Economics of regaining office: the case of Pakistan (1947-2005).
Akram, Muhammad Shahid ; Azid, Toseef
1. INTRODUCTION
Political business cycle (PBC) can be defined as fluctuations in
the economy due to an attempt of a government to manipulate the economy
prior to elections for favourable outcomes i.e. regaining its office.
The concept of policy cycles gained a good deal of attention by the
economists during mid 70s. Though most of the researchers attribute the
PBC theory to Schumpeter (1939) and Kalecki (1943) but the seminal work in the theory of PBC is Nordhaus (1975).
The literature on PBC sets these foundations for the topic:
(i) The incumbent politicians want to regain their office,
(ii) This requires how well the economy is doing especially at the
time of election,
(iii) The incumbent politicians have, at their disposal, certain
policy instruments, which at least partially determine the macroeconomic performance of the economy.
Above-mentioned points state the intuitive plausibility of the idea
that the governments attempt to manipulate the economy prior to the
elections to have the office again. In addition, to above-mentioned
points, believe in governments stabilisation power itself is believe in
government's power to destabilise.
Traditional Approach investigates the uniform and systematic
engineered business cycles for its belief in "similar
incentives" for all incumbents to manipulate the economy at the
event of all elections where as Rational Expectations Thesis rejects the
possibility of PBC on the assumption of increasingly sophisticated ideas
about the behaviour of voters else then the incumbent politicians
[Schultz (1995)]. Yet both the models present a limited insight into the
very foundation of theory of PBC. Away from intuitive plausibility of
idea empirical record of the theory is spotty at best. A good deal of
this spotty record may be due to different assumptions underlying the
different empirical investigation [Whynes (1989)]. To resolve the
dilemma one is required to revise the existing text first. (1)
Till its birth the literature on political business cycle has
attracted a good number of researchers. The early spotty record of
empirical investigation caused a many economists to ignore the topic for
further inquiry despite of the intuitive plausibility of idea [Schultz
(1995)]. On the other hand the interest of many economists kept on
refining the intellectual fabric of the literature on political business
cycle. The basic model of PBC developed by Nordhaus (1975) along with
the preceding development in the theory of political business cycle.
The existing literature on PBC can be categorised under two
headings: the Opportunistic PBC theory [Nordhaus (1975)] and the
Partisan theory of PBC [Hibbs (1977)]. The literature on PBC can be
classified further as: the monetary PBC and the Fiscal Approach to PBC.
The story starts with Nordhaus (1975), who proposed a model of political
intervention to create a pre-election boom for harvesting the election
outcomes favourably. Later, Hibbs (1977) proposed the influence of party
affiliation on polices adopted by the incumbent president towards the
aim of being re-elected. The said theories tried monetary variables for
empirical investigation. Both models based heavily on the notion of a
retrospective or myopic voters or simply an irrational voter who can be
fooled easily every time. This shortcoming led to the emergence of the
concept of Rational Expectations in the PBC literature. Cukierman and
Meltzer (1987) developed a model of PBC based on Rational Expectations.
Alesina (1987, 1988) developed a Rational Partisan Theory. The fourth
generation of PBC models is driven by Rogoff's model of Political
Budget Cycles (1990). Rogoff's model evidently emphasized the power
of fiscal instruments on behalf of an incumbent in engineering a
business cycle. The most recent version of a Political Budget Cycle
Model is Active Fiscal and Passive Monetary (AFPM) model of Drazen
(2000).
Alesina (1989), Alesina and Roubini (1990), Cohen and Roubini
(1991), Alesina (1992) argues for rational models to analysis
politically motivated manipulation of the economic policies. Alesina and
Roubini (1992) regressed OECD countries quarterly data during 1960 to
1987 on GNP growth, unemployment and inflation against election timings
and of changing of governments and political affiliations of different
governments for implications of both types of models: OPBC and RPT. They
concluded that most recent models performed more rigorously. Beck (1988)
argues that normally a clear OPBC is not observed because it is
exceedingly hard to time economic manipulation. Dinkel (1981) rejects
the presence of OPBC in Germany. Dinkel deems the theoretic of OPBC
plausible, yet empirical investigation rejected the possibility of OPBC.
