Determinants of exports in developing countries.
Majeed, Muhammad Tariq ; Ahmad, Eatzaz
I. INTRODUCTION
According to the orthodox classical economist as well to the modern
liberal view trade is equivalent to an engine of economic growth.
Exports promotion strategy is often in accordance with the principle of
comparative advantage, when a country specialises in a product, which it
can produce competitively. The goods become available to the community
of the world at cheaper prices. The markets are extended. The internal
and external economies are attained. Income and employment levels
expand. Consequently process of economic development is facilitated. In
a nutshell, putting more emphasis on the promotion of exports would
permit the optimal allocation of world resources and, therefore, returns
from trade sector depend upon accelerating growth of exports.
The proposition of FDI led exports growth is controversial in
empirical literature. But the role of domestic investment is believed to
be much important for export expansion strategies. In any case the
importance of FDI, if any, cannot diminish the role of productive
investment from the domestic economy. While private domestic investment
can be regarded as a permanent and reliable channel to enhance
production capacity, investment in public sector has been considered
important, for example in roads, communication and other public goods
and services that are essential to stimulate private investment.
Furthermore, government has a decisive role through support for research
and contract with foreign buyers as well as in facilitating access to
credit to both directly and indirectly exporting terms.
Funke and Holly (1992) argue that the majority of the previous
approaches have emphasised demand factors. Such models have generally
been rather unsuccessful in explaining long run trends in export
performance. (1) The study takes into account both supply side and
demand side factors and applies the model to the West German
manufacturing sector using quarterly data over the period 1961.1 to
1987.4. The findings of the study suggest that supply side factors are
much more important for explaining export performance than demand side
factors.
Togan (1993) investigates the changes in the structure of export
incentives in Turkey from 1983 to 1990. The export incentives are export
credits, tax rebate scheme, premium from the "Support and Price
Stabilisation Fund", duty free imports of intermediates and raw
materials, and exemption from the value added tax, foreign exchange
allocations, exemption from the corporate income tax and other
subsidies. The study finds that during the 1980s the level of the
economy-wide subsidy rates and that of inter-industry dispersion of
incentives has substantially been lowered. The study also finds that the
Turkish export- and import-competing industries have benefited from the
export incentives more than the other sectors.
In a comprehensive study Riedel, Hall and Grawe (1984) investigate
quantitatively the determinants of export performance in India on the
basis of time-series analysis over the period 1968-1978. The study
analyses the effects of relative price of exports, relative domestic
demand and domestic profitability on export performance. The dependent
variable used is the ratio of indexes of constant price exports to
industrial production. Exports are expressed as a ratio to output in
order to account for the effect of expansion of production capacity. The
results support the view that domestic market conditions strongly
influence export behaviour. The variable measuring domestic
profitability or relatively domestic demand is found to be statistically
significant in explaining export behavior in 23 of 30 sectors. Relative
price, incorporating export policy incentives and the exchange rate turn
out to be statistically significant in only 10 of the 30 sectors.
However, relative prices tended to be significant in those sectors where
comparative advantage is presumed to be strongest, for example,
ready-made garments, carpet weaving, handicrafts and metal products. The
study has the loophole of using short period. It requires a long period
for better estimates.
A more recent study of Sharma (2001) investigates exports
determinant in India using annual data for 1970-98. The study uses
simultaneous equation framework. The results of study suggest that
demand for Indian exports increase when its export price falls in
relation to world prices. Furthermore, the real appreciation of the
rupee adversely effects Indian exports. Exports supply is positively
related to the domestic relative price of exports and higher domestic
demand reduces export supply. Foreign investors appear to have
statistically no significant impact on export performance, although the
coefficient of FDI has a positive sign.
Hoekman and Djankov (1998) analyse the magnitude of change in the
export structure in Central and Eastern European countries. The study
investigates the relative importance of processing (subcontracting)
trade, imports of input, and FDI as determinants of the countries'
export performance in European Union markets. The findings of the study
suggest that in most countries export of intermediate goods and
machinery drive the changes in export structure. Local enterprises
apparently exploit the opportunity to acquire foreign inputs and
know-how in order to improve production quality, thereby expanding their
export market share in the European Union.
