Y.sub.t], from its trend
Subject to [T-1.summation over (t=2)] [[(ln [Y.sub.t+1)] - ln
[Y.sup.*.sub.t])-(ln [Y.sup.*.sub.t] - ln [Y.sub.t-1]) ].sup.2] [less
than or equal to] 2
HP method chooses ln [Y.sup.*] to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
Where [Y.sub.t] is the actual GDP at constant market prices,
[Y.sub.t.sup.*] is the trend GDP at constant market prices, and the
[lambda] is Lagrange multiplier. The [lambda] may be termed as penalty
parameter that controls the smoothness of the series variance. It
implies that the larger the value of [lambda], the smoother the series:
as [lambda] [right arrow] [infinity], ln[Y.sub.t.sup.*] approaches a
linear trend. In terms of output gaps a smaller [lambda] implies shorter
cycles and smaller gaps. Following what has become the norm in the
literature and among practitioners, this paper sets [lambda] at 100.
The study covers data period 1960 to 2003, and the two main data
sources are the Federal Bureau of Statistics of Pakistan (Various
Issues) and the International Financial Statistics (2004).
3. ESTIMATED INDICATOR OF INFLATION
One of the important assumptions of the model by Hallman, et al.
(1989, 1991) is that the velocity of money is stationary and the
long-run measure of velocity can be obtained by a simple average.
However, this assumption does not hold as shown by the outcome of the
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test of unit root in Table 1. The results show
that velocity is not stationary and that implies that we cannot get the
equilibrium value of velocity of money by the simple average. Therefore,
this study adopts the widely recommended Hodrick-Prescort filter
approach to calculate the equilibrium value of velocity ([V.sup.*]).
The estimated price gap [[pi].sup.*] (that is p-[p.sup.*]) as an
indicator of inflation is presented in the Figure 1. It shows that the
gap between the actual prices and the P-star model predicted equilibrium
prices ([P.sup.*]) remains positive during the early sixties, mid
seventies, early eighties, early and late nineties, and early years of
2000. It also reveals that actual prices are less than the model
predicted prices for the last two years. This implies that in future
actual prices would move upward towards equilibrium prices, as shown in
Figure 2.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
4. COINTEGRATION AND CAUSALITY ANALYSIS
In this section we estimate the long run as well as dynamic
relationship and direction of Granger causality between the actual rate
of inflation and the P-star based leading indicator of inflation. The
objective is to test whether P-star model can be used to calculate a
leading indicator of inflation in Pakistan or not.
Implicit assumption of the theory is that there is a long run
relationship between the actual prices and equilibrium prices [Hallman,
et al. (1991)] and it is also assumed that there is a one to one
relationship between both prices. We test these propositions in this
section. To test the existence of cointegrating relationship between the
actual and equilibrium prices we used the Engle-Granger (1987) two step
method written as;
[LP.sub.t] = [alpha] + [beta] [LP.sup.*.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
(8a)
[DELTA][[epsilon].sub.t] - [[rho][[epsilon].sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.1] [[DELTA][[epsilon].sub.t-1] + [[beta].sub.2]
[DELTA][[epsilon].sub.t-2] + ... + [[beta].sub.p]
[DELTA][[epsilon].sub.t-p] + [[mu].sub.t] ... (8b)
where LP is log of price index, [LP.sup.*] is log of equilibrium
prices calculated in the previous section, [[epsilon].sub.t] is the
residual from cointegrating equation and [[mu].sub.t] is the residual
from the Equation 8b of the ADF unit root test which is assumed to be
white noise. The results of the long run Equation 8a--the first step of
Engle-Granger method--are given by Equation 9.
LP = 1.0025 [LP.sup.*] - 0.0118 ... (9)
(87.039) (-0.290)
R-squared 0.994617 Durbin-Watson star 0.655984
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -4.477
Figures in the parentheses show t-statistics
The second step of the Engle-Granger procedure is to test the
hypothesis of unit root in the residual obtained from Equation 9 by
applying the ADF test. If the residual term has no unit roots, i.e., it
is 1(0), then we can conclude that both variables are cointegrated. The
results from the ADF test statistics show that the residual term is
stationary and that implies that there is long run relationship between
the actual prices and the equilibrium prices calculated by the P-star
model. The estimated parameter of the equilibrium price level is close
to one. We formally tested that the estimated parameter is one by
applying Wald test and the results show that there is one to one
relationship between the actual and P-star prices.
