Inflation everywhere is a monetary phenomenon: an introductory note.
Ul Haque, Nadeem ; Qayyum, Abdul
Ever since the 1970s, when inflation became a virtually global
phenomenon, controlling inflation has become a high priority for
policy-makers. Given the well-known costs of inflation, policy now in
all countries is inflation-averse. Perhaps one of the more important
adverse consequences of inflation may be that high and persistent
inflation is a regressive tax (1) which adversely impacts the poor. (2)
The poor are extremely limited in their options to protect themselves
against inflation; they are normally asset-poor, while most of their
saving is in the form of cash. Inflation erodes cash savings and
protects the rich who hold real assets. (3) It is not surprising that
inflation may be politically costly for the government.
Studies have also found that high and volatile inflation has been
detrimental to growth and financial sector development. Resource
allocation is inhibited as inflation obscures relative price changes and
thus inhibits optimal resource allocation.
For policy to control inflation, it is important to understand the
factors that drive inflation. Unquestionably, empirical evidence points
to "inflation being always and everywhere a monetary
phenomenon" [Friedman (1963)]. However, there still remains some
debate on whether supply-side factors could cause inflation without
monetary accommodation. (4) The structuralist school of thought holds
that supply constraints that drive up prices of specific goods can have
wider repercussions on the overall price level. Similarly, there are a
number of possible sources of rising costs such as wages, profits,
imported inflation-exchange rate, commodity prices, external shocks,
exhaustion of natural resources, and taxes. For example, in Pakistan,
increases in the wheat support price have frequently been blamed for
increasing inflation. (5)
Consensus among economists has also been reached that price
stability is the prime objective of monetary policy. (6) Maintaining
price stability is the responsibility of a central bank and it is
accountable for achieving it. (7) In keeping with this consensus, the
State Bank of Pakistan was also explicitly mandated to ensure price
stability in the SBP law of 1997. However, in the period 2001-2005,
monetary policy of the SBP was biased towards supporting growth because
of its expectation that inflation could be maintained at low levels
while giving the economy a monetary stimulus. In keeping with monetary
experience, inflation started accelerating in 2005, forcing a reversal.
(8)
To control inflation, monetary authorities in Pakistan use M2 as an
intermediate target. (9) Growth of this monetary aggregate is fixed
annually, and was maintained within target till 2001. From 2001 to 2005
the actual money supply growth was overshot by 69 percent on average
from the targeted money supply growth.
The recent rise in inflation has once again triggered a debate on
the causes of inflation. Even policy-makers are divided on the issues of
causes of inflation. Policymakers on one side have contended that the
current inflation was caused by cost push factors such as wheat
procurement price and oil price increases (10) and on the other side
they think that it is accommodative monetary policy that is responsible
for current surge in inflation. (11) Commentators pointed to the
monetary overhang as a cause of inflation. (12) It is not surprising
that policy-makers should point to factors beyond their control as the
cause of inflation and for commentators to point to a policy failure the
inability to control money supply growth. Interestingly enough a similar
debate also took place in the nineties. (13)
Figure 1 shows ten year averages of inflation, money growth and GDP growth. The chart shows that inflation and money growth to be positively
correlated while GDP growth appears to be negatively impacted by
inflation. This is in keeping with economic theory and experience of
other countries.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
In this symposium, we have collected three papers to understand and
examine the determinants of inflation and to see which side the data
support. All of them seem to reprove what is now well accepted in the
world that "inflation is everywhere a monetary phenomenon".
Consequently, policy cannot escape responsibility for the rekindling of
inflation.
The first paper in this symposium is on "Inflation in
Pakistan" written by Mohsan S. Khan and A. Schimmelpfennig. The
main objective of the paper is to examine the factors that explain and
help forecast inflation in Pakistan during the recent decade. In their
analysis they use two monetary variables (money supply and/or credit to
the private sector), an activity variable, the interest rate(s), the
exchange rate, and the wheat support price (as a supply-side factor).
The study reveals that a long-run relationship between inflation
and private sector credit exists. The loading coefficient in the
equation for the CPI indicates that 23 percent of a deviation from the
long-run relationship is adjusted in the next period. In response to an
innovation in private sector credit, the CPI initially falls, but after
4 months steadily increases. When broad money was used as monetary
variable they found that there no long run relationship exists among the
variables. The reason may be the ongoing changes in macroeconomic stabilisation and financial sector reforms.
In order to search for an appropriate leading indicator of
inflation, the study uses a different specification. It concludes that
private sector credit growth and broad money growth are leading
indicators of inflation. The results are consistent with a monetary
transmission mechanism that works through the credit channel.
Overall, the paper concludes that monetary factors are the main
drivers of recent surge in inflation in Pakistan, whereas other
variables such as real GDP growth, the wheat support price matter, and
NEER appreciation play less role. Moreover, the monetary growth affects
inflation with a lag of around 12 months. The study also concludes that
the State Bank of Pakistan is fully capable of implementing its own
independent monetary policy consistent with the needs of the domestic
economy. Finally, it is recommended that monetary policy has to be
forward-looking to achieve its inflation target.
The prime objective of the second paper "Money, Inflation, and
Growth" by Abdul Qayyum, is to test the validity of the monetarist stance that inflation is a monetary phenomenon, i.e., the money supply
growth (excess) causes inflation in Pakistan.
The study shows that money (M2) growth remains above the target
level since 2001 and inflation exceeds its target during 2005 and 2006.
