New Keynesian Phillips curve for Pakistan.
Satti, Ahsan ul Haq ; Malik, Wasim Shahid ; Saghir, Ghulam 等
Following Gali and Gertler (1999), we have estimated the New
Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) for Pakistan over the period 1976-2006.
The results indicate significance of the forward-looking component in
determining inflation along with the fact that real marginal cost, and
not output gap, is the driving force of inflation. Results of Hybrid
NKPC show that inflation does not possess backward inertia; rather it is
dominated by forward-looking behaviour. Along with these results, the
degree of price stickiness in Pakistan is found to be very high, while
the fraction of firms using the backward-looking rule in price setting
is quite low.
JEL classification: E12, E31
Keywords: Forward-looking, Real Marginal Cost, Hybrid New Keynesian
Phillips Curve
I. INTRODUCTION
Recently macroeconomists have moved to a new neo-classical
synthesis by integrating Keynesian features like imperfect competition and nominal rigidities with dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model
of the Real Business Cycle Theory with micro foundations and rational
expectations, [see, for instance, McCallum and Nelson (1999)]. The
standard model comprises of a trinity; consumption and inflation
adjustment equations with a monetary authority's reaction function.
One of the pillar of the model-inflation adjustment equation, also known
as New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) in the literature, has at least
two important features; unlike the traditional Phillips curve the NKPC
is forward-looking; and it has been derived from the profit maximising
behaviour of the firms in a monopolistically competitive market
structure.
In this type of framework, instead of starting with the ad hoc curves, we investigate the price setting behaviour of firms while
formulating the firms' profit maximisation problem. It has an added
advantage of analysing the deep structural parameters of the model, e.g.
the degree of price inertia, parameter of firms' time preference,
etc, which are the important ingredients of policy making. On the other
hand in this type of inflation adjustment equation, inflation is
determined by expected future inflation, which has certain implications
for policy making. For instance, contrary to the case of traditional or
backward-looking Phillips curve, policy maker can deflate the economy
almost immediately at no cost.
An important issue remains however that whether or not the economic
agents are forward-looking. For instance, Furher and Moore (1995)
highlights that the economy consists of a combination of forward-looking
as well as well as backward-looking agents, thus showing the importance
of previous periods' inflation in determining the current
inflation. For this reason most of the studies in the area include
hybrid New Keynesian Phillips curve [see for instance, Gali and Gertler
(1999)].
The empirical evidence on the subject is mixed. An important issue
regarding the NKPC is how to estimate it. The NKPC is estimated either
through Generalised Method of Moments (GMM), Maximum Likelihood (ML)
technique or the Vector Auto regression (VAR). Surprisingly evidence
based on different techniques is not the same. (2) There are certain
merits and demerits of these techniques. (3) For instance, GMM technique
is easy to handle and require minimum assumptions about exogenous
variables but it gives biased results in small samples and choice of
instruments is not an easy task, [Stock, et al. (2002)].
Despite importance of NKPC in the literature there is limited
evidence on NKPC in developing countries. In case of Pakistan, to our
knowledge, this issue has not been investigated yet. On the other hand
the issue of disinflationary policy by State Bank of Pakistan since 2005
is much debated issue on media and among academia and researchers in the
country. Hence there is a need for estimating NKPC as it possesses
different policy implication regarding disinflationary policy.
In this regard the present study focuses on investigating how well
the NKPC explains the dynamics of inflation in Pakistan. Following Gali
and Gertler (1999), we have estimated standard NKPC for Pakistan over
the period 1976-2006 using GMM. We have also estimated hybrid forward-
and backward-looking model. Both types of models are estimated as
reduced form equations as well as in the form of structural equations.
We have found that future expectations of inflation play
significant role in inflation determination. Next we have estimated the
inflation adjustment equation both with output gap and real marginal
cost as determinant of inflation and find that real marginal cost and
not the output gap is driving force of inflation. For the case of hybrid
NKPC, results show that the inflation does not posses backward inertia
rather it is dominated by forward-looking behaviour. We have also found,
with the help of estimating structural NKPC that the degree of price
stickiness in Pakistan is very high while the fraction of firms using
backward-looking rule in price setting is quite low.
Rest of the study proceeds as follows. Section II reviews the
theoretical framework underlying the NKPC in comparison to the
traditional Phillips Curve. Section III deals with the empirical
methodology. Section IV presents the empirical results both for the
standard and hybrid NKPC. Finally Section V concludes the paper.
II. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
Negative slope of Phillips curve could be explained in either
setup: Keynesian as well as Monetarists. According to Keynesians nominal
wages are fixed for some period, so any increase in money supply and
hence in prices would cause real wage to decline, thereby increasing
labour demand. Assuming there are unused resources in the economy this
increased labour demand by firms would result in higher employment
thereby reducing unemployment. But on the other hand wages and prices
are perfectly flexible in the classical setup. So any change in money
supply would be accompanied by increase in both nominal wages as well as
in prices. However workers directly observe wage increase but
information regarding price change is available only with a lag. In this
way workers face signal extraction problem and they increase labour
supply assuming as if their relative price (real wage) has increased.
