Rural-urban income inequality under financial development and trade openness in Pakistan: the econometric evidence.
Shahbaz, Muhammad ; Aamir, Naveed ; Butt, Muhammad Sabihuddin 等
Pakistan is a developing economy, which has adopted a Structural
Adjustment Programme (SAP) in the form of economic reforms initiated in
early 1990s. The objective of such reforms was to improve the welfare of
society but these reforms did not lead to improvement in all sections of
the economy. The present paper explores the understanding between
financial deepening, trade-openness, and rural-urban income inequality
in Pakistan. We utilised DF-GLS and Ng-Perron to examine the order
integration and modified ARDL co-integration along with the Johanson
Technique for robustness of long-run association between the said
actors. Our empirical analysis suggests that improvements in financial
performance decline the rural-urban income inequality in the case of
Pakistan. In contrast, economic growth widens the rural-urban income gap
in the long span of time. Openness in foreign capital and trade worsen
rural-urban earnings situation in Pakistan. Finally, low inflation is
associated with a high rural-urban income gap in the country.
JEL classification: F43, D30, C4
Keywords: Finance, Inequality, ARDL Co-integration
1. INTRODUCTION
Pakistan is a developing economy, which has adopted Structural
Adjustment Programme (SAP) in the form of economic reforms initiated in
early 1990s. Economic reforms related to privatisation of state-owned
assets, deregulation, confiscation of price controls, trade
liberalisation generally and financial reforms (especially to improve
quality of financial institutions) particularly. The objective of such
reforms was to improve the welfare of society but these reforms never
fruited to every livelihood in the country. Perhaps, fruits of economic
reforms are eaten up by poor governance, lack of transparency in
economic policies, high level of corruption, high burden of internal and
external debts and interest rate payments on these debts, weak situation
of law and order, and improper implementation of economic policies.
All this resulted in widespread poverty, which has pervasive
effects on global and local communities. The unequal distribution of
resources adding to material deprivation makes life courses further
difficult for millions of people. Thus, all these issues of poverty and
income inequality have frequently been raised internationally on a
premise that nation cannot progress when a vast segment of society is
deprived of it's due share. If we look at those countries, which
are able to acquire rapid economic growth for instance, China, this
growth has been accompanied by remarkable increases in inequality. China
is among those countries, which has the highest level of inequality in
the world [World Bank (1997) and Chang (2002)]. This shows that growth
no doubt is a necessary condition but not the sufficient condition for
the alleviation of poverty. But, Deinenger and Squire (1996) did not
find any evidence to support the proposition that growth leads to higher
income inequality.
As argued by Eastwood and Lipton (2000), urban residents are more
educated and better informed of economic opportunities. Therefore, they
are in much advantageous situation as compared to the rural residents
with regard to socio-economic benefits both at the public and private
level along-with the political representation. Specially, in this era of
globalisation, which demands integration into global markets, there are
opportunities for well positioned and those at the detrimental situation
remain deprived. It will not be incorrect to say that globalisation has
also created a great deal of insecurity for a number of cohorts. The
opening up of trade and capital flows benefits only the existing well to
do or those who are already well established and well connected. For the
lower as well as the middle income group there is still a sense of
insecurity related to economic changes, unemployment, lack of access to
social services, etc. So, what is needed is the sound functioning of the
labour and financial markets with the sense of accountability at all
levels. This is also the pre-requisite for any developing country for
integrating into the international financial markets. The issue of price
and trade liberalisation benefits rural areas or the urban is still
unresolved. One argument is that liberalisation programmes or
deregulations benefit formal sector of the urban areas. But here,
Kruger, et al. (1995) argues that price distortions against tradable are
often harmful to agricultural products; thus when prices and trade are
liberalised such distortions are eliminated. This cause rural-urban
inequality to fall and brings improvement in the rural standards of
living.
It could, therefore, be argued that, the entire literature on rural
urban poverty and inequality in terms of income, consumption or other
social indicators need some assessment of the role of financial sector
at the same time, keeping in view the on-going process of globalisation.
In fact, it is often argued that financial development has an important
role in improving income distribution. According to the dynamic model of
Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990), the inverted U-shaped relationship
between finance and inequality shows that in the early stage financial
development might widen income inequality, but then starts reducing as
average income level rise with more households acquiring financial
intermediaries and services. On the contrary, Galor and Zeira (1993) and
Banerjee and Newman (1993) gives negative and linear relationship
between finance and inequality thereby showing that development of
financial markets and it's intermediaries reduce income inequality
and Shahbaz, et al. (2006) for the case of Pakistan.
This entire discussion, shows that imperfection of financial
markets create inequality as the benefits from high-return investments
are acquired by those who are already stable and have wealth in hand.
Those who are poor will become poorer on account of lack of access to
credit markets. This is because as the financial system becomes
healthier, powerful and competitive, it is possible that, a greater
capacity and desire exists to bear the high cost of small credits [Rajah
and Zingales (2003)]. Instead, of relying on the informal credit system
there will then be more demand for the formal credit from the
well-established financial institutions. Infact, Li, et al. (1998) and
Clark, et al. (2003) are also strong advocates of this concept.