The study observes that FDI has been concentrated in the sectors
where the Central and Eastern European countries do not have a revealed
comparative advantage (that is, they are not relatively specialised in
terms of their export share in Eastern Union markets). Of the five
countries for which data are available, Poland is the only one with a
significant positive association between FDI and exports structure. The
negative relationship for the other countries implies that FDI could be
a force for change. Foreign investors must perceive the industries
concerned to be viable in the median term, and over time this FDI may
lead to greater changes in the countries' export composition. Thus
FDI complements efforts by domestic industries to restructure and
upgrade production facilities.
It appears from the above review that studies on export
determinants are mostly based on country specific factors as export
expansion schemes, subsidies, etc. There is hardly any study that
conducted panel data estimation on export determinants for a large
number of developing countries.
The present study aims to find out the internal and external
determinants of export promotion in a large set of developing countries.
In this study we will follow panel data estimation procedure for 75
developing countries. The rest of the discussion is organised as
follows: Section II explains the model and framework of analysis:
Section III introduces the data set and the construction of variables.
Section IV puts forward the main findings from empirical analysis.
Section V presents a summary results with some policy implications.
II. METHODOLOGY
In this chapter, we formulate a framework of analysis to determine
the effects of various factors on exports in developing countries, which
we have taken in our sample. The underlying objective is to explain the
rational behind exports.
In the export function we consider all those factors that can
potentially play a meaningful role in the determination of exports in
the developing countries. Export promotion strategies have a great deal
in trade liberalisation regime. On one hand, developing countries are
facing twin deficits, namely, fiscal deficit and trade deficit. On the
other hand, external debt crises create further financial problems. In
such sorry state of financial crises, the sole of FDI inflow is not
sufficient. But the expansion of export sector for the improvement of
financial disturbance also needs to be addressed. In this respect, we
identify various determinants of exports. Export growth is basically
determined by external factors, for this we employ two variables FDI and
real exchange rate. However, exports are also affected by domestic
factors. In this respect we incorporate GDP, GDP growth rate, indirect
taxes, communication facilities, savings, industrialisation, labour
force and official development assistance. Specified equation for export
promotion is as follow.
[EX.sub.it]= f([FDI.sub.it] [GDP.sub.it] [GROW.sub.it] [SAV.sub.it]
[OD.sub.it] [IT.sub.it] [EXCH.sub.it], [TV.sub.it] [TP.sub.it]
[VAD.sub.it] [LF.sub.it]), ... (2)
where the subscript i (=l, ... n) represents country and t (= 1,
... T) the period of time (years). The variables appearing in the
equation are defined as follows.
EX = Exports as a percentage of GDP,
FDI = Foreign Direct Investment as a percentage of GDP,
GDP = Gross domestic production in constant prices of 1989,
GROW = Annual percentage growth rate of GDP,
SA V = National savings as a percentage of GDP,
OD = Official development assistance as a percentage of GDP,
IT = Indirect taxes as a percentage of GDP,
EXCH = Real exchange rate. It is obtained by multiplying the
nominal exchange rate by US CPI and divided by domestic CPI,
TV = Number of televisions per 1000 persons,
TP = Number of telephones per 1000 persons,
VAD = Industry value added as a percentage of GDP,
LF = Total labour force,
Justification of Exports Determinants
Production Level
It is the supply side determinant of exports [see Bertil (1968)].
The higher level of production is the main cause of export expansion,
because surplus of output can be exhausted in international markets. [n
a close economy surplus of production leads to fall in prices, which, in
turn, creates pessimism among producers. In an open economy such
surpluses create foreign reserves by exporting production. So we expect
the positive impact of GDP on exports growth. In empirical literature
Kumar (1998) confirms the positive impact of GDP on exports.
Production Growth
Growth of the GDP is an indicator of future potential and
sustainability of production level. Growth is more valid determinant of
exports as compare to GDP because it measures the sustainability of
output levels. So we expect positive impact of GDP growth on exports
expansion.
Real Exchange Rate
A fall in the relative domestic prices due to exchange rate
depreciation makes exports cheaper in international markets resulting in
increased demand for exports, therefore we expect the positive impact of
real exchange rate on export growth.
Communication Facilities
In this era, when time is shrinking, the importance of
communication facilities has become more important. For the measurement
of communication facilities we employ two variables, namely, the number
of television sets and the number of telephones sets in use. These two
variables have also been justified in empirical literature [Kumar
(1998)]. Expansion of such facilities has favourable effect for
exploration and excess to the world markets. Hence we expect the
positive impact of provision of such facilities.
