首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月11日 星期三
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Willingness to pay for the quality of drinking water.
  • 作者:Sattar, Abdul ; Ahmad, Eatzaz
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2007
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:JEL classification: D12, D13, D31, Q21, Q25, Q51, R21
  • 关键词:Consumer behavior;Drinking water;Water supply;Water-supply

Willingness to pay for the quality of drinking water.


Sattar, Abdul ; Ahmad, Eatzaz


This paper presents households behaviour in terms of willingness to pay for safe drinking water in Hyderabad city, Sindh, Pakistan. The multinomial logit model is estimated for averting water contamination behaviour. Measures of awareness and households' wealth are incorporated into the model to account for joint production of utility. The study finds that measures of awareness such as different levels of formal education of decision-makers and their informal exposure to mass media have statistically significant effects on the willingness to pay for drinking-water purification devices that can be adopted at home.

JEL classification: D12, D13, D31, Q21, Q25, Q51, R21

Keywords: Willingness to Pay, Quality of Drinking Water, Multinomial Logit Model

1. INTRODUCTION

Willingness-to-Pay to avoid risks has long been recognised as an important response to perceived environmental and health hazards. Abdalla, et al. (1992) have documented the existence of consumer averting behaviour in response to potential water contamination, while Musser, et al. (1992) Smith and Desvouges (1986) and Courant and Porter (1998) were among the first to provide a theoretical framework for the averting behaviour in response to pollution. All these studies estimated that averting behaviour formed a lower bound willingness-to-pay for reduction in pollution under certain conditions.

In developing countries willingness-to-pay and demand for the good quality drinking water is often low. The major causes are lack of awareness regarding the contamination of drinking water and low levels of household incomes.

The objectives of this paper are (a) to estimate the effects of formal and informal awareness of households on the demand for the home purification methods and b) to estimate willingness to pay for the safe drinking water. To accomplish these objectives we develop a theoretical framework of households' water purification behaviour by incorporating the wealth and awareness indicators of households.

For this study primary data of households are collected from Hyderabad city with known history of polluted water. Multinomial Logit regression is used to analyse the effects of awareness and wealth on safe drinking water practices among households. By using estimated probabilities, costs of the different methods of purification are calculated to arrive at the estimates of willingness to pay for the safe drinking water. The estimated results show that the education level of female decision-makers compared to that of male decision-makers has more significant effect in using any or even more expensive method of purification. Furthermore, on average education level of decision makers is more important factor contributing to willingness to pay for safe drinking water than the wealth of households.

2. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

The traditional demand functions are dependent on, besides income and prices, several other factors capturing preference structure of households like demographic composition, educational levels, profession and residential status of households [see Deaton (1980)]. In cross section data all consumers face the same set of prices and, therefore, the variations is prices paid by different consumers do not represent genuine price variations; these may be due to quality differentials and the differences due to locations The budget allocation decision of households in our context may be understood as a multi-stage budgeting process. For example, at the upper stage budget is allocated to food, health and other categories. Then at the lower stage the food expenditure is allocated to clean drinking water and other food items, while the lower-stage stage health expenditure is allocated to curing of diarrhea and other waterborne diseases along with other health items. Engel's law observes that the nature of preferences is such that income-consumption curves are skewed, that is, as budget size increases, the budget share of luxuries tends to rise and that of necessities tends to decline. This implies that rich households are more likely to allocate a larger share of their budget to more expensive water purification devices as compared to poor households. In a typical averting behaviour model developed by Courant and Porter (1998), water purification practices enter into utility function through households' production function of health. Thus denoting the quantities of composites goods health and 'all other goods' by H and Y respectively, the utility function of a consumer can be written as

U = U [Z, H(A, [pi])] (1)

where Z is the Marshallian composite good, H is a measure of health level, H(.) is the production function for health, A is the set of averting activities, [pi] is an indicator of the perceived health-risk associated with drinking contaminated water. It is assumed that [U.sub.A] > 0 and [U/sub.[pi]] < 0. Here we have assumed that households get utility through the drinking safe water and indirectly through the health. We consider four water purification devices, which are electric filter, ordinary filter, use of chlorine tablets and boiling. If a household's uses two purification methods, we consider the one that is the most effective, where effectiveness follows the order: electric filter (most effective), ordinary filter, use of chlorine tablets and boiling (least effective).