The Granger representation theorem states that if there exists a
cointegrating relationship between the two variables then there exists
at least one-way Granger causality between them. This theorem further
implies that if the two series are non-stationary and they have
cointegrating relationship between them then the dynamic system can be
represented by equilibrium correcting mechanism. In the following we
estimate the dynamic relationship by specifying the equilibrium
correcting mechanism (EqCM) and test Granger causality between the
variables.
The dynamic equilibrium correcting model is estimated by applying
general to specific methodology. The results of the preferred dynamic
model for inflation prediction are given by Equation 10.
[INF.sub.t] = 0.9395 [INF.sub.t-1] - 0.275 [EqCM.sub.t-1] (10)
(16.28) (-4.12)
R-squared 0.573
LM Test: [chi square](1) 0.00
Durbin-Watson stat 2.146
ARCH Test: [chi square](1) 0.150
Figures in the parentheses show t-statistics.
It shows that the residual passed all the required diagnostic tests
and the estimated coefficients have a priori expected signs. The
estimated coefficient of [EqCM.sub.t-1] term indicates a speed of
adjustment of the rate of inflation towards the equilibrium state. It
implies that economic agents correct approximately 28 percent of their
errors during one year. The significance of error correction term in the
equation also implies that P-star inflation indicator causes the actual
rate of inflation. More precisely in the words of Granger and others,
the P-star indicator of inflation predicts the future rate of inflation.
From this we can infer that the higher the actual prices from the
equilibrium prices today implies low rate of inflation in the future.
The cointegration analysis and the results of the error correcting
model indicate that there is a causality between the actual inflation
and the P-star model based inflation indicator. The important question
is whether P-star model based measure of inflation can be used as
leading indicator of inflation for forecasting. In order to decide the
sequence of causality (prediction). whether it is unidirectional or
bidirectional, pair wise Granger Causality test is applied. The
hypothesis that P-star model calculated indicator of rate of inflation
does not predict the actual rate of inflation is rejected at five
percent level of significance. The F-values for Granger bivariate causality test is 2.774. When we test for the inverse causality that is
inflation does not Granger causes the P-star inflation indicator, the
hypothesis is accepted implying inflation does not predict the
indicator. On the basis of analysis we can conclude that there is
unidirectional causality that runs from the P-star inflation indicator
to the actual rate of inflation.
5. FORECASTING PERFORMANCE OF THE P-STAR INDICATOR OF INFLATION
Since the main objective of this paper is to develop a leading
indicator of inflation by using P-star model, we performed a forecasting
exercise using the univariate autoregressive model as the benchmark
model. Moreover to compare the forecasting performance of preferred
leading indicator we used money (M2) growth as another leading indicator
of inflation. Currently State Bank of Pakistan is using money growth as
one of the indicators of future inflation. The performance of the P-star
based leading indicator is evaluated with the simulation of out of the
sample forecasting. To get the forecasted value of inflation in Pakistan
we estimated the following equation:
[[pi].sub.t+h] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1]
[[pi].sup.*.sub.t] + [n.summation over (i=[1.sub.1]) [[beta].sub.i]
[[pi].sub.t-i] + [[epsilon].sub.t+h] ... (11)
Where [[pi].sub.t+h] is the h-period ahead inflation and
[[pi].sub.t.sup.*] is an indicator of inflation whose forecasting
performance is being evaluated. The data used for this study, as
mentioned earlier, spans from 1960 to 2003. Out of sample forecasts are
made from 1990 to 2003 (detail results are given in the Table 2). (1)
The forecasting performance is evaluated by the Root Mean Square
Error (RMSE) and the relative RMSE to a simple univariate autoregressive
model. The reduction in RMSE and less than one value of the ratio of the
leading indicator's RMSE corresponds with the benchmark
model's RMSE indicates improvement in the forecasting by using
leading indicator [Stock and Watson (1999)]. The exercise was performed
for forecasts of inflation from 1 to 13 years ahead. The results from
recursive estimation and forecasting performance of autoregressive
model, M2 growth augmented model and the P-star indicator model are
presented in the Table 2. The fourth column of Table 2 reports the Root
Mean Square Error (RMSE) of the univariate autoregressive model and the
fifth column reports forecasting performance of growth in M2 as an
indicator of inflation.