Indirect Taxes
The effect of this variable is expected to be adverse on production
decisions. But we cannot rule out the possibility of positive effect on
exports due to fiscal incentives by government. Specifically, if
government provides tax exemptions for the expansion of exports sector,
higher rate of indirect taxes can have the negative effect on domestic
demand resulting in exportable surplus.
Official Development Assistance
Large size of official development assistance implies is likely to
facilitate growth of infrastructure, which in turn will favourably
affect investment climate. We expect positive effect of this variable on
export growth.
Savings
Generally, in developing countries the proportion of savings used
for nonproductive factors, for example purchasing of jewellery,
property, etc. is larger. Therefore higher savings result is large
volume of goods made available for exports. So we expect positive impact
of this variable on exports.
Industrialisation
The agricultural output is subjected to uncertainty, particularly
because of operation of nature's vagaries. Accordingly, now a day,
just on the basis of agricultural output no country has greater incomes
and outputs. On the other hand, it is the industrialisation that results
in maximum utilisation of natural and human resources of the country and
industrial output is more or less stable. Thus industrialisation will
provide greater stimulus to output and national income of the country,
Industrialisation also promotes agriculture sector and agriculture
uplifts the industrial sector. The industrial development will have the
effect of developing the allied and related sectors.
The situation of persistent deficit in balance of payments is
attributed to concentration in agriculture exports, falling prices of
exports, the imports restrictions by rich countries and the increasing
import bill due to increased demand for oil and manufactured products,
etc. Through industrialisation a country can enhance industrial
production; replace the agriculture exports by the industrial exports,
which command reasonable and stable prices in the world markets.
Moreover, industrialisation reduces dependence on imports by initiating
the process of import substitution. Keeping in view all such arguments,
we conclude that industrialisation has favourable effect on exports.
Labour Force
Optimum utilisation of resources depends upon the labour force.
Labour force positively determines production levels. In developing
countries large volume of labour force in agriculture sector can be
transferred in industrial sector without affecting the output of
agriculture sector, because this sector is confronted with the problem
of disguised unemployment. Such labour force can be properly utilised in
industrial sector that in turn expand export sector. In empirical
literature, Pfaffermayr (1996) justifies the positive impact of labour
force on exports.
Skilled labour force is the source of competitiveness in production
and lower cost of production. Many developing countries exploit the
advantages of skilled labour force for competitiveness in export sector.
At the same time many developing countries have unskilled labour force.
The effect of unskilled labour force is opposite on competitiveness in
export sector. Hence we can have positive or negative effect of labour
force on exports.
Foreign Direct Investment
In empirical literature the role of FDI in exports promotion is
controversial. Many studies [e.g. Pfaffermayr (1996)] find positive
effect of FDI on exports. The main reason underlying is the export
oriented MNCs. Since government provides facilities for export
promotion, such facilities also attract foreign investors. In order to
promote exports government can adopt FDI-led export growth strategies
with twin objectives of capturing the benefits of both FDI inflow and
exports growth. On the other hand, many studies find insignificant or
weak impact of FDl on exports [see Hoekman and Djankov (1997)]. Such
studies point out that the role of FDI in export promotion in developing
countries remains controversial and depends crucially on the motive for
such investment. If the motive behind FDI is to capture domestic market
(tariff-jumping type investment), it may not contribute to export
growth. On the other hand, if the motive is top tap exports markets by
taking advantage of the country's comparative advantage, then FDI
may contributes to export growth.
III. DATA AND ESTIMATION PROCEDURE
The data for this study have been taken from World Development
Indicators (WDI) 2005. Originally a sample of 155 countries was selected
but after screening process 75 countries was chosen for which data on
most of the variables were available for at least 15 years. For each
variable expressed in terms of ratios to GDP, both the level of the
variable and the GDP are measured in US dollar at current prices.
Gross foreign direct investment is measured as percentage of GDP.
Gross foreign direct investment is inflows of foreign direct investment
recorded in the balance of payments financial account.
Official exchange rate is measured as the period average of the
number of local currency units per US$. Official exchange rate refers to
the actual principal exchange rate and is an annual average based on
monthly averages determined by country authorities or on rates
determined largely by market forces in the legally sanctioned exchange
market. To convert the nominal exchange rate into real exchange rate we
multiply the nominal exchange rate with the US CPI and divided it by
domestic CPI.