The present study, first of its breed, aims to explore any
possibility of politically motivated business cycles in Pakistan. More
precisely do incumbents- politicians, technocrats or military Lords-
ever tried to manipulate the economy prior to elections for favourable
outcome, in Pakistan through the history. The study will employ the
Opportunistic Political Business Cycle (OPBC) approach for this purpose,
where OPBC stands for the absence of party affiliation of the incumbent.
The data on the Real Money Supply (RM) and Real Exchange Rate (ER), from
1973-Q1 to 2005-Q4 will be used for the present analysis as dependent
variables and the election timings will be the cause variable. (2)
2. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK OF THE STUDY
The Nordhausian theoretic of PBC (1975) or more specifically the
Opportunistic Political Business Cycle is the first seminal work in the
theory of PBC and still remains one of the most frequently investigated
concepts of the literature on PBC. This traditional approach to measure
any politically motivated manipulation of the economy is undoubtedly not
only easy to employ but also rigours in its results especially in
developing world context. Though the relatively modern approaches to PBC
investigation promise some deeper analysis of the topic, but on the same
time these call for relatively sophisticated data, which is normally
either not collected or highly non-reliable in most of the developing
nations on account for unavailability of funds, skilled working force in
the field and most seriously non-respondent public.
2.1. Assumptions of Nordhaus' Political Business Cycle (3)
(1) An expectations- augmented Philips Curve describes the economy
(2) Voters are retrospective and myopic
(3) Expectations of the voters are adaptive
(4) Politicians are opportunistic
(5) They control certain policy instruments
(6) The timings of elections are exogenously fixed.
Yet the case of Pakistan differs from Nordhausian assumption of
exogenously fixed election timings. In Pakistan, the case of premature
democracy- if we consider a very less number of publicly elected
governments and civil and military dissolution of governments- the
election timings are not exogenously set. To include endogenously set
election timings in the model the research will follow Lachelar (1982),
Ito (1990) and Asutay (2004) who used the notion of endogenously set
timings for elections under certain reasoning such as:
(1) Early election calls to reap good economic conditions
(2) Early election calls for increasing function of high economic
growth
(3) Non-imposition of fixed time of election by laws or
constitution.
Yet there are studies, for example Nordhaus (1975), Paldam (1979
and 1983), Soh (1986) etc. investigating OPBC model in various cases
without making the setting of election date as a particular issue.
3. EMPIRICAL MODELLING AND SPECIFICATIONS
To estimate OPBC of Nordhaus type in monetary instruments, the
coming lines will summarize the model and specifications.
3.1. Modelling
The study will employ Box- Tiao intervention analysis [Box-Tiao
(1975)] to capture any manipulation of fiscal policy prior to elections
for favourable outcomes or to find if election timings bear additional
explanation of fluctuations in the monetary policy instruments as
suggested by Beck (1982, 1987).
3.2. Capturing the Impact of Elections
Beck (1982 and 1987) on the basis of Box-Tiao's (1975)
intervention analysis suggests following standard dummy variables to
capture the impact of election timing on the policy instruments which
are also known election dummies: the standard electoral dummies and
their respective definitions are as follow:
ED1 = 1 in the election quarter = 0 otherwise
ED2 = 1 in one quarter prior to an election and election quarter =
0 otherwise
ED3 = 1 in two quarters prior to an election and election quarter =
0 otherwise
ED4 = 1 in three quarters prior to an election and election quarter
= 0 otherwise
ED5 = 1 in three quarters after an election = 0 otherwise
The dummies defined above aim for capturing any possible
significance of the election timings on the economic policy. In brief
ED1 stands for impact of elections on economic policy right before the
elections i.e. the election-quarter itself. ED2 bears some extra
explanation of effects of elections i.e. it aims on capturing the impact
of elections on economic policy one quarter before an election on the
assumption that the election may held in the start of the election
quarter or the incumbent aims on timing the manipulation of the policy
towards election eve. ED3, by including the time of two quarter prior to
election shares the responsibility of ED2. ED4 shares the same
responsibility, as by its predecessors, in three quarter prior to an
election. Where as the dummy ED5 stands to capture the expected down
fall of the economy due to engineered boom via policy manipulation for
reaping the election outcome.