Moreover, the growing literature on globalisation and on the issues
of inequality with respect to rural-urban dimensions shows that it
varies across regions/sectors and many developing countries are bound to
undertake reforms to get positive effects of this process. For example,
Eastwood and Lipton (2000) and Jha (2000) have measured urban-rural gaps
while considering inequality as rural poverty relative to urban poverty.
Most important factors contributing towards rural-urban disparity are
provision of services both by public and private sector, resource
endowment and the level of infrastructure. As the rural areas lack all
these facilities and apart from that the services offered there by banks
or financial institution are far from satisfactory. This entire
situation makes a strong case for slow growth and under development of
the economy, which is mainly depending on the agrarian sector's
performance, based in rural settlement thereby effecting majority of
country's population. Thus, this inequality or disparity causes
growth rates to fall [Alesina and Rodrick (1994) and Ravillion (1998)].
On the other hand, in the setting of competitive market for goods and
production factors, credit may improve the well-being of the poor, even
if they do not directly receive loans [Beck, et al. (2004)].
This pioneering endeavour utilises both expressive and empirical
methods to analyse the inter-link between rural-urban gap, financial
intermediation and trade-openness plus per capita income and foreign
capital openness in small developing economy like Pakistan. The present
paper explores the understanding between financial deepening,
trade-openness and rural-urban income inequality. To investigate the
order of integration running actors in the model, we utilised DF-GLS and
Ng-Perron due to their superiority over ADF and P-P Tests and modified
ARDL co-integration along with Johansson Technique for robustness of
long run association between said actors and ECM (Error Correction
Method) for short run dynamics. Rest of the paper is designed as;
Section 2 describes the model specification, methodological framework
and data collection is discussed in Section 3, while Section 4
elaborates the interpreting Style and finally, conclusions and policy
implications are included in the remaining of this paper.
2. MODEL SPECIFICATION
In the light of above discussion in literature and to inquire the
relationship between financial intermediation, trade-openness and
rural-urban income inequality, the following equation is being modelled;
AG/MA = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1]M2 + [[alpha].sub.2]GDPC +
[[alpha].sub.3]CPI + [[alpha].sub.4]FDI + [[alpha].sub.5]TR +
[[epsilon].sub.t] (1)
Where M2 as share of GDP is for financial intermediation, dependent
variable is ratio between agricultural to manufacturing value-added as
share of GDP (AG/MA) for rural-urban income inequality, real per capita
income (GDPC), consumer price index is proxy for inflation (CPI), while
FDI and TR (export + imports as share of GDP) captures the phenomenon of
openness of foreign capital and Trade.
[[beta].sub.11]M2 + [[beta].sub.12][M2.sup.2] (2)
The inequality-narrowing hypothesis predicts [[alpha].sub.11]>0
and [[alpha].sub.2] = 0, the inequality-widening hypothesis predicts
[[beta].sub.11]<0 and [[beta].sub.12] = 0, and inverted U-shaped
hypothesis predicts if [[beta].sub.11]>0 and [[beta].sub.12]<0, if
[[beta].sub.11]<0 and [[beta].sub.12]>0 U-shaped hypothesis
predicts.
[[gamma].sub.11]GDPC + [[gamma].sub.12][GDPC.sup.2] (3)
After including linear term of GDPC, we also utilised squared term
of said actor to inquire the monotonous impact of economic growth on
rural-urban income inequality. So, relation between said variables
predicts inverted U-shaped hypothesis predicts if [[gamma].sub.11]>0
and [[gamma].sub.12]<0 and U-shaped friendship can be predicted as
[[gamma].sub.11]<0 and [[gamma].sub.12]>0.
Table 1 describes the pair-wise correlations among working actors
in the said model. Correlations show that economic growth is negatively
associated with rural-urban income inequality, which indicates that an
increase in economic growth widens the rural-urban gap. Like foreign
capital and inflation are strongly correlated with rural-urban
inequality except trade-openness. Inflation, trade, FDI and financial
development promote the economic activity in the economy. Openness of
foreign capital is also positively and significantly correlated with
inflation.
Except the financial intermediation (financial deepening) and
trade-liberalisation, we also included other explanatory variables in
the model to avoid the problem of mis-specification. Due to an increase
in the trade, manufacturing sector becomes more export-oriented due to
its enhancement. Expecting positive correlation between manufacturing
sector and trade liberalisation, trade and price liberalisation may
influence the farmers positively. Expanding manufacturing sector may
generate new demand for agricultural products additionally and hence,
migration to urban areas could also decline unemployment situation and
improve the wages in rural areas. Therefore improvement in growth of
agricultural sector relative to manufacturing sector may reduce
rural-urban gap.
Openness of foreign capital is proxied by foreign direct investment
inflows in the country; inward foreign direct investment may deteriorate
the rural-urban gap. The main reason is that, FDI in Pakistan is going
to services and telecommunications sectors etc. Inflationary pressures
hurt more poor segments of the society and fixed salaried persons than
rich individuals. We are expecting increasing rural-urban inequality of
income on account of inflationary impact because as against non-poor,
majority of the poor population is living in the villages holding cash
in their hands to purchase basic necessities of life and inflation thus,
erodes their purchasing power. Impact of economic growth on rural-urban
income inequality is captured through inclusion of GDP per capita and
expecting a rural-urban income distribution improving impact of real per
capita income in the country.