Gross national savings, defined as gross domestic savings plus net
income and net current transfers from abroad, are measured as percentage
of GDP.
Official development assistance and net official aid record the
actual international transfer by the donor of financial resources or of
goods or services valued at the cost to the donor, less any repayments
of loan principal during the same period. Aid dependency ratios are
computed using values in U.S. dollars converted at official exchange
rates.
Industry value added is measured as percentage of GDP. It comprises
of value added in mining, manufacturing, construction, electricity,
water, and gas. Value added is the net output of a sector after adding
up all outputs and subtracting intermediate inputs. It is calculated
without making deductions for depreciation of fabricated assets or
depletion and degradation of natural resources.
Total labour force comprises people who meet the International
Labour Organisation (ILO) definition of the economically active
population: all people who supply labour for the production of goods and
services during a specified period. It includes both the employed and
the unemployed members of labour force. While national practices vary in
the treatment of such groups as the armed forces and seasonal or
parttime workers, in general the labour force includes the armed forces,
the unemployed and first-time job seekers, but excludes homemakers and
other unpaid caregivers and workers in the informal sector.
Telephone mainlines are measured as the number of lines per 1,000
persons. Telephone mainlines are telephone lines connecting a
customer's equipment to the public switched telephone network.
Likewise television sets are also measured as the number of sets in use
per 1,000 persons.
Net indirect taxes are measured as percentage of GDP. These taxes
are the sum of indirect taxes less subsidies. Indirect taxes are those
taxes payable by producers that relate to the production, sale, purchase
or use of the goods and services. Subsidies are grants on the current
account made by general government to private enterprises and
unincorporated public enterprises. The grants may take the form of
payments to ensure a guaranteed price or to enable maintenance of prices
of goods and services below costs of production, and other forms of
assistance to producers.
We now discuss estimation procedure for our model. The use of
pooled time-series and cross-section data provide large sample that is
expected to yield efficient parameter estimates. Since political,
structural and institutional characteristics vary from country to
country, imposing a single relationship to all units is likely to
suppress information. In order to overcome this problem we will use the
approach of uniform shifts. The econometric literature suggests two
approaches for uniform shifts [Green (1993); Kmenta (1986) and Maddla
(1977)] the fixed effects and random effects model. In the present study
we will follow fixed effects model.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS AND INTERPRETATION
In this section we report the empirical results based on pooled
data for 75 developing countries over the period 1970 to 2004. We select
a large set of developing countries for empirical investigation. The
panel data model is estimated by allowing the deterministic shifts
across the countries. Since the model uses panel data, it is likely to
suffer from autocorrelation as well as hetroskedasticity. Both are
removed by applying appropriate econometric techniques. The results of
estimation are presented in Tables la and Table lb.
In literature the first and foremost determinant of exports is FDI.
However, in empirical literature the effects of FDI on exports are
controversial. Our study finds positive but insignificant impact of FDI
on export growth. The success stories of East and South East Asian
countries suggest that FDI is a powerful tool of export promotion
because multinational companies (MNCs) through which most FDI is
undertaken have the well-established contacts and the up-to-date
information about foreign markets. However, the experience of these
countries cannot be generalised to all developing countries given the
lower level of infrastructure and the rigidity in both the factor as
well as commodity markets. Furthermore, the role of FDI in exports
promotion in developing countries remains controversial and depends
crucially on the motive for such investment. If the motive behind FDI is
to capture domestic market (tariff-jumping type investment), it may not
contribute to export growth. On the other hand, if the motive is top tap
exports markets by taking advantage of the country's comparative
advantage, then FDI may contribute to export growth to the extent
permissible under the prevailing policy regime. By now it is well known
that an outward oriented regime encourages export-oriented FDI while an
inward-oriented policy regime attracts FDI mainly to capture domestic
rather than exports markets.
The effect of GDP and GDP growth on exports is highly significant
with positive sign. The level of production can be utilised at domestic
and international level at the same time. The developing countries have
relative advantages for agriculture goods. They can exhaust benefits of
lower cost production by export growth policies. Moreover, large size of
GDP creates environments for investment decisions.
According to the regression results real exchange rate positively
affects export. It turned out to be the most significant variable
affecting export. Our empirical estimates are consistent with theory as
well as empirical evidence found in other studies [e.g. Sharma (2001)].