3.3. Expected Signs of the Dummies Introduced
The coefficients of the dummies explained above on the basis of
Box-Tiao' (1975) intervention analysis have the following expected
signs which are best possible approximation to capture the said
intervention.
Coefficient of ED1 should be a positive for a PBC to present
Coefficient of ED2 should be a positive for a PBC to present
Coefficient of ED3 should be a positive for a PBC to present
Coefficient of ED4 should be a positive for a PBC to present
Coefficient of ED5 should be a negative for a PBC to present
3.4. The Data and the Source of the Data
The series are constructed as follows. The real exchange rate is
the relative inflation adjusted exchange rate, and is constructed by
multiplying the nominal exchange rate by the ratio of consumer price
indexes (e.g. RER=(PAK/USA)*(CPI US/CPI PAK). The real money supply
series are obtained by deflating the money supply series with the
consumer price indexes; CPIs are convened into common base of 1995.
Prior to the estimation all variables are transformed into natural
logarithms. Data span from 1973-Q1 to 2005-Q4, providing series of 132
observations. All the series are obtained from international financial
statistics (IFS) up to 1998; from 1998 to 2003 the series are obtained
from statistical bulletin of government of Pakistan, finance division.
3.5. Limitations on the Data
As the present study is based on secondary data, so one should keep
in mind the limitations on data in developing countries like Pakistan,
where meagre resources are employed to generate data. The situation
presented above leads to many problems such as non-reliability, limited
availability, unavailability of data for sophisticated analysis etc. The
problem of limited availability of quarterly data, which is highly
important to capture the impact of elections on economic variables, is
one of the major hurdles for present study, which has limited the time
of study from 1973 to 2005.
3.6. The Politico-economic Models
In general form the Politico-economic or even more relaxingly the
economic models for both the dependent variables are:
3.7. Real Money Supply (RM) and Election Timings
RMt = f(RMt-i, ED1, ED2, ED3, ED4, ED5; [??]i) ... (5.1)
Where RM is supply of real money in the economy, ED1 to ED5 are the
standard electoral dummies and [??]i's are the unknown parameters
associated with independent variables in the model.
3.8. Real Exchange Rate (ER) and Election Timings
RE t = f(Ret-i, ED1; [??]i) ... (5.2)
Where ER is real exchange rate, ED1 is the standard electoral dummy
and [??]i's are the unknown parameters associated with independent
variables in the model.
3.9. The Hypotheses
In the following line, hypothesis in both null and alternative
forms is presented.
H0: The incumbents in Pakistan did not manipulate the economic
policy tools for political motives i.e. for favourable outcomes in
elections.
H1: The incumbents in Pakistan manipulated the economic policy
tools for political motives i.e. for favourable outcomes in elections.
4. ESTIMATION AND INTERPRETATION
The first step in the estimation of a model with time series data
is to ensure the stationarity of the series involved as more of the
macroeconomic time series follow a long-run trend. The implication of
this long-run trend would be the invalidity of the significance test
applied on OLS estimates [Price (1998)], for this purpose Unit Root test
is employed to the both series. The results of Augmented Dickey-Fuller
for Unit Root test of the Real Money Supply and the Real Exchange Rate
series suggest that each series is stationary of the first difference.
One must remember that before applying unit root test the natural
logarithm for each of the series is developed. On the basis of the
results of Augmented Dickey-Fuller the study is modelled into Auto
Regressive Moving Average (ARMA), whereas AR(1) is utilised as more
parsimonious benchmark model following Gujarati's advice (2005).