Further, household chooses between A and Z subject to budget constraint. Y = Z + [P.sub.1] [A.sub.1] + [P.sub.2] [A.sub.2] + [P.sub.3] [A.sub.3] + [P.sub.4] [A.sub.4] + C, where Y is income Pi is the price of water alternative and C is the average cost of filtered water. The price of the composite good is set equal to unity. Given that the consumer chooses water alternative j, the conditional demand for water practices can be solved as a function of wealth (a proxy of permanent income), awareness (formal and informal) and other variables like sex and occupation of decisionmaker and occurrence of diarrhea among 0-5 age members of the household. That is,

[A.sub.j] = [A.sub.j] ([P.sub.j], Y, M, O) (2)

where M is the set of awareness variables and O is the set of other variables.

To estimate willingness to pay for the safe drinking water we first obtain the predicted probabilities of each choice from multinomial logit model that determines the decision to adopt one of the four methods of purifying drinking water vis-a-vis no water purification. The equation for the multinomial regression model is given by

P([Y.sub.i] = j|[X.sub.i])= exp([[beta].sub.j][X.sub.i]) / 1 + [4.summation over.m-1] exp([[beta].sub.m][X.sub.i]) j = 1, ..., 4 (3)

The predicted probabilities of each choice are then multiply by the cost of adopted water purification device. The cost of adopting a purification device is estimated as the annual cost reported by the surveyed households.

Let [C.sub.ij] be the actual cost associated with jth method of purification for ith household and P([A.sub.i] = j) be the probability of the adoption of a purification method j by ith household predicted from the estimated multinomial model. Then the ([WTP.sub.i]) by ith household is given by

[WTP.sub.i] = [C.sub.1] P([A.sub.i] = 1) + [C.sub.2] P([A.sub.i] = 2) + [C.sub.3] P([A.sub.i] =3) + [C.sub.4] P([A.sub.i] = 4) (4)

Now from policy perspective, it is important to determine how this WTP is affected by changes in various explanatory variables. For this purpose we regress estimate WTP on a set of explanatory variables by Ordinary Least Square (OLS) method, that is;

[WTP.sub.i] = [beta][X.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.i] (5)

From this willingness to pay we will calculate the mean willingness to pay. Since there are four choices for water purification, the multivariate logit model takes the form:

P([Y.sub.i] = j|[X.sub.i])= exp([[beta].sub.j][X.sub.i]) / 1 + [4.summation over.m-1] exp([[beta].sub.m][X.sub.i]) j = 1, ..., 4

3. SURVEY DATA

The data used in this study are based on a survey conducted by researchers themselves from Hyderabad city in the year 2006. The stratified random sampling technique was used to collect the information about various characteristics of 514 households, which consists of 3796 household members. The population of each stratum is taken form District Census Report 1998, which shows that Hyderabad city is administratively divided in four parts; the three Tehsils (Hyderabad city, Latifabad and Qasimabad) and one cantonment. Total population of the city according to the Census is 1.473 million. The distribution of the sample is based on population and the number of Union Councils of the area. Nine households are chosen randomly from each union councils of city Tehsil, while ten households are chosen, again randomly, form each of the rest of union councils. Administratively cantonment has not been further divided into union councils. However, its population is much higher than average population of a union council in other parts of the city. So, the authors made their own convenience strata based on number of households in the area. The same treatment is given to the remaining areas of the city.

Geographic distribution of population and the randomly drawn sample are shown in Table 1, which also shows average size of households taken from each region. Table 2 shows the distribution of sampled households with respect to age, gender, and education levels of members of the sampled households.

Geologically, the city is a flat-topped with subtropical, semi desert type conditions. The main source of drinking water of the city is surface water, which is served by five water supply systems. Since long the quality of drinking water in Hyderabad has been poor. Mukesh and Zeenat (2001) estimated the contents of metals in drinking water of Hyderabad city by taking 18 water samples from different locations. The results of the study reveal that water quality in the city is poor against the standard health values.

The statistics shown in Table 3 indicate that out of 514 households, 35.02 percent households are not treating their drinking water, while remaining 64.98 percent households are using some water purification device with 32.68 percent using the boiling technique, 5.64 percent chlorine tablets, 11.87 percent ordinary filter and 14.79 percent electric filter at their homes.