In the globalisation era, when the value of time is most important,
the need of wide spread communication facilities is becoming most
important. For the measurement of communication facilities we employed
two variables, namely, number of Tele visions and number of Tele phones.
The effects of expansions in communication facilities are positive and
both the variables turned out to be significant. Thus expanding the net
of such facilities is helpful in exploration of new international
markets. Further, these make easy to access the world markets. As
developing countries' exports are concentrated in few markets they
can reap the benefits of global communication facilities. The results
are in line with Kumar (1998).
As expected, the effect of labour force on exports growth is
positively significant. The results are consistent with the findings in
Pfaffermayr (1996).
The effect of official development assistance variable is also
positively significant. This variable reflects the development
phenomena. Exports are favorably affected by development expenditures.
Because it is the sign of government positive behavior and the future
expectations of exporters that export facilities would become stronger.
Indirect taxes are also positive associated with exports. The proportion
of indirect taxes varies for different goods. So it is not necessary
that indirect tax is high for exportable goods. Furthermore, government
provides tax exemptions to exporters. These are the reasons that this
variable does not adversely affect exports.
The results show that increase in savings significantly contributes
to exports. Higher savings imply lower interest rates that promote
investment opportunities. The investment is the key channel for export
growth. In developing countries government provide many incentives for
export promotion strategies. The domestic investment take place in
different sectors but it is much responsive in trade sector to
incentives provided by government. After the activism of WTO developing
countries are enhancing export oriented investment schemes. These are
the arguments that support our hypotheses of investment led export
growth. The empirical results also support our hypotheses. Over and
above, savings are the source of removal of internal and external gaps
in developing countries. As two-gap theory explains saving-investment
and exports-imports gaps in developing countries, large savings are the
source of removal of domestic gap that in turn remove external gap by
enhancing export growth.
The industrialisation variable is highly significant in explaining
export growth. The importance of industrialisation for developing
countries is obvious because production levels in agricultural remains
unstable due to uncertainty of weather conditions and pest attacks and,
hence, on the basis of agricultural output alone a country cannot expand
its exports potential. The results signify the importance of
industrialisation as means of sustained exports growth.
V. CONCLUSION
The objective of this study has been to find out the main factors
that are important in the determination of exports in developing
countries. For this purpose the study used a fairly large sample of
panel observations for 75 developing countries over the period
1970-2004. The data are derived from the World Development Indicators
(WDI) 2005. Fixed effects (country specific intercepts) model is
employed for the estimation of the relationship of exports with its
potential determinants based on the panel data. A number of conclusions
can be drawn from the study, which are summarised as follows.
* It is of critical importance to maintain a high and sustainable
economic growth rate. Evidence has shown that a sustainable growth
patterns promotes exports.
* Development of the net of communication facilities is crucial not
only in promoting economic growth, as is well known, it is also
important for sustained exports performance. This finding strengthens
the case for subsidising the communications industry.
* A stable exchange rate policy has to be ensured in order to avoid
the exchange-rate risks associated with the assets, import prices and
profit considerations of direct investor in developing countries.
* Developing countries need to replace agriculture exports by the
industrial exports, which command reasonable and stable prices in the
world markets. Moreover, the industrialisation will reduce dependence on
imports by initiating the process of import substitution.
REFERENCES
Baldwin, R. E. (1979) Determinants of Trade and Foreign Investment:
Further Evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics, 61 : 40-48.
Bertil, O. (1968) Model Construction in International Trade Theory.
Published in Induction, Growth and Trade. Clarendon Press. Oxford.
325-341.
Funke, M. and S. Holly (1992) The Determinants of West German
Exports of Manufactures: An Integrated Demand and Supply Approach.
Weltwirtschaftliches Archive. 128:3, 498-512.
Green, W. H. (1993) Econometric Analysis. Second Edition. New York:
MacMillan.
Grossman, G. M. and E. Helpman (1989) Product Development and
International Trade. Journal of Political Economy 97:6, 1261-1283.
Hausman, J. and W. Taylor (1985) Panel Data and Unobserved
Individual Effects. Economatrica 49, 1377-1398.
Helpman, E. (1984) A Simple Theory of International Trade with
Multinational Corporations. Journal of Political Economy 92:3, 451-471.