The results for all models are reported in Appendix B. The slope
coefficients of variables responsible for capturing the possible
political intervention in forming economic policy in all the models bear
the required positive signs for the presence of a politically motivated
business cycle, which according to Box-Tiao's (1975) intervention
analysis are signs of politically motivated manipulation of economic
policy in the respective quarters, as mentioned earlier. But all the
results failed to qualify the significance test, which leads to the
rejection of idea of presence of PBC in Pakistan. The one exception for
the required signs is the result of the model 5, which contains
electoral dummy ED5, the sign of the slope coefficient of ED5 must be a
negative according to the Box-Tiao's (1975) intervention analysis
for presence of a PBC. Yet the sign of this slope coefficient is
positive which suggest the absence of PBC, but this result too, is not
statistically significant which indicates an arise of little anomaly
which is contradictory to the results of other models estimated by the
study. The four estimations of the RM model, else than that of the model
with electoral dummy ED5, and the estimation of the RE model have
rejected the presence of PBC in Pakistan for the insignificant results,
in the light of these results, though a little loosely, the study
recognizes an overall rejection of the idea of presence of a politically
motivated business in Pakistan, as on the basis of one spot in favour of
the presence of PBC, the other five results, which are in contrast of
this single result, can not be rejected.
5. CONCLUSION
Though the intuitive plausibility of the idea of politically
motivated intervention in economic policies enjoys high esteem in common
as well as critical intellect yet the present study could not find any
traces of politically motivated manipulation of economic policy or
political business cycle in Pakistan during the span of time selected
for investigation. As reported earlier that some of the signs of slope
coefficients suggest the symptoms of manipulation of economic policy yet
the results could not qualify the regarding test for significance of the
estimates. One of the strongest reasons for rejection of, intellectually
strong, idea is itself the political history of Pakistan. Pakistan could
never enjoy a politically stable scene in its life. (4) Time and again
it has been under nonelected rules, which has caused the political
behaviour in Pakistan to be immature. Although economic policy tools
seems to be attractive in regaining political power or office but the
rulers in Pakistan seem to be using some other tools for being in office
or to regain their office. The limited nature of the present study
doesn't allow for some other dimensions of enquiry such as Rational
Expectations thesis, Partisan Theory of PBC, Equilibrium Political
Budget Cycle Theory, AFPM Model etc. Yet the study opens up new horizons
to evaluate and investigate, critically, the interplay of economics and
politics in Pakistan with its history and limitations on its past such
as unavailability of data or to devise the tools for using available
data set etc. This also requires some empirical techniques to be
developed for investigating the data type available in Pakistan and
other developing countries facing similar limitations in the field of
data availability. One recommendation in light of the present
investigation is that political process must be given proper time to
make itself mature and interruption in political process must end now.
This is not to say to give a way to politicians to make the economy
unstable on their political desires that is to regain their office or to
stuck with the office unlawfully but to say that a smooth political
scene can help the country enjoy a calm economic and social scene.
REFERENCES
Alesina, A. (1992) Political Models of Macroeconomic Policy and
Fiscal Reforms. Country Economic Department. The World Bank. (Working
Papers.)
Alt, J., and A. Chrystal (1983) Political Economy. Berkeley CA:
Berkeley University Press.
Asutay, M. (2004) Searching for Opportunistic Political Business
Cycles in Turkey. Presented at the Annual Conference of the European
Public Choice Society.
Asutay, M. (2005) Political Monetary Cycles: The Political
Manipulation of Monetary Policy Instruments and Outcomes in Turkey.
Presented at the Annual Conference of the European Public Choice
Society.
Bartels, L. M., and J. Zaller (2001) Presidential Vote Models: A
Recount. PS: Political Science and Politics 34:1, 8-20.
Box, G. E. P., and G. C. Tiao (1975) Interventional Analysis with
Applications to Economic and Environmental Problems. Journal of the
American Statistical Association 70:349, 70-79.
Burki, S. J. (1998) Is Pakistan's Past Relevant for Its
Economic Future? Edited by Craig Baxter and Charles H. Kennedy, Pak Book
Corporation Pakistan.
Cartwright, P.A., and C. D. DeLorme Jr. (1985) The
Unemployment-inflation-voter Utility Relationship in the Political
Business Cycle: Some Evidence. Southern Economic Journal 51:3, 898-905.
Drazen, A. (2000a) Political Economy in Macroeconomics. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Drazen, A. (2000b) The AFPM Model of the Political Business Cycle:
Theory and Evidence. (Working Paper.)
Drazen, A. (2000) The Political Business Cycle After 25 Years.
University of Maryland, Hebrew University of Jerusalem, and NBER.