Notwithstanding the different interpretation of negative slope of
the Phillips curve in the short run both schools of thought agreed on
the long run neutrality of money. Both have reached at the same result
within the framework of Adaptive expectations. Economic agents are
assumed to be backward-looking. Policy-maker takes the position of
private agents on expected inflation as given and then decides on the
monetary policy shock. (4) So policy is effective in the short run but
not in the long run, making long run Phillips curve vertical. (5) An
important point here is that agents make systematic forecast errors. It
is important to note here that in this setup deflationary policy is much
costly in terms of loss in output.
However macroeconomists in the 1950s and 60s were ignoring the
basic assumption of Microeconomics, rationality. Agents are rational so
are their expectations. They utilise all available information to
forecast inflation for the next period and forecast error contains
information that was not available to workers at the time of forecast.
In this way policy-maker cannot systematically change the state of the
economy. The idea led to the emergence of Policy Irrelevance
Proposition, [Sargent and Wallace (1975)]. Fischer (1977), Taylor (1979,
1980) and Calvo (1983) responded to this new challenge to defend the
Keynesian's position. Due to overlapping wage contracts and the
market power of the firms, policy can have real effect even if the
expectations are rational.
Almost a decade ago, some researchers tried to incorporate
Keynesian assumptions in the Real Business Models, [see for instance,
McCallum and Nelson (1999); Gali and Gertler (1999); Rotemberg and
Woodford 2003]. The models are built within the rational expectations
framework with complete micro-foundations. Consumers, while maximising
their inter-temporal utility, take into account the future stream of
income. Firms maximise their profit considering future expected cost of
production and facing probability of being unable to change the price in
the near future. The small general equilibrium model consists of new
forward-looking IS and Phillips Curves and monetary authority is assumed
to follow a state-contingent rule.
Model
Consider monopolistically competitive firms which are unable to
adjust their prices each period. Following Calvo (1983) assume that each
period a particular firm faces a constant probability (1-[lambda]) of
adjusting price. So on the whole (1-[lambda]) of all the firms are able
to adjust their prices each period. In this way the parameter [lambda]
is the degree of nominal rigidity, [Walsh (2003)]. Hence a larger value
of [lambda] implies a larger time expected to adjust the price of a
firm. In this case the firm, while setting the price, maximise the
current and expected profits keeping in view that in the next
[1/(1-[lambda])] periods it would not be able to adjust the price, [Gali
and Gertler (1999)].
The representative firm set its price to maximise current and
future profits
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
Where [p.sub.t.sup.*] is the price set by all firms setting their
price in period t, because by assumption all firms are identical except
the product differentiation and their time of setting prices is
different. So in case of all firms setting their prices in period t are
identical and set the same price.
By taking first order conditions, solving the model and then
linearising around steady state we get the following inflation
adjustment equation
[[pi].sub.t]=[beta][E.sub.t][[pi].sub.t+1] + [kmc.sub.t] (2)
Where k=(1-[lambda])(1-[beta][lambda])/[lambda]
Equation (2) is the standard New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC),
in which current inflation depends on the stream of future expected real
marginal cost. (6) Comparing this to traditional Phillips curve we can
see the following differences. (7) First, unlike the traditional
Phillips curve, NKPC contains future expected inflation. It means any
thing which is expected to happen in the future and that will affect
future course of inflation would exert pressure on the current
inflation. (8) Second NKPC is based on micro foundations with explicit
optimising decision of firms. It has an advantage analysing some
structural parameters of the economy like [lambda]; the degree of
nominal rigidity and [beta] the discount factor or agents' rate of
time preference. Third, disinflationary policy is no more costly
according to NKPC. Any announcement by the central bank, if credible,
influences the future expectations of private agents thereby changing
the current inflation. Fourth, real marginal cost and not the output gap
is the factor affecting inflation.
However, under certain assumptions, there is a relationship between
real marginal cost and output gap,
[[phi].sub.t]=[eta]([y.sub.t] - [y.sup.f.sub.t]) (3)
Where [y.sup.f.sub.t] is the flexible price equilibrium output and
[eta] is the output elasticity of real marginal cost, [Gali and Gertler
(1999)]. So inside the parentheses is the output gap. With this
relationship between real marginal cost and output gap, Equation (2)
becomes
[[pi].sub.t]=[beta][E.sub.t][[pi].sub.t+1] + [k.sup.l] ([y.sub.t] -
[y.sup.f.sub.t]) (4)
Where [k.sup.l]=[eta](1-[lambda])(1-[beta][lambda])/[lambda]
As the data show, disinflation is costly as inflation persists. So
it is common to augment the standard NKPC with lagged inflation: both
future and the past are relevant in determining the current inflation,
see for instance, Furher and Moore (1995); Furher (1997); Rudebusch
(2002); Gali and Gertler (1999); and Gali, Gertler, and Lopez-Salido
(2001). (9) In this case the inflation adjustment equation becomes (10)
[[pi].sub.t]=[beta][E.sub.t][[pi].sub.t+1] + [k.sup.l]([y.sub.t] -
[y.sup.f.sub.t]) + [theta] [[pi].sub.t-1] (5)
Here [theta] is the degree of backward-looking behaviour in price
setting in the economy. According to this Hybrid NKPC current inflation
is determined by output gap (or real marginal cost), previous
period's inflation and future expected inflation.