For estimation, education will be used as a proxy for health awareness of households regarding the drinking water contamination. Education is classified into five categories, which are no education, 1-8 years of education, 9-12 years of education, 13-15 years of education and 16 years of education or above. Table 3 shows that out of 65 illiterate decision-makers of households, 70.77 percent do not purify drinking water, while 16.92 percent boil water and only 1.54 percent use the most expensive method of water treatment, that is, electric filter. The percentage of households who do not purify drinking water reduces to 15.2 percent as decision-makers gets the highest level of education, while for the same educational level, the percentage of boiling increases to 31.2 percent and for electric filter to 29.6 percent.

The survey also collected the information on whether household members read newspapers, watch television or listen to radio on regular or irregular basis. Table 4 shows that decision-makers in 350 of the 514 households almost never listen to radio and among them 36.59 do not purify their drinking water. Further, decision-makers in 469 of the 514 households watch television at least once in a week, out of which only 31.34 percent do not purify drinking water at their homes. Likewise decision-maker in 335 households read newspaper at least once in a week and out of these households only 26.28 do not purify drinking water.

It is expected that female decision-makers have greater willingness to adopt safe drinking water practices than male decision-makers because females are in general more intensively involved in the food related household activities. The data show that among the male decision-makers 46.95 percent do not purify water, while this proportion reduced to only 16.75 percent among the female decision-makers. The most commonly adopted device for safe drinking water among the female decision-makers appears boiling of water. Data show that among the female decision-makers 47.29 percent female use boiled water, which reduces to 14.29 percent for the expensive methods like electric filter.

One can also expect that the members of a household belonging to medical profession have better stock of knowledge regarding water contamination. The data in Table 3 show that among the 32 households in which the decision makers are working in medical profession, only 12.50 percent do not purify drinking water at their homes, while 43.75 percent use the most expensive and most effective device, that is, electric filter.

The correct information on consumption, income, or wealth of households cannot be collected accurately. However, the survey collects information on households' ownership of various assets and different characteristics of household dwelling. A wealth index is then calculated from the given information by using first principle component. (1) For the ease of interpretation, the analysis is carried out on the basis of wealth quartiles rather than the actual wealth index. Households of the lowest wealth quartile correspond to the poorest units of the sample, while those belonging to the highest quartile represent the richest units. Table 3 also shows the relationship of water purification practices with the four wealth quartiles. This relationship indicates some correlation between the two attributes. In particular, households belonging to the lowest wealth quartile tend to rely on the cheaper water purification device of boiling, while among those belonging to the two upper wealth quartiles, a larger percentage is found to use electric filters.

4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION

Results from multinomial logit model are shown in Table 4, the dependent variable consists of five categories i.e., no purification, boiling, use of chlorine/alum tablets, ordinary filter and electric filter. The no purification method is taken as the base category. The marginal probability coefficient of the first educational level (1-8 years) of decisionmaker is significant only for boiling method. On average the probability that households with 1-8 years of schooling boils water for drinking is 23 percentage points higher as compared to the households with illiterate decision-maker. The marginal probability of boiling technique reduces as decision-makers become more educated. The probability that the households with the most educated decision makers (16 or above years) adopt the most expensive technology (electric filter) turns to be 40 percentage points higher than the households with illiterate decision-makers.

Among the media exposure variables radio listening habit of decision-makers is statistically insignificant for water purification techniques, while television-watching habit is only significant for the use of chlorine tablet for water purification. The newspaper reading habit of decision maker has significant influence on the probability of adoption of all the water treatment methods.

The wealth quartile dummies have insignificant effect on the households' purification behaviour except for the third and fourth quartiles for the most expensive technique that is electric filter. The estimated marginal probability coefficients show that on average the probability of using electric filter to purify drinking water among the third and the fourth wealth-quartile (richest) households is respectively 21.1 and 25.8 percentage points higher than the first wealth-quartile (poorest) households.

Other variables included in the set of explanatory variables are the occurrence of diarrhea among 0-5 years old members of the house, sex and occupation of decisionmakers. Sex of the decision makers is highly significant for all the methods of purification. On average female decision-makers are 36, 12 and 3 percentage points more likely to use boiling, ordinary filters and electric filters at their home respectively as compared to the male decision-makers.