Fair, R. (1978) The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for
President. Review of Eeonomics and Statistics 60, 159-72.
Fair, R. (1982) The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for
President: 1980 Results. Review of Economies and Statistics 64, 322-25.
Fair, R. (1988) The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for
President: 1984 Update. Political Behaviour 10, 168-79.
Gregory, A. W., and G. W. Smith (1995) Business Cycle Theory and
Econometrics. The Economic Journal 105:433, 1597-1608.
Haynes, S. E., and J. A. Stone (1994) Political Parties and the
Variable Duration of Business Cycles. Southern Economic Journal 60:4,
869-885.
Hibbs, D. (1977) Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy.
American Political Science.
Ito, T. (1990) The Timing of Elections and Political Business
Cycles in Japan. Journal of Asian Economics 1, 135-156.
Keech, W., and K. Pak (1989) Electoral Cycles and Budgetary Growth
in Veterans' Benefit Programmes. American Journal of Political
Science 33, 901-11.
Keil, M. W. (1988) Is the Political Business Cycle Really Dead?
Southern Economic Journal 55:1, 86-99.
Khan, H. (2005) Constitution and political history of Pakistan.
Karachi: Oxford University Press.
Maloney, K. J., and M. L. Smirlock (1981) Business Cycle and the
Political Process. Southern Economic Journal 48:2, 377-392.
McCallum, B. (1978) The Political Business Cycle: An Empirical
Test. Southern Economic Journal 42, 501-15.
McClelland, P. D. (1984) The Presidential Political Business Cycle
of 1972: Discussion. The Journal of Economic History 44:2, The Tasks of
Economic History, 273-376.
McGarrity, J. P., and K. B. Grier (1998) The Effect of
Macroeconomic Fluctuations on the Electoral Fortunes of House
Incumbents. Journal of Law and Economics 41:1, 143-161.
McKelvey, R. D., and R. T. Boylan (1995) Voting over Economic
Plans. The American Economic Review 85:4, 860-871.
McRae, D. (1977) A Political Model of the Business Cycle. Journal
of Political Economic Journal 85, 239-63.
Nordhaus, W. (1975) The Political Business Cycle. Review of
Economic Studies 42, 169-90.
Persson, T. (2002) Do Political Institutions Shape Economic Policy?
Econometrica 70:3, 883-905.
Ploeg, F. V. D. (1989) The Political Economy of Overvaluation. The
Economic Journal 99:397, 850-855.
Poterba, J. M., and D. G. Golden (1980) The Price of Popularity:
The Political Business Cycle Reexamined. American Journal of Political
Science 24:4, 696-714.
Richards, D. J. (1986) Unanticipated Money and the Political
Business Cycle. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 18:4, 447-457.
Rogoff, K. (n.d.) Equilibrium Political Budget Cycles. The American
Economic Review 80:1, 21-36.
Rogoff, K., and A. Sibert (1988) Elections and Macroeconomic Policy
Cycles. Review of Economic Studies 55, 1-16.
Roubbini, A. A. N. (1992) Political Cycles in OECD Economies. The
Review of Economic Studies 59:4, 663-688.
Sadiq, N. (1997) Social Change--The Essence of Development. The
Pakistan Development Review 26:4, 315-320.
Schultz, K. A. (1995) The Politics of the Political Business Cycle.
British Journal of Political Sciences 25:1, 79-99.
Tufte, E. (1975) Determinants of the Outcomes of Midterm Congressional Elections. American Political Science Review 69, 812-26.
Zaidi, Akbar (2005) Issues in Pakistan's Economy. (Second
Edition). Karachi: Oxford University Press.
Comments
This paper tests the hypothesis of political business cycles due to
Nordhaus (1975). The political business cycles are described as
fluctuations in the economy caused by the incumbent government's
manipulations prior to elections in order to regain office. Using
Box-Tiao intervention analysis to capture manipulations of fiscal and/or
monetary policy prior to election, the paper does not find support for
this hypothesis in the case of Pakistan for the time period 1973-2005.