III. ESTIMATION ISSUES AND METHODOLOGY
Regarding empirics of New Keynesian Phillips Curve there are at
least three issues that are worth discussing here. First, NKPC, when
estimated in the form of Equation (2) does not capture the dynamics and
persistence of inflation showed by data. An important issue in this
regard is that NKPC implies negative relationship between inflation and
output gap and hence positive relationship between inflation and
unemployment [Estrella and Furher (2002)]. (11) However in the data the
actual relationship between output gap and inflation is positive; see
for instance Sbordone (2001) for U.S. In case of Pakistan Malik, But and
Tashfeen (2006) shows a negative relationship between inflation and one
period lagged unemployment. For the issue in hand we have estimated the
relationship between inflation and one period lagged output gap and find
the following results (12)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
Furher and Moore (1995) put forward that in the NKPC inflation
leads the output gap. But Gali and Gertler (1999) explained that the
U.S. data does not support this hypothesis and shows lead of output gap
over inflation. In this study we have estimated dynamic correlations
between inflation and output gap for Pakistan. (13) Our results show
that the current output gap moves positively to future inflation but
negatively to lagged inflation rate. So output gap take a lead over
inflation in case of Pakistan.
Second, in empirical literature output gap rather than real
marginal cost has been used to estimate NKPC. However according to the
theory real marginal cost is the driving force of inflation. Gali and
Gertler (1999) explains that log linear relationship between output gap
and real marginal cost could be established only under certain
restrictive assumptions, which may not be the case in reality.
Third, Equation (2) cannot be estimated with simple OLS and data on
expected inflation are also needed. For that matter some other technique
is needed. Regarding the estimation issues the New Keynesian Phillips
Curve is estimated by Generalised Method of Moments (GMM) and Maximum
Likelihood (ML) techniques. It is note worthy that studies based on
different techniques present different results. It means results of
estimation of NKPC are sensitive to the choice of estimation technique.
In this study, following Gali and Gertler (1999), we have used GMM
approach to estimate NKPC. However estimates based on this technique may
be biased in small sample and the issue of weak instruments remains
there, [Stock, et al. (2002)]. (14)
Fourth, instead of just estimating reduced form equation, we can
estimate structural equation which can help identify deep parameters of
the economy.
IV. DATA AND ESTIMATION RESULTS
We have used annual data for Pakistan over the period 1976-2006.
For real marginal cost log labour income share excluding the share of
agriculture is taken. (15) Inflation is calculated as percentage change
in GDP deflator. Data on GDP and GDP deflator are taken from
International Financial Statistics (IFS) and that on employed labour
force and related variables are taken from Labour Force Survey (LFS) and
Economic Survey of Pakistan. (16)
We have estimated dynamic correlations between inflation and real
marginal cost both at leads and lags finding a positive correlation (Figure 1 in Appendix). It means whenever there is a positive shock to
real marginal cost it would lead to higher inflation in the future. In
formal econometric analysis, first, we have estimated reduced form
equation of NKPC. Using GMM as estimation technique and two
periods' lag inflation, labour share, output gap, call money rate,
wage inflation and CPI inflation as instruments we find the following
result [Equation 7].
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
The results seem quite supportive for the NKPC in Pakistan. Both
parameters (slope coefficient of real marginal cost and discount factor)
are positive and statistically significant with magnitude in a
reasonable range. It is important to note that the magnitude of
coefficient on future expected inflation is quite high in a developing
country. (17)
Following Gali and Gertler (1999) we have also estimated the same
model with same instruments except for a change that output gap and not
the real marginal cost is used as determinant of inflation.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
Not surprisingly we find negative and statistically significant
coefficient on output gap in inflation adjustment equation, which is
clear contradiction to what theory predicts. (18)
Furher (1997) asserts that forward-looking component of inflation
becomes redundant once the lagged inflation term are included in
estimation process. To test such an issue for the case of Pakistan we
have also estimated the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve. (19) Our
results (Equation 9) indicate that the presence of backward-looking
terms could not undermine the importance of forward-looking term in the
inflation adjustment equation and inflation dynamics are dominated by
the movement in expected future inflation. Surprisingly the parameter on
lagged inflation (degree of backward-looking behaviour in price
setting), though positive, is statistically insignificant. This result
again supports the earlier one that future expectations play important
role in determining inflation in developing country like Pakistan.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