Time series data from 1971 to 2006 of all the variables have been
collected from World Development Indicators (WDI, 2007 CD-ROM), Economic
Survey of Pakistan (various issues) and International Financial
Statistics (IFS, 2007 CD-ROM).
3. METHODOLOGY AND DATA
Unit Root Estimation
In order to scrutinise the integrating level of variables,
standards tests are employed like DF-GLS and Ng-Perron in the prior
step. Mostly in literature to find out the order of integration, ADF
[Dicky and Fuller (1979)] and P-P [Philip and Perron (1988)] tests are
often used respectively. Due to their poor size and power properties,
both tests are not reliable for small sample data set [Dejong, et al.
(1992) and Harris (2003)]. They conclude that these tests seem to
over-reject the null hypothesis, when it is true and accept it, when it
is false. While, two newly proposed tests seem to solve this arising
problem: the Dicky-Fuller generalised least square (DF-GLS), de-trending
test developed by Elliot, et al. (1996) and Ng-Perron test following by
Ng-Perron (2001). On the assumption that there is need to test the order
of integration of variable [X.sub.t], Elliot, et al. (1996), enhance the
power of ADF test by de-trending procedure and DF-GLS test is based on
null hypothesis [H.sub.0] : [[delta].sup.*.sub.0] = 0 in the regression:
[DELTA][X.sup.d.sub.t] = [[delta].sup.*][X.sup.d.sub.t - 1] +
[[delta].sup.*.sub.1][DELTA][X.sup.d.sub.t - 1] + ......
[[delta].sup.*.sub.p - 1][DELTA][X.sup.d.sub.t - p + 1] + [[eta].sub.t]
(4)
Where [X.sup.d.sub.t] is the de-trended series and null hypotheses
of this test is that [X.sub.t] has a random walk trend, possibly with
drift as follows.
[X.sup.d.sub.t] = [X.sub.t] - [[??].sub.0] - [[??].sub.1]t (5)
Basically, two hypotheses are proposed, (i) [X.sub.t] is stationary
about a linear time trend and (ii) it is stationary with a non-zero
mean, but with no linear time trend. Considering the alternative
hypotheses, the DF-GLS test is performed by first estimating the
intercept and trend utilising the generalised least square technique.
This estimation is investigated by generating the following variables:
[bar.X] = [[X.sub.t],(1 - [bar.[beta]]L)[X.sub.2],.........., (1 -
[bar.[beta]]L)[X.sub.T]] (6)
Subject:
[bar.Y] = [[X.sub.t],(1 - [bar.[beta]]L)[Y.sub.2],.........., (1 -
[bar.[beta]]L)[Y.sub.T]] (7)
and
[Y.sub.t] = (1,t)[bar.[beta]] = 1 + [bar.[alpha]]/T (8)
Where "T" representing number of observation for
[X.sub.t] and [bar.a] is fixed. (1) While OLS estimation is followed by
this equation:
[bar.X] = [[phi].sub.0] [bar.Y] + [[phi].sub.1][Y.sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t] (9)
and OLS estimators [bar.[[phi].sub.0]] and [bar.[[phi].sub.1]] are
utilised for the removal of trend from as [X.sub.t] above. ADF test is
employed on the transformed variable by fitting the OLS regression (2):
[DELTA][X.sup.d.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.0] + [rho][X.sup.d.sub.t -
1] + [k.summation over (j = 1)][[gamma].sub.j][DELTA] [X.sup.d.sub.t -
j] + [[mu].sub.t] (10)
In alternative hypothesis, [alpha] = -7 in the required equation of
[beta], above, then they calculate [X.sup.d.sub.t] = [X.sub.t] -
[[phi].sub.0], fit the ADF regression on new transformed variable and
employ the test of the null hypothesis that is [rho] = 0.
In recent times, Ng-Perron (2001) developed four test statistics
utilising GLS detrended data [D.sup.d.sub.t] . The calculated values of
these tests based on the forms of Philip-Perron (1988) [Z.sub.[alpha]]
and [Z.sub.t] statistics, the Bhargava (1986) [R.sub.1] statistics, and
the Elliot, Rotherberg and Stock (1996) created optimal best statistics.
The terms are defined as follows:
k = [T.summation over (t = 2)][([D.sup.d.sub.t -
1]).sup.2]/[T.sup.2] (11)
While de-trended GLS tailored statistics are given below:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (12)
If [x.sub.t] = {1} in fist case and [x.sub.t] = {1,t} in second.
(3)
Modified ARDL Bounds Testing
We employed the modified autoregressive distributed lag (MARDL)
bounds testing approach suggested by Pesaran, et al. (2001) as the most
appropriate specification to explore the impact of financial development
and trade-openness with battery of other variables on rural-urban
inequality (earnings-gap) in long run in the case of Pakistan. The
bounds testing approach has numerous advantages. The main merit lies in
the fact that unlike other widely used co-integration techniques, it can
be applied irrespective of whether the variable are integrated of order
I(0) or integrated of order I(1). Fortunately, modified ARDL method is
free of any problem faced by traditional techniques in the literature.