As can be seen from Table 2, the RMSE of M2 growth augmented model
is decreased relative to autoregressive model for 1 to 6 years ahead
forecasting period. It means that for short and medium forecasting time
horizon the M2 growth indicator has additional information about future
rate of inflation than the simple model. However, the forecasting
performance of P-star model indicator shows that in forecasting
inflation the P-star indicator augmented model performs better than the
univariate autoregressive model. The RMSE of P-star indicator augmented
model is less than the RMSE of autoregressive model. The ratio RMSE of
P-star indicator and M2 growth indicator with RMSE of univariate
autoregressive are also calculated and plotted in Figure 3.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
We also compare the forecasting performance of the M2 growth
indicator augmented model and the P-star indicator augmented model by
calculating the ratio of the RMSE of M2 growth model to the P-star
model. If the value of this ratio is less than one it indicates better
performance. As may be seen from the Table 2 and Figure 4, P-star based
indicator of inflation performs better than M2 growth indicator to
forecast future inflation. Thus we can safely conclude that the
indicator calculated by the P-star model can be used as a leading
indicator of inflation in Pakistan.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
6. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Forecasting based on leading indicators has a long history in
economics. Much of the earlier work concentrated on developing
indicators of macroeconomic variables such as inflation. While
forecasting on the basis of leading indicators is also emerging lastly.
One of the leading indicators of inflation is based on the P-star model.
The P-star inflation model is based on the long-term quantity theory of
money and puts together the long-term determinants of the price level
and the short-term changes in current inflation. In this paper we used
the P-star model to calculate the leading indicator of inflation and
also tested the forecasting performance of P-star model based leading
indicator of inflation.
The results of the study show quite clearly that compared to the
simple autoregressive model and M2 growth augmented model the P-star
model can be used to obtain the leading indicator of inflation in
Pakistan because it has additional information about the future rate of
inflation. Therefore, this paper provides a useful tool to the
policy-maker to assess the future movement of inflation in Pakistan.
Finally, in future the research can be extended in following
directions, firstly by using high frequency data i.e., quarterly or
monthly, and secondly by including other indicators of inflation such as
Philips curve, interest rate spread and credit growth and compare the
forecasting performance.
REFERENCES
Bomhoff, E. J. (1990) Stability of Velocity in the Group of Seven
Countries: A Kalman Filter Approach. (September). (IMF Working Paper
(WP/90/80).)
Braun, S. (1990) Estimation of Current Quarter Gross National
Product Pooling Preliminary Labour Market Data. Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics 8, (July), 293-304.
Christiano, L. J. (1981) A Survey of Measures of Capacity
Utilisation. IMF Staff Papers (March), 144-198.
Christiano, L. J. (1989) [P.sup.*]: Not the Inflation
Forecaster's Holy Grail. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis,
Quarterly Review 13, 3-18.
Clements, Michael P., and D. F. Hendry (1998) Forecasting
Non-stationary Economic Time Series. MIT Press.
Ebrill, L. P., and S. M. Fries (1990) The Dynamics of Money Demand
and Prices. (August). (IMF Working Paper 90/75.)
Engle, R. F., and C. W. J. Granger (1987) Cointegration and Error
Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing. Econometrica 50,
251-76.
Federal Bureau of Statistics (Various Issues) Statistical Year
Book. Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Fisher, D., and A. Fleissig (1995) Monetary Aggregates and the
[P.sup.*] Model of Inflation in the United States. Department of
Economics, North Carolina State University. (Working Paper.)
Gibbs, D. (1995) Potential Output: Concepts and Measurement. Labour
Market Bulletin 1, 72-115.
Hallman, J. J., R. D. Porter, and D. H. Small (1989) M2 Per Unit of
Potential GNP as an Anchor for the Price Level. Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System (April). (Staff Study No. 157.)
Hallman, J. J., R. D. Porter, and D. H. Small (1991) Is the Price
Level Tied to the Stock of M2 in the Long-run. American Economic Review
81, 841-858.
Hannah, S., and A. James (1989) P-star as a Monetary Indicator for
the UK. NatWest Capitol Markets (June).
Hodrick, R. J., and E. C. Prescott (1980) Post-war US Business
Cycles: An Empirical Investigation. Evanston, Illinois: Centre for
Mathematical Studies in Economics and Management Science, Northwestern
University. (Discussion Paper No. 451 .)