Based on predicted probabilities of various purification methods from multinomial logit model, we have calculated WTP. To relate this WTP to household wealth, education, and media exposures, we have estimated a linear regression equation by OLS. The results are reported in Table 5. These results show that the two higher levels of education are statistically significant at 5 percent level of significance and the top educational level has the maximum WTP. On average, if a decision-maker is has 16 and above years of schooling then his willingness to pay for quality of drinking water will be 215.18 rupees higher than that of an illiterate decision maker and 46.86 rupees higher than that of a decision-makers who has 13-15 years of schooling.

Among the media exposure variables, only newspaper habit of decision makers is statistically significant, and on average 69.14 rupees higher will the WTP, if household decision-maker reads newspaper at least once in a week. The top two wealth quartiles are statistically significant at 5 percent level of significance. The households who belong to upper-middle and topmost wealth quartiles have on average 86.8 and 176.11 rupees higher willingness to pay than the households belonging to the bottom wealth quartile.

Another variables included in the analysis is the dummy for occupation of decision-makers, which is highly significant and shows that households in which the decision makers belong to medical profession are willing to pay 203.3 rupees more for safe drinking water than the households in which decision-makers belong to non-medical profession.

Sex of decision-makers is also significant and indicates that the female decision makers are willing to pay on average 100.59 rupees more than the male decision makers. The only variable with an unexpected sign of its regression coefficient, which is also statistically significant, is diarrhea.

5. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

The study measures WTP for safe drinking water practices among the households in Hyderabad district, Sindh, Pakistan. The sample size is 514 households, which consists of 3796 household members. The study estimates that there are statistically significant and quantitatively non-negligible effects of formal education on the quality of safe drinking water. The study also finds that there is a strong effect of informal education like electronic and print media on the water purification behaviour of households. The willingness to pay of a better-informed household is more than an uninformed people, while study finds that the willingness to pay of a better-educated person is 784 percentage pinots higher than that of an uneducated person. Thus better level of formal and informal education, especially among the women, about health hazards of contaminated drinking water may prevent waterborne diseases, rather than focusing other strategies. Further, the study also finds that female decision-makers are willing to pay more and are more likely to adopt some water purification device than male decision-makers.

Comments

(1) Due to the problem of clean drinking-water in growing urban areas, this is a highly useful area of the research.

(2) Diarrhea is an effect than the cause of water purification. But, the health conditions also affects the behaviour of the people. Therefore, the variable diarrhea is endogenous. It needs to be taken care.

(3) Income and wealth variables are taken interchangeably using income in the theory and wealth in the model. Consistency is required.

(4) Some variables like occupation as medical professional is very rare in the random sample. Special care need to be taken for such skewed variables.

Description of the variables is desirable particularly for those fitted in the model.

(5) Use of other means like bottled water and electric filter need to be taken into account.

Krishna Prasad Pant

NARDF, Kathmandu, Nepal.

REFERENCES

Abdalla, C. W., B. A. Roach, and D. J. Epp (1992) Valuing Environmental Quality Changes Using Averting Expenditures: An Application to Groundwater Contamination. Land Economics 68, 163-169.

Courant, P. N., and R. C. Porter (1998) Averting Expenditure and the Cost of Pollution. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 8, 321-329.

Deaton, A., and J. Muellbauer (1980) Economics and Consumer Behaviour. Cambridge, M.A: Cambridge University Press.

Mukesh, M. and K. Zeenat (2001) Content of Metals in Drinking Water of Hyderabad. Pakistan Journal of Analytical Chemistry 2:2, 34-48.

Musser, W. N., L. M. Musser, A. S. Laughland, and J. S. Shortle (1992) Contingent Valuation and Averting Costs Estimates of Benefits of Public Water Decisions in a Small Community. Agriculture Economics and Rural Sociology. Pennsylvania State University (Publication No. 238).

Smith, V. K. and W. H. Desvouges (1986) Averting Behaviour: Does It Exits? Economics Letters 20: 3, 291-96.

World Health Organisation (2004) The World Health Report 2002. Geneva: WHO, Switzerland.

(1) Consider a data matrix A consisting of m columns (variables) and n rows (observations) on the m wealth indicators. Denote the eigenvector associated with the largest eigenvalue of the variance-covariance matrix of A by v. Then v'A = [m.summation over.i=1][v.sub.i][a.sub.ij] is the defined to be the first principal component of the matrix A. The first principal component is a linear combination of the variables in the matrix A that captures the maximum common variation in these variables.