Another merit is that it has better small sample properties. Moreover, a
dynamic error correction model (ECM), can be derived from modified ARDL
through a simple linear transformation [Banerrjee, et al. (1993)]. The
ECM integrates the short-run dynamics with the long-run equilibrium,
without losing long-run information.
The modified ARDL approach to Co-integration involves estimating
the conditional error correction version of the ARDL model, described as
follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (13)
Where, [[lambda].sub.0] is the drift component and [mu] is assumed
to be white noise error processes. The modified ARDL approach estimate
[(p + 1).sup.k] number of regression in order to obtain optimal lag
length for each variable, where 'p' is the maximum number of
lags to be used and "k" is the number of variable in the
Equation 13. The optimal lag structure of the first difference
regression is selected by the Schwarz-Bayesian criteria (SBC) to ensure
an absence of serial correlation in the estimated residual. (4)
Following PSS (1999), two separate statistics are employed to
"bound test" for the existence of a long-run relationship: an
F-test for the joint significance of the coefficients of the lagged
levels in Equation (13), so that null hypothesis [H.sub.0] :
[[lambda].sub.2] = [[lambda].sub.3] = [[lambda].sub.4] = 0 means no
evidence of existence of long run relationship, while alternative
hypothesis is [H.sub.1] : [[lambda].sub.2] [not equal to]
[[lambda].sub.3] [not equal to] [[lambda].sub.4] [not equal to] 0 which
indicates existence of long run relationship among variables in the
concerned model. Two asymptotic critical value bounds provide a test for
co-integration when the independent variables are I(d) (Where 0 [less
than or equal to] d [less than or equal to] 1): a lower value assuming
the regressors are I(0), and an upper value assuming purely I(1)
regressors.
If the F-statistics exceeds the upper critical value, we can
conclude that a long run relationship exists, regardless of whether the
underlying order of integration of the variables is I(0) or I(1). If,
the F-statistics falls below the lower critical values, we cannot reject
the null hypothesis of no co-integration. If, the F-statistics exceeds
the upper bounds, one may reject the hypotheses of no long run
relationship. However, if the F-statistics falls between these two
bounds, inference would be inconclusive. Moreover, when the order of
integration of the variable is known and if all the variables are I(1),
the decision is made based on the upper bound. Similarly, if all the
variables are I(0), then the decision is made based on the lower bound.
Then, the long-run relationship is estimated using the selected ARDL
model. If variables are co-integrated, the conditional long run model
can then be produced from the reduced from solution of Equation (13),
when the first differenced variables jointly equal to zero, i.e.
[DELTA]x = [DELTA]y = [DELTA]z = 0. Thus,
[y.sub.t] = [[partial derivative].sub.0] + [[partial
derivative].sub.2][x.sub.t] + [[partial derivative].sub.3][z.sub.t] +
[v.sub.t] (14)
Where [[partial derivative].sub.0] =
-[[lambda].sub.1]/[[lambda].sub.2] ; [[partial derivative].sub.2] = -
[[lambda].sub.3]/[[lambda].sub.2] ; [[partial derivative].sub.3] =
-[[lambda].sub.4]/[[lambda].sub.2], and [v.sub.t] are the random errors.
These long run coefficients are estimated by the modified ARDL model in
Equation 11 by OLS. When, there is long relationship between variables,
there exists an error correction representation. Therefore, the error
correction model is estimated generally as in the following given
reduced form:
[DELTA][y.sub.t] = [p.summation over (i =
1)][[lambda].sub.i][DELTA][y.sub.t - 1] + [m.summation over (j =
1)][[beta]].sub.i][DELTA][x.sub.t - j] + [n.summation over (k =
1)][beta].sub.k][DELTA][z.sub.t - k] + [eta][ECM.sub.t - 1] +
[[omega].sub.t] (15)
To establish the good fit of the ARDL model, the diagnostic test
and the stability test are conducted. The diagnostic test examines the
serial correlation, functional form, normality and heteroscedisticity
associated with the model. The stability test is conducted by employing
the cumulative sum of recursive residuals (CUSUM) and the cumulative sum
of squares of recursive residuals (CUSUMsq). Examining the prediction
error of the model is another way of ascertaining the reliability of the
modified ARDL model. If the error or the difference between the real
observation and the forecast is infinitesimal, then the model can be
regarded as best fitting.
4. RESULTS INTERPRETING STYLE
Process of investigating the order of integration reveals that
except M2 and FDI, other variables are having unit root problem at
level, while stationary at 1st difference level. We relied on the
stationarity evidence of DF-GLS and Ng-Perron test statistics, which are
more power full and suggestive than ADF & P-P tests, as explained in
theoretical background and their statistics are given in Table 2. The
lag-order has been selected on the basis of AIC, SBC and FPE that is 2
as mentioned in Table 3. After investigating order of integration of
said variables, we employed both techniques (J-J Test and MARDL) to
check the robustness of long run relation between rural-urban inequality
and explanatory influencing actors in the said model.