Hoeller, P., and P. Poret (1991) Is P-Star a Good Indicator of
Inflationary Pressure in OECD Countries. OECD Economic Studies 17.
International Monetary Fund (2004) International Financial
Statistics. IMF.
Kool, C., and J. Tatom (1994) The P-Star Model in Five Economies.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 3.
Kuttner, K. (1992) Monetary Policy with Uncertain Estimates of
Potential Output, Economic Perspective. Federal Reserve Bank Chicago
16:1.
McMarrow, K., and W. Poeger (2001) Potential Output: Measurement
Methods, New Economy Influences and Scenarios for 2001-2010--A
Comparison of the EU15 and the US. (European Commission Economic Papers
No. 150.)
Okun, A. M. (1962) Potential GDP: Its Measurement and Significance.
Proceedings of the Business and Economic Statistics Section, American
Statistical Association 98-104.
Orphanides, A., and R. D. Porter (2000) [P.sup.*] Revisited:
Money-Based Inflation Forecasts with a Changing Equilibrium Velocity.
Journal of Economics and Business 52, 87-100.
Pecchenino, R. A., and R. H. Rasche (1990) [P.sup.*] Type Models:
Evaluation and Forecasts. (August). (NBER Working Papers Series No.
3406.)
Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson (2001) Forecasting Output and
Inflation: The Role of Asset Prices. (NBER Working Paper No. 8180.)
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson (1999) Forecasting Inflation.
Journal of Monetary Economics 44, 293-335.
(1) The forecasting performance of the P-star model-based leading
indicator of inflation did not improve significantly by considering the
1973 inflation as an outlier.
Abdul Qayyum is Associate Professor at the Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad Faiz Bilquees is Joint Director at the
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Statistic
Variables Test Statistics Lag t-value P-value
LV Constant 1 -1.978088 0.2950
[DELTA]LV None 0 -5.047787 0.0000
LP-star Constant, Trend 0 -3.221457 0.0941
[DELTA]LP-star Constant 0 -5.355803 0.0001
LP Constant, Trend 1 -3.412787 0.0636
[DELTA]LP Constant 1 -3.522934 0.0124
P-star Inflation None 1 -4.431786 0.0000
Table 2
Forecasting Performance of the P-Star Indicator of Inflation
Estimation Forecasting
Period Period h-step
1960-1990 1990-2003 13
1960-1991 1991-2003 12
1960-1992 1992-2003 11
1960-1993 1993-2003 10
1960-1994 1994-2003 9
1960-1995 1995-2003 8
1960-1996 1996-2003 7
1960-1997 1997-2003 6
1960-1998 1998-2003 5
1960-1999 1999-2003 4
1960-2000 2000-2003 3
1960-2001 2001-2003 2
1960-2002 2002-2003 1
Root Mean Square Error
Estimation Autoregres- M2 Growh P-star
Period sive indicator
1960-1990 0.020 0.0208 0.0189
1960-1991 0.021 0.0215 0.0177
1960-1992 0.0202 0.0190 0.0143
1960-1993 0.0208 0.0196 0.0150
1960-1994 0.0213 0.0196 0.0234
1960-1995 0.0204 0.0209 0.0160
1960-1996 0.0214 0.0226 0.0170
1960-1997 0.0232 0.0225 0.0167
1960-1998 0.0232 0.0203 0.0175
1960-1999 0.0182 0.0129 0.0111
1960-2000 0.0193 0.0132 0.0094
1960-2001 0.0228 0.0156 0.0066
1960-2002 0.0162 0.0159 0.0093
Ratio of RMSE
Estimation M2 / P-star / P-star /
Period Auto Auto M2
1960-1990 1.04 0.945 0.90865
1960-1991 1.023809 0.842857 0.82325
1960-1992 0.940594 0.707920 0.75263
1960-1993 0.942307 0.721153 0.76530
1960-1994 0.920187 0.774647 0.84183
1960-1995 1.024509 0.784313 0.76555
1960-1996 1.056074 0.794392 0.75221
1960-1997 0.969827 0.719827 0.74222
1960-1998 0.875 0.754310 0.86206
1960-1999 0.708791 0.609890 0.86046
1960-2000 0.683937 0.487046 0.71212
1960-2001 0.684210 0.289473 0.42307
1960-2002 0.981481 0.574074 0.58490