Abdul Sattar <[email protected]> is Research Officer, Finance Division, Government of Pakistan, lslamabad. Eatzaz Ahmad <[email protected]> is Professor, Department of Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
Table 1
Sample Profile

 Number of Average
Name of Area Population Union Population of
(Tehsil) (Thousand) Councils Union Council

City 518 20 25.9
Latifabad 556 20 27.8
Qasimabad 114 4 28.5
Cantonment 85 3* 28.3
Remaining Areas 200 7* 28.6
Total 1.473 54 27.3

 Number of Average
Name of Area Households Household
(Tehsil) Chosen Size

City 180 7.80
Latifabad 200 7.12
Qasimabad 40 7.05
Cantonment 30 6.03
Remaining Areas 64 7.89
Total 514 7.39

* District Census Report does not classify the total area into Union
Councils in these regions. The numbers are obtained on the basis of
the average size of a union council in the district. The numbers shown
are those retained after discarding some of the sampled households
due to incomplete and/or sketchy information.

Table 2
Education Profile of the Sample

 Number of Males with Education

Age in Years Illiterate 1-8 9-12 13-15 16 +

0-5 172 34
6-10 14 195
11-20 40 155 346 71
21-30 30 26 122 115 95
31-40 3G 30 72 60 95
41-50 22 24 62 36 44
51-60 15 13 28 26 32
Above 60 16 14 9 6 7
Total 345 491 639 314 273
Percentage 16.73 23.81 30.99 15.23 13.24

 Number of Females with Education

Age in Years Illiterate 1-8 9-12 13-15 16 +

0-5 157 20
6-10 24 148
11-20 58 136 210 66
21-30 51 15 109 125 76
31-40 63 25 85 38 24
41-50 49 25 51 27 15
51-60 29 18 20 11 6
Above 60 35 9 5 2 1
Total 466 396 480 269 122
Percentage 26.89 22.85 27.70 15.52 7.04

Table 3
Distribution of Purification Adoption Rates (Percentages)
by Households' Characteristics

 Number of No
Household Characteristics households Purification Boiling

Education Level of Decision-maker
 No Education 65 70.77 16.92
 1-8 Years 59 54.24 32.21
 9-12 Years 158 34.81 41.77
 13-15 Years 107 26.17 30.84
 16 Years or Above 125 15.20 31.20
Media Exposures of Decision-maker
 Listening to Radio
 Almost Never 350 34.29 34.00
 At least Once a Week 164 36.59 29.88
 Watching TV
 Almost Never 45 73.34 17.78
 At least Once a Week 469 31.34 34.12
 Reading Newspaper
 Almost Never 179 51.39 30.73
 At least Once a Week 335 26.28 33.73
Sex of Decision-maker
 Male 311 46.95 23.15
 Female 203 16.75 47.29
Occupation of Decision-maker
 Non Medical Professional 482 36.51 33.20
 Medical Professional 32 12.50 25.00
Household Wealth
 Bottom Quartile 129 33.33 40.31
 Lower Middle Quartile 129 24.03 42.64
 Upper Middle Quartile 130 31.54 34.62
 Top Quartile 126 51.59 12.70
All Households 514 35.02 32.68

 Chlorin/Alum Candle Electric
Household Characteristics Tablets Filter Filter

Education Level of Decision-maker
 No Education 7.69 3.08 1.54
 1-8 Years 8.47 1.69 3.39
 9-12 Years 6.33 8.86 8.23
 13-15 Years 3.74 17.76 21.49
 16 Years or Above 4.00 20.00 29.6
Media Exposures of Decision-maker
 Listening to Radio
 Almost Never 6.57 10.85 14.29
 At least Once a Week 3.66 14.02 15.85
 Watching TV
 Almost Never 0.00 4.44 4.44
 At least Once a Week 6.18 12.58 15.78
 Reading Newspaper
 Almost Never 6.15 5.03 6.70
 At least Once a Week 5.37 15.52 19.10
Sex of Decision-maker
 Male 5.79 9.00 15.11
 Female 5.42 16.25 14.29
Occupation of Decision-maker
 Non Medical Professional 6.02 11.41 12.86
 Medical Professional 0.00 18.75 43.75
Household Wealth
 Bottom Quartile 5.43 11.63 9.30
 Lower Middle Quartile 8.53 17.05 7.75
 Upper Middle Quartile 3.85 9.99 20.00
 Top Quartile 4.76 8.73 22.22
All Households 5.64 11.87 14.79