Turning to the modified ARDL results shown in Table 4, the total
number of regressions estimated following the ARDL method in the
equation-13 is [(5+1).sup.2] = 36. The results of the bounds testing
approach for Co-integration show that there are five cointegrating
vectors among rural-urban inequality and its determinants and
F-statistics the lowest value is 5.430, which is also significant if we
compare it with Narayan's (2005) critical boundaries at 10 percent
level of significance. After the comparison of F-calculated values with
upper and lower boundaries created by both Pesaran, et al. (2001) or
Narayan's (2005), one may conclude that the null hypothesis of no
Co-integration cannot be accepted and that there is indeed an existence
of long run relationship among the variables in this model.
After the calculation of F-statistics of MARDL Test, one seems to
agree with J-J Test's conclusion and rejects the null hypothesis of
no co-integration between concerned macroeconomic variables. This proves
that results about long run friendship between rural-urban inequality
and financial intermediation plus other friends in the model are robust.
After a brief look at Tables 4 and 5, Table 6 describes the long
run elasticities because all the variables are in logarithm form, except
consumer price index. Estimation shows that financial intermediation or
financial deepening helps significantly in improving the rural-urban
income gap in the country. Economic growth widens the rural-urban
inequality gap. The main reason is that fruits of economic growth are
going to top 10 non-poor segments at the cost of remaining segments in
the society, where more than 66 percent is living in rural areas. So,
economic growth is concentrated to few cities not the whole country.
Rising overall income inequality is also a major factor for widening
rural-urban gap. Inflation is narrowing rural-urban earnings gap through
macroeconomic phenomenon but significant at 11 percent level of
significance in the small developing economy like Pakistan.
GDP per capita worsens the rural-urban income inequality more than
the impact of Trade-openness in the economy. Manufacturing sector in
Pakistan is concentrated in major hubs of the country and they demand
skilled labour for the improvement of their production for exports and
to enhance the trade share in the world market. Migration to urban areas
could not play its role in declining the rural-urban gap because major
share of labour force in rural areas is unskilled, while manufacturing
demands skilled human resource. Moreover, migrated labour cannot be
fully absorbed in these industries and employment opportunities are
captured by urban skilled population. Rural income inequality is
increasing due to unequal distribution of land and water access and
obviously, major fruits from trade-openness reaped up by the big
landlords or feudals. Openness of foreign capital is also widening
rural-urban income inequality, in a small developing economy like
Pakistan; most of the FDI is being invested in the services sectors like
financial and telecommunications that utilises high skilled urban labour
force. In second round of estimation, monotonous impact of financial
deepening on rural-urban inequality presents phenomenon of inverted
U-shaped curve insignificantly. While in the third model, linear and
squared terms of GDP per capita show the existence of Kuznets inverted
U-shaped curve, which confirms the interpretations of linear term.
Finally, we employed the ECM version of modified ARDL to
investigate the short run dynamic relationships. After investigating the
long run impacts of concerned variable in the basic model, we turned to
short run dynamic model as following;
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Table 7 reports the results of ECM (Error Correction Model)
formulation of above equation. According to Engle-Granger (1987),
Co-integrated variables must have in ECM representation. The ECM
strategy provides an answer to the problem of spurious correlation in
the short run dynamic relationship between rural-urban gap, financial
intermediation and trade-openness in a small developing economy like
Pakistan. The long run dynamics appear in the set of regressors.
Technically, ECM (Error Correction Term) measures the speed of
adjustment back to Co-integrated relationships. The ECM posited to be a
force affecting the integrated variables to return their long-run
relation when they deviate from it and thus the longer the deviation;
greater would be force tending to correct the deviation [Banerjee, et
al. (1993)].
Short run dynamic behaviour reveals that financial intermediation
improves the rural income distribution insignificantly whereas, GDP per
capita is widening the rural-urban gap but statistically insignificant
in the short span of time. Openness of foreign capital and trade worsens
the inequality gap between rural and urban areas in short run. Finally,
inflation improves the income distribution in rural economy as shown in
Table-7.
The signs of the short run dynamic impacts are maintained to the
long span of time. The equilibrium correction coefficients (CRt-1)
estimated value of -0.629, which is significant at 1 percent level of
significance, has the correct sign and imply a fairly high speed of
adjustment to the equilibrium level after a shock. Approximately 62.9
percent of dis-equilibrium from the previous year's shock converges
back to the long run equilibrium in the current year. The short-run
diagnostic tests results are very satisfactory with an absence of 2nd
order serial correlation, prevalence of no heteroscedisticity and error
term is normally distributed along-with no auto-regressive conditional
heteroscedisticity. Ramsey's Reset test for functional form
confirms that there is no specification problem in the short run model.