Hirch, S. S. Kalish and S. Katzeneison (1988) Effects of Knowledge
and Service Intensities on Domestic and Export Performance.
Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 124:2, 230-241.
Hoekman, B. and S. Djankov (1997) Determinants of Export Structure
of Countries in Central and Eastern Europe. The Worm Bank Economic
Review 11:3, 471-487.
Kmenta, J. (1986) Elements of Econometrics. Second Edition. New
York: MacMillan.
Kravis, I. and Robert E. Lipsey (1982) The Location of Overseas
Production and Production for Export by US Multinational Firms. Journal
of International Economics 12, 01-23.
Kumar, N. (1998) Multinational Enterprises, Regional Economic
Integration, and Export-Platform Production in the Host Countries: An
Empirical Analysis for the US and Japanese Corporations.
eltwirtschaftliches Archiv 134, 450-83.
Lall, S. (1978) Transnationals, Domestic Enterprises and the
Industrial Structure in Host LDCs: A Survey. Oxford Economic Papers 30,
217-248.
Maddala, G. S. (1977) Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Nayyar, D. (1978) Transnational Corporations and Manufactured
Exports from Poor Countries. Economic Journal 88, 59-84.
O'Sullivan, P. J. (1993) An assessment of Irelands'
Export-Led Growth Strategy via Foreign Direct Investment, 1960-1980.
Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 129, 139-158.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Economic Advisors Wing Ministry of Finance.
Petrochilos, G. A. (1989) Foreign Direct Investment and the
Development Process: The Case of Greece. Avebury: Gower Publishing
Company Ltd.
Pfaffermayr, M. (1996) Foreign outward Direct Investment and
Exports in Austrian Manufacturing: Substitutes or Complements?
Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 132(2): 501-522.
Rehman, K. (1991) Firms' Competitive and National Comparative
Advantages as Joint Determinants of Trade Composition.
Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 127:1, 83-97.
Riedel, J., C. Hall, and R. Grawe (1984) Determinants of Indian
Exports Performance in the 1970s. Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 120:1),
40-53.
Sharma, K. (2000) Export Growth in India: Has FDI Played a Role?
at: http://www.econ.yale.edu/~egcenter/
Todaro, M. P. (1997) Economic Development. Sixth Edition. New York:
Longman.
Togan, S. (1993) How to Assess the Significance of Export
Incentives: An Application to Turkey. Weltwirtschaftliches Archive
129:4, 777-799.
World Bank (1991) World Development Report. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Comments
Although a large number of studies exist on determinants of exports
but a cross-country study on this aspect of exports, specifically for
developing countries, is hard to find. The authors deserve appreciation
for venturing into this area.
The paper is technically very sound. I hope that following
suggestions would help the authors to remove minor shortcomings.
The authors find that depreciation of real exchange rate has a
positive influence on exchange rate. To support the finding they make a
reference to Marshal-Lerner condition. It is note worthy that
Marshal-Lerner condition is about the impact of depreciation of nominal
exchange rate. Though nominal and real rate are related through price
indices, still drawing a direct inference about impact of depreciation
of real exchange rate from Marshal-Lerner condition is perhaps not
correct.
The authors recommend that developing countries should replace
industrial exports with agricultural exports. This implicitly implies
that developing countries do not enjoy comparative advantage in
agricultural exports. Some discussion on this issue, supported by
literature, will make the recommendation more forceful.
The paper recommends that a stable exchange rate policy has to be
ensured in order to avoid the exchange rate risk attached to the assets,
import prices and profit considerations of direct investor in developing
countries. However the results obtained from econometric investigation
do not suggest such an inference, the results only show that
depreciation of real exchange rate has a positive influence on exports.
The authors may consider taking off the recommendation.
Table 4.2(b), that shows fixed effects for 75 countries, and is
spread over three pages, if included as appendix, would perhaps make
reading through the paper more convenient.
Finally, there appears to be a typographical error in the following
statement on page 15. "Depreciation of domestic currency makes its
exports cheaper and exports expensive" This should read
"Depreciation of domestic currency makes the country's exports
cheaper and imports expensive".
M. Idrees Khawaja
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
(1) See the debate between Landesman and Snell (1989) and Holly and
Wade (I 991), for example.