Table 4
Marginal Effects of Multinomial Logit Regression

Probabilities of Purification Methods

 Boiling Chlorine/
Explanatory Variables Alum Tablets

Education of Decision-maker; 1-8 Years 0.230 * -0.001
 (0.006) (0.351)
Education of Decision-maker; 9-12 Years 0.107 * -0.001
 (0.005) (0.725)
Education of Decision-maker; 13-15 Years -0.046 * -0.002
 (0.002) (0.821)
Education of Decision-maker; 16 Years -0.031 * -0.002
 or Above (0.000) (0.562)
Radio Habit of Decision-maker 0.009 -0.001
 (0.708) (0.295)
TV Habit of Decision-maker 0.010 0.012 *
 (0.417) (0.000)
Newspaper Habit of Decision-maker 0.087 ** 0.000
 (0.010) (0.163)
Second Wealth Quartile 0.055 0.001
 (0.147) (0.220)
3rd Wealth Quartile -0.057 0.000
 (0.366) (0.583)
Top Wealth Quartile -0.205 -0.001
 (0.175) (0.641)
Diarrhea 0.108 * 0.000
 (0.047) (0.283)
Sex of Decision-maker 0.357 * -0.001 *
 (0.000) (0.019)
Occupation Decision-maker -0.026 -0.015
 (0.854) (0.780)
Log Likelihood -596.172
Number of Observations 514

 Candle Electric
Explanatory Variables Filter Filter

Education of Decision-maker; 1-8 Years -0.085 0.087
 (0.903) (0.215)
Education of Decision-maker; 9-12 Years 0.003 0.173 *
 (0.207) (0.046)
Education of Decision-maker; 13-15 Years 0.037 * 0.369 *
 (0.018) (0.002)
Education of Decision-maker; 16 Years 0.045 * 0.39G *
 or Above (0.007) (0.000)
Radio Habit of Decision-maker 0.036 -0.017
 (0.288) (0.862)
TV Habit of Decision-maker 0.038 0.074
 (0.360) (0.135)
Newspaper Habit of Decision-maker 0.101 * 0.042 *
 (0.001) (0.030)
Second Wealth Quartile 0.021 0.036
 (0.218) (0.234)
3rd Wealth Quartile -0.019 0.211
 (0.551) (0.001)
Top Wealth Quartile -0.032 0.258 *
 (0.631) (0.004)
Diarrhea 0.017 -0.032
 (0.229) (0.963)
Sex of Decision-maker 0.117 * 0.029 *
 (0.000) (0.000)
Occupation Decision-maker 0.030 0.069
 (0.568) (0.327)
Log Likelihood
Number of Observations

Note: The probabilities vale's of the marginal effects are reported in
parentheses. The marginal effects significant at 5 percent and 10
percent levels are indicated by * and ** respectively.

Table 5
Parameters Estimates of the Willingness-to-pay Equation (in Pak Rupees)

Explanatory Variables Coefficients

Constant -249.95
 (0.00)
Education of Decision-maker 1-8 Years 24.34
 (0.54)
Education of Decision-maker 9-12 Years 42.90
 (0.21)
Education of Decision-maker 13-15 Years 168.33 *
 (0.00)
Education of Decision-maker 16 or Above Years 215.19 *
 (0.00)
Radio Habit of Decision-maker 15.44
 (0.46)
TV Habit of Decision-maker 53.19
 (0.13)
Newspaper Habit of Decision-maker 69.14 *
 (0.01)
Second Wealth Quartile 3.89
 (0.89)
3rd Wealth Quartile 86.81
 (0.00)
Top Wealth Quartile 176.11
 (0.00)
Diarrhea 40.06 *
 (0.05)
Sex of Decision-maker 100.59 *
 (0.00)
Occupation Decision-maker 203.31
 (0.00)
Number of Observations 514
F-statistic 19.29 *
R-squared 0.334

Note: The statistics significant at 5 percent and 10 percent levels
are indicated by * and ** respectively.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有