Following Bahmani-Oskooee and Nasir (2004) the null hypothesis
(i.e. that the regression equation is correctly specified) cannot be
rejected if the plot of these statistics remains within the critical
bounds of the 5 percent significance level. As it is clear from Fig. 1
and 2 as given in Appendix, the plots of both the CUSUM and the CUSUMsq
are within the boundaries and hence these statistics confirm the
stability of coefficients of regressors that affect the rural-urban
inequality in small developing economy like Pakistan. The model appears
to be stable and correctly specified with an indication that neither the
CUSUM nor the CUSUMsq test statistics exceeds the bounds of the 5
percent level of significance.
5. CONCLUSIONS
Pakistan is a developing economy, which has adopted Structural
Adjustment Programme (SAP) in the form of economic reforms initiated in
early 1990s. Economic reforms related to privatisation of state-owned
assets, deregulation, confiscation of price controls, trade
liberalisation generally and financial reforms (especially to improve
quality of financial institutions) particularly. The objective of such
reforms was to improve the welfare of society but these reforms never
fruited to every one in the country. Perhaps, fruits of economic reforms
are eaten up by poor governance, lack of transparency in economic
policies, high level of corruption in the country, high burden of
internal and external debts, weak situation of law and order, and
improper implementation of economic policies.
The present paper explores the understanding between financial
deepening, trade-openness and rural-urban inequality in case of small
developing economy like Pakistan. We employed DF-GLS and Ng-Perron to
examine the order of integration and modified ARDL co-integration along
with Johansson Technique for robustness of long run association between
the said actors. Our empirical analysis suggests that improvement in
financial performance declines the rural-urban income inequality in the
case for Pakistan. In contrast, economic growth widens the rural-urban
income gap in long span of time. Openness in foreign capital and trade
worsen rural-urban inequality situation in Pakistan. Finally, low
inflation is associated with high rural-urban income gap in the country.
Stability in macroeconomic policies and sustained economic growth
declines rural-urban income inequality along-with investment in social
sectors like education, health, and population welfare. There is a need
to deregulate structural and trade reforms according to the
underpinnings of macroeconomic policies and eliminate microeconomic hurdles that affect the economy and slows the speed of economic growth.
In the case of Pakistan ground reality is different from figures
with respect to rural-urban income inequality. Better situation of Law
and Order, improved quality of institutions, proper implementation of
economic policies and better delivery of social and financial services especially to the poor are essential to lower the gap between
rural-urban earnings.
The availability of financial services in rural areas like access
to capital is a very important issue for business owners, who often lack
formal education in financial matters and who face barriers to accessing
financing. They have smaller amounts of personal capital available for
start up or they have not much to provide for higher guarantees as
collateral to the banks. Thus, they have difficulties in obtaining
capital and fair lending terms. Therefore, the high handling cost of the
loans (interest) should be bearable along with the banking procedure
(forms), which should be easily readable keeping in view the literacy
rate especially of rural areas.
For instance, the agricultural sector with large number of peasants
involved, the cottage industries and small businesses of rural areas
have access to finance from undocumented financial avenues because it
requires less paper work and easily available cash on their door-step.
Big borrowers and large industrial set-ups of capital intensive nature
have access to commercial banks due to political power and links that
are more professional in their approach operating mainly in urban
centres. The entire banking sector need restructuring in favour of rural
areas to make the backbone of the country strong thereby reducing
rural-urban disparity.
APPENDIX
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
REFERENCES
Alesina, Alberto and Dani Rodrik (1994) Distributive Politics and
Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 465-90.
Bahmani-Oskooee, Mohsen and A. B. M. Nasir (2004) ARDL Approach to
Test the Productivity Bias Hypothesis. Review of Development Economics
8:3, 483-488. Blackwell Publishing.
Banerjee, A. and A. Newman (1993) Occupational Choice and the
Process of Development. Journal of Political Economy 101:21.
Banerjee, A. V. and A. F. Newman (1993) Occupational Choice and the
Process of Development. Journal of Political Economy 101:2, 274-298.
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine (2004) Finance,
Inequality, and Poverty: Cross-Country Evidence. (NBER Working Paper
Series.)
Bhargava, Alok (1986) On the Theory of Testing for Unit Roots in
Observed Time Series. Review of Economic Studies 53:3, 369-384.
Birchenall, Javier A. (2001) Income Distribution, Human Capital and
Economic Growth in Colombia. Journal of Development Economics 66,
271-287.
Chang, G. H. (2002) The Causes and Cure of China's Widening
Income Disparity. China Economic Review 13, 335-340.
Clarke, G., L. C. Xu, and H. Zou (2003) Finance and Income
Inequality: Test of Alternative Theories. (World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper 2984.)
D. N., Nankervis, J. C. and N. E. Savin (1992) Integration versus
Trend Stationarity in Time Series. Econometrica 60, 423-33.
Deininger, Klaus and Lynn Squire (1996) A New Data Set Measuring
Income Inequality. The World Bank Economic Review 10:3, 565-591.
Dickey, D., and W. A. Fuller (1979) Distribution of the Estimates
for Autoregressive Time Series with Unit Root. Journal of the American
Statistical Association 74 (June), 427-31.
Eastwood, R. and M. Lipton (2000) Rural-Urban Dimensions of
Inequality Change. Helsinki: The World Institute for Development
Economic Research. (WIDER Discussion Paper No. 200.)