The velocity of money shows a decreasing trend over the period from 1973
to 2005. During 2005, inflation tax on money holder is estimated to be
0.98 percent of GDP. The results from the correlation analysis indicate
that there is a positive association between the money growth and
inflation. It is concluded that money supply growth at first round
affects real GDP growth, and at second round, inflation.
The results indicates that in the long run, there is a one-to-one
relationship between the rate of inflation and the growth in money
supply, growth in real income, and growth in velocity of money. The
results also proves that there is one-to-one relationship between the
inflation and money growth relative to real income in Pakistan. Finally,
the study concludes that there is proportional relationship between the
excess money supply over the output growth and the velocity growth. It
implies that excess money supply is the main cause of inflation in
Pakistan. The important policy implication is that inflation in Pakistan
can be cured by sufficiently tight monetary policy. The formulation of
monetary policy must consider development in the real and financial
sectors and treat them as constraints on the policy.
Ali Kemal in his paper tests the hypothesis whether the inflation
is essentially a monetary phenomenon and investigates the lag length
over which the money supply may impact on the inflation rate in
Pakistan. The results from the correlation analysis reveal that one-year
lagged-level correlation between money growth and inflation rate is
higher than the level-level correlation. It is also observed that an
increase in the variability in money supply leads to an increase in the
variability in inflation and variability in GDP growth.
From the cointegrating analysis, the study concludes that inflation
has a positive long-run association with money supply and a negative
relationship with income. Kemal therefore concludes that the negative
association between inflation and output implies that any increase in
output in the short run resulting from demand stimulus results in a
decline in the output. The results from the VAR lead to the conclusion
that inflation is strongly associated with the short-run movements in
the money supply, but it affects with a lag of three quarters. Finally,
the results of the impulse response function (IRF) show that both money
and output adjust in response to exogenous shocks in inflation, but that
inflation does not adjust to its own shock. Further, the equilibrium is
not fully restored. Inflation adjusts while output overshots in response
to the money supply shock. GDP adjusts significantly to its own shock
and money supply adjusts slightly. Inflation does respond well to the
shock in GDP but equilibrium is not stable. His conclusion is that
inflation in Pakistan is a monetary phenomenon. It takes three quarters
of money growth to affect inflation.
REFERENCES
Akhtar, S. (2006) Pakistan--Economic Outlook and Prospects. Speech
Delivered at the Adam Smith Institute, Thun, Switzerland, June 27.
Bailey, M. J. (1956) The Welfare Cost of Inflationary Finance.
Journal of Political Economy 64, 93-110.
Bernanke, B. S. (2005) Inflation in Latin America--A New Era?
Remarks at the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Economic
Summit, February 11, 2005. Available via the Internet at:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/
speeches/2005/20050211/default.htm.
Blejer, M. I., and A. M. Leone (2000) Introduction and Overview. In
Blejer, et al. Inflation Targeting in Practice: Strategic and
Operational Issues and Application to Emerging Economies. Washington, D.
C.: International Monetary Fund.
Blejer, M. I., A. Ize, A. M. Leone, and S. Werlang (2000) Inflation
Targeting in Practice: Strategic and Operational Issues and Application
to Emerging Economies. Washington, D. C.: International Monetary Fund.
Cecchetti, S. G. (2000) Making Monetary Policy: Objectives and
Rules. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 16:4, 43-59.
Fischer, S. and F. Modigliani (1978a) Towards Understanding of the
Costs of Inflation. In K. Brunner and A. H. Meltzer (ed.) The Costs and
Consequences of Inflation. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy, Vol. 15, 5-42.
Fischer, S. and F. Modigliani (1978b) Towards Understanding of the
Real Effects and the Costs of Inflation. Weltwirtschaftliehes Archiv
114, 810-832.
Friedman, M. (1963) Inflation: Causes and Consequences. New York:
Asia Publishing House.
Goodfriend, M. (2000) Maintaining Low Inflation: Rationale and
Reality. In Blejer, et al. Inflation Targeting in Practice: Strategic
and Operational Issues and Application to Emerging Economies.
International Monetary Fund.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Pakistan Economic Survey.
Ministry of Finance, Government of Pakistan.
Khan, A. H. and M. A. Qasim (1996) Inflation in Pakistan Revisited.
The Pakistan Development Review 35:4, 747-759.
King, M. (1999) Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old, in New
Challenges for Monetary Policy. Proceedings of the Symposium sponsored
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Sherani, S. (2005) The Dark Side of the Force, ABN-AMRO, Economic
Focus--Pakistan. Monday, May 30.
State Bank of Pakistan (2006) Monetary Policy Statement. State Bank
of Pakistan.
(1) Baily (1956), Fisher and Modigliani (1978a, 1978b).
(2) Cecchetti (2000).
(3) Fisher and Modigliani (1978a).
(4) Bernanke (2005).
(5) Pakistan Economic Survey (Various Issues).
(6) King (1999) and Blejer, et al. (2000).
(7) Goodfriend (2000), King (1999), and Blejer and Leon (2000).
(8) SBP-MPS (2006).
(9) Akhtar (2006).
(10) Pakistan Economic Survey (2005-2006).
(11) Akhtar (2006).
(12) Sherani (2005).
(13) See, for example, Khan and Qasim (1996).
Nadeem Ul Haque is Vice-Chancellor, and Abdul Qayyum is Associate
Professor at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.