My main worry is that these Western-based theories may not be
applicable to the Pakistani case. The political business cycle theory
implies very subtle manipulations, through various policy instruments at
the disposal of the government. Pakistan has a different political
history with altogether different modes of intervention and tactics by
the government to regain office. Pakistan has experienced very direct
modes of government intervention--the nationalisation experiment of the
Bhutto regime; and also very ambitious programmes by various democratic
regimes to woe the voters (the People's Programme, the Yellow Cab Scheme). There is nothing subtle about these schemes. Successive
Pakistani governments have also been accused of trying many illegal ways
to regain office-election engineering, results manipulations etc. Though
the authors take notice of the fact that Pakistan has had a political
history of being ruled by non-elected rulers, and also that the
government must be using different tools to regain office, it would be
interesting to see if the authors come up with an 'indigenous'
method of analysis that better suits the case of Pakistan.
Lubna Hasan Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Muhammad Shahid Akrarn <
[email protected]> is currently
enrolled as a PhD student at Bhauddin Zakariya University, Multan.
Toseef Azid is Fulbright Fellow at Social and Behavioural Sciences
Division, El Camino Community College, Torrance, CA. USA.
(1) For comprehensive details on the exiting literature, one may
consult Alesina, et al. (1991), Alesina (1992), and Drazen (2002).
(2) A table of election timing is given in Appendix A.
(3) For details see Nordhaus (1975), Alesina and Roubini (1992),
Alesina, et al. (1993, 1997), Drazen (2000) and Asutay (2004).
(4) For a review of Pakistan's political and economic history,
the study relied heavily on Sadik (1997), Burki (1998), Khan (2005),
Zaidi (2005).
Appendix A
Table 1
A Table of Election Date in Pakistan *
20 December, 1971 4th quarter
February, 1977 1st quarter
19 December, 1988 4th quarter
February, 1985 1st quarter
November, 1988 4th quarter
October, 1990 4th quarter
October, 1993 4th quarter
February, 1997 1st quarter
October, 2002 4th quarter
* The table is developed by the authors with the help of different
sources, which are mentioned in the bibliography. * It must be
remembered that all the general elections as well as referenda, over
the time under investigstion, are included in the study
Appendix B
Table 2
Autoregressive RM and ER, 1973Q1-1005Q3
Dependent Variable: Logged RM (NLRM)
Logged ER (NLER) *
Model l Model 2
Coeff. t-statis. Coeff. t-statis.
Constant 0.338852 2.784465 0.338073 2.758874
NLRM(1) 0.955416 64.79810 0.955535 64.15002
NLER (1)
EDl 0.004003 0.113094
ED2 0.000796 0.029354
ED3
ED4
ED5
Diagnostic Tests
[R.sup.2] 0.975733 0.975730
AIC -1.720858 -1.720746
SBC -1.646784 -1.646672
F-stat 2131.020 2130.775
DW 2.227034 2.225260
Model 3 Model 4
Coeff. t-statis. Coeff. t-statis.
Constant 0.327069 2.728233 0.349769 2.898397
NLRM(1) 0.957684 65.94241 0.953487 65.15040
NLER (1)
EDl
ED2
ED3 0.042278 0.5 0.032258
ED4 1.238707
ED5 0.004918 0.132392
Diagnostic Tests
[R.sup.2] 0.976301 0.976076
AIC -1.744561 -1.735109
SBC -1.670487 -1.661035
F-stat 2183.406 2162.368
DW 2.191022 2.156685
Model 5 Model 6
Coeff. t-statis. Coeff. t-statis.
Constant 0.338095 2.789474 0.024520 0.793988
NLRM(1) 0.955504 65016894
NLER (1) 0.989200 108.2485
EDl 0.006148 0.473764
ED2
ED3
ED4
ED5
Diagnostic Tests
[R.sup.2] 0.975734 0.991107
AIC -1.720903 -3.72010
SBC -1.646829 3.646337
F-stat 2131.118 5906.741
DW 2.224813 1.813939
Notes: Coeff.: Coefficient; t-statis.: r-statistics; [R.sup.2] :
Coefficient of Determination; AIC: Akaike Information Criterion; SBC:
Schwarz Bayesian Criterion; F-scat: F-Distribution Test; DW:
Durbin-Watson d Statistics.