Elliot, G., T. J. Rothenberg, and J. H. Stock (1996) Efficient
Tests for an Autoregressive Unit Root. Econometrica 64, 813-36.
Engle R. F., and C. W. J. Granger (1987) Co-integration and Error
Correction Representation: Estimation and Testing. Econometrica 55,
251-276.
Galor, O. and J. Zeira (1993) Income Distribution and
Macroeconomic. Review of Economic Studies 60:1, 35-52.
Greenwood, J. and B. Jovanovic (1990) Financial Development,
Growth, and the Distribution of Income. Journal of Political Economy
98:5, 1076-1107.
Harris, R., and R. Sollis (2003) Applied Time Series Modeling and
Forecasting. Wiley: West Sussex.
Jha, R. (2000) Reducing Poverty and Inequality in India: Has
Liberalisation Helped? Helsinki: The World Institute for Development
Economic Research. (WIDER Discussion Paper No. 204.)
Krueger, A., A. Valdes, and M. Schiff (1995) Agricultural
Incentives in Developing Countries: Measuring the Effects of Sectoral
and Economy-Wide Policies. In G. Peters (d.) Agricultural Economics,
Edward Elgar: Aldershot.
Li, H., L. Squire, and H. Zou (1998) Explaining International and
Intertemporal Variations in Income Inequality. The Economic Journal 108,
26-43.
Ng, S. and P. Perron (2001) Lag Length Selection and the
Construction of Unit Root Test with Good Size and Power. Econometrica
69, 1519-54.
Paresh, Kumar Narayan (2005) The Saving and Investment Nexus for
China: Evidence from Co-integration Tests. Applied Economics 37,
1979-1990.
Pesaran, M. H. and Y. Shin (1999) An Autoregressive Distributed Lag
Modeling Approach to Co-integration Analysis. In S. Strom (ed.)
Econometrics and Economic Theory in the 20th Century: The Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium. Ch. 11. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Pesaran, Shin and Smith (2001) Bounds Testing Approaches to the
Analysis of Level Relationships. Journal of Applied Econometrics 16,
289-326.
Phillips, P. C. B. and P. Perron (1988) Testing for a Unit Root in
Time Series Regression. Biometrica 75, 335-446.
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales (2003) The Great Reversals: the Politics
of Financial Development in the Twentieth Century. Journal of Financial
Economics 69:1, 5-50.
Ravallion, Martin (1998) Does Aggregation Hide the Harmful Effects
of Inequality on Growth? Economics Letters 61, 73-77.
Shahbaz M, Q. M. Ahmad, and M. S. Butt (2006) Financial Development
and Income Inequality in Pakistan: An Application of ARDL Approach.
Paper presented at 22nd AGM Conference at Lahore.
Shrestha, Min B. (2003) ARDL Modeling Approach to Co-integration
Test.
World Bank (1997) Sharing Rising Incomes: Disparities in China.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
(1) The power of envelop curve is one-half at [bar.a] = -13.7 when
the model has constant and trend term, and at [bar.a] = -7 when it has
only constant tern [see Elliot, et al. (1996) for comprehensive study].
(2) For the critical values see [Elliot, et al. (1996)] of
null-hypothesis which is [rho] = 0.
(3) [bar.a] = -7, If [x.sub.t] = {1} and [bar.c] = -13.7, [bar.a] =
-7, If If [x.sub.t] = {1, t).
(4) SBC is known as selecting the smallest lag length to specify a
parsimonious model. The mean prediction error of AIC based model is
0.0005 while that of SBC based model is 0.0063 [Shrestha (2003)].
Muhammad Shahbaz <
[email protected]> is Research Officer
and Naveed Aamir <
[email protected]> is Economist at the
Social Policy and Development Centre, Karachi. Muhammad Sabihuddin Butt
<
[email protected]> is Associate Professor at the Applied
Economics Research Centre, University of Karachi, Karachi.