Muhammad Tariq Majeed <
[email protected]> and Eatzaz Ahmad
<
[email protected]> are respectively Lecturer and Professor of
Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
Table 1a
Parameter Estimates of the Fixed Effects Model
Variables Fixed Effects
FDI 0.000261
(-1.4945)
GDP 7.15E-20
(4.91) *
Grow 0.012143
(4.05) *
SAV 0.389982
(15.66) *
OD 0.164817
(8.38) *
IT 0.037753
(2.08) *
[R.sup.2] .948
D W 1.999
EXCH 3.96E-06
(17.48) *
T P 0.000326
(6.41) *
TV 9.85E-05
(4.66) *
LF 0.242757
(2.72) *
VAD 0.003333
(10.27) *
AR (1) 0.73764
(38.16) *
A. [R.sup.2] .943
F 651
Note: The numbers in parenthesis are the compound t-values.
The statistics significant at 5 percent level are indicated by *.
Table 1b
Country-specific Intercepts of the Fired Effects Model
Fixed
Countries Effects
Angola 0.3600
(0.05)
Argentina -0.2537
(-4.84) *
Bunandi -0.1263
(-2.33) *
Benin 0.0305
(1.04)
Burkina Faso -0.1391
(-2.53) *
Bahrain 0.1172
(0.16)
Belize 0.2091
(0.99)
Bolivia -0.0824
(-2.71) *
Brazil -0.2813
(-4.87) *
Botswana 0.0342
(1.58)
Chile -0.0753
(-3.05) *
China -2.2870
(-4.00) *
Cote d'Ivoire 0.1189
(0.46)
Cameroon -0.0316
(-2.06) *
Congo, Rep. 0.1106
(0.90)
Colombia -0.1646
(-3.66) *
Cape Verde -0.0362
(-1.57)
Costa Rica 0.0478
(1.35)
Czech Republic 0.0092
(1.71)
Sri Lanka 0.0387
(1.43)
Lesotho 0.0238
(1.92)
Madagascar -0.0073
(-1.57)
Mexico -0.0957
(-3.13) *
Mali -0.0270
(-1.62)
Mozambique -0.1410
(-2.35) *
Mauritania 0.1474
(0.39)
Mauritius 0.2353
(0.44)
Malaysia 0.1935
(0.02)
Niger -0.0381
(-1.81)
Nigeria 0.0240
(2.04) *
Nicaragua 0.2144
(0.19)
Nepal 0.1300
(0.64)
Pakistan -0.0813
(-2.75) *
Panama 0.0640
(0.89)
Peru -0.1853
(-4.21) *
Philippines 0.0214
(1.98) *
Papua N. Guinea 0.1359
(0.70)
Poland -0.1806
(-3.38) *
Dominican Republic 0.0035
(1.92)
Algeria -0.1484
(-4.24) *
Ecuador -0.0678
(-3.04) *
Egypt, Arab Rep. -0.0626
(-.73) *
Fiji 0.3478
(1.90)
Gabon -1.0560
(1.57)
Ghana -0.0494
(-1.91)
Gambia, The 0.1963
(0.21)
Guatemala -0.0414
(-2.29) *
Guyana 0.5325
(2.80) *
Honduras 0.0640
(1.08)
Haiti -0.1013
(-2.39) *
Indonesia -0.0519
(-2.69) *
India -0.1803
(-3.29) *
Iran, Isl. Rep. -0.2925
(-3.87) *
Jamaica 0.1500
(0.83)
Jordan 0.2677
(1.76)
Kenya 0.0220
(1.28)
Korea, Rep. -0.1602
(-3.36) *
Paraguay 0.0399
(1.51)
Saudi Arab 0.0667
(1.87)
Scncgal 0.0756
(0.90)
Sierra Leone -0.0282
(-.89)
El Salvador -0.0623
(-.49) *
Swaziland 0.4597
(2.80) *
Chad -0.0494
(-1.76)
Thailand -0.0860
(-2.46) *
Togo 0.1706
(0.05)
Trinidad & Tobago 0.0141
(2.50) *
Tunisia 0.0999
(0.88)
Turkey -0.3606
(-5.14) *
Tanzania 0.0195
(1.35)
Uganda -0.1126
(-2.29) *
Venezuela, RB -0.1151
(-3.58) *
South Africa -0.0653
(-2.99) *
Zambia -0.0100
(-1.96)
Zimbabwe -0.0476
(-2.25) *
Note: The numbers in parentheses are the computed t-values. The
statistics significant at 5 percent level are indicated by *.