Table 1
Correlation Matrix and Descriptive Statistics
Variables AG/MA GDPC M2 CPI FDI TR
Observations 36 36 36 36 36 36
Std. Dev. 0.1661 0.3129 0.0949 52.6778 0.4636 0.1259
Skewness -0.0845 0.0296 -0.4185 0.5132 1.0206 -1.8850
Kurtosis 2.3887 1.9885 3.0433 1.7525 3.7345 8.3488
AG/MA 1.0000
GDPC -0.8305 1.0000
M2 -0.2642 0.4812 1.0000
CPI -0.7725 0.9292 0.4128 1.0000
FDI -0.8025 0.7852 0.4463 0.8166 1.0000
TR -0.4816 0.1748 -0.0517 0.2208 0.4238 1.0000
Table 2
Unit Root Estimation
DF-GLS
DF-GLS Test at Level Test at 1st Difference
Variables Calculated Values Lags Calculated Values Lags
AG/MA -2.571 0 -5.213 * 0
M2 -5.236 1 -5.563 * 1
GDPC -2.681 0 -5.060 0
CPI -1.986 1 -2.980 *** 2
FDI -5.102 * 3 -5.607 1
TR -2.879 0 -4.712 0
Ng-Perron at Level
Variables MZa MZt MSB MPT
AG/MA -9.536 -2.179 0.228 9.571
M2 -19.137 ** -3.091 0.161 4.775
GDPC -6.054 -1.738 0.287 15.049
CPI -1.092 -0.732 0.670 82.225
FDI -23.430 ** -3.422 0.146 3.889
TR -6.997 -1.855 0.265 13.040
Ng-Perron at 1st Difference
Variables MZa MZt MSB MPT
AG/MA -38.258 * -4.276 0.111 2.897
M2 -29.921 * -3.851 0.128 3.138
GDPC -15.043 *** -2.532 0.168 7.237
CPI -18.809 ** -2.603 0.138 7.426
FDI -47.337 * -4.732 0.099 2.578
TR -56.566 * -5.307 0.093 1.658
Table 3
Lag Length Criteria
Lag-order AIC SBC FPE HQ
1 -5.516 -3.649 1.34e-10 -5.101
2 -7.795 -4.293 2.12e-11 -6.601
Short-run Diagnostic Test-Statistics
Serial Correlation LM, F = 0.0920 (0.764)
ARCH Test = 0.1608 (0.691)
\Normality J-e Value = 1.006(0.604)
Heteroscedisticity Test, F = 1.029 (0.466)
Ramsey RESET Test, F = 0.0108 (0.917)
Table 4
ARDL Bound Testing
Dependent Variable F-Statistic
Lag Order 2
AG/MA 13.605
CPI 5.430
FDI 21.364
GDPC 6.847
TR 18.605
M2 2.394 *
Critical Value Pesaran, et al. (2001) (a) Narayan (2005) (b)
Lower Upper Lower Upper
Bound Bound Bound Bound
Value Value Value Value
1% 6.34 7.52 7.527 8.803
5% 4.87 5.85 5.387 6.437
10% 4.16 5.06 4.477 5.420
* ARDL estimation shows that there are five Co-integrating
Vectors that is strong indication of long run relationship
among said actors.
(a) Critical values are obtained from Pesaran, et al. (2001),
Table CV (V): Unrestricted Intercept and Unrestricted Trend.
(b) Critical values are obtained from Narayan (2005),
Table CV (V): Unrestricted Intercept and Unrestricted Trend,
p.1990.
Table 5
Johansen's Multiple Cointegration Test Results
0.05 Critical
Hypotheses Trace-Test Value Inst. Value
R = 0 226.182 117.708 0.0000
R [less than or equal to] 1 142.858 88.803 0.0000
R [less than or equal to] 2 95.622 63.876 0.0000
R [less than or equal to] 3 56.609 42.915 0.0013
R [less than or equal to] 4 25.455 25.872 0.0562
R [less than or equal to] 5 9.413 12.517 0.1564
Maximum 0.05 Critical
Hypotheses Eign Value Value Inst. Value
R = 0 83.323 44.497 0.0000
R = 1 47.235 38.331 0.0037
R = 2 39.012 32.118 0.0061
R = 3 31.153 25.823 0.0090
R = 4 16.043 19.387 0.1434
R = 5 9.4125 12.517 0.1564
Table 6
Long Run OLS (Ordinary Least Squares) Results
Dependent Variable: AG/MA
Variable Model-1 Model-2 Model-3
Constant 5.3059 -1.2020 -25.620
(0.0001) (0.9332) (0.0817)
M2 0.3071 3.9690 0.2426
(0.0519) (0.6226) (0.1074)
[M2.sup.2] -0.4994
(0.6496)
GDPC -0.5021 -0.5175 6.3211
(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0525)
[GDPC.sup.2] -0.3693
(0.0373)
CPI 0.0011 0.0011 0.0023
(0.1158) (0.1100) (0.0108)
FDI -0.1128 -0.1072 -0.1070
(0.0393) (0.0588) (0.0388)
TR -0.3299 -0.3472 -0.4399
(0.0066) (0.0074) (0.0008)
[R.sup.2] = 0.844856 [R.sup.2] = 0.845975 [R.sup.2] = 0.866756
Durban-Wat = 1.435 Durban-Wat = 1.477 Durban-Wat = 1.808
F-stat = 32.67 F-stat = 26.54 F-stat = 31.441
Note: Prob-values are given in parentheses.
Table 7
Short-run Dynamic Behaviour
Dependent Variable: [DELTA]AG-MA
Variable Coefficient Std. Error Inst. values
Constant -0.0351 0.0167 0.0450
[DELTA]M2 0.0978 0.1315 0.4638
[DELTA]GDPC -0.1864 0.1328 0.1720
[DELTA]FDI -0.1235 0.0416 0.0064
[DELTA]FDI(-1) 0.0228 0.0406 0.5791
[DELTA]CPI 0.0063 0.0032 0.0568
[DELTA]TR -0.2331 0.1384 0.1042
CR(-1) -0.6291 0.1875 0.0025
R-squared = 0.48291
Adjusted R-squared = 0.34369
Durbin-Watson stat = 1.923
F-statistics (prob) = 3.468 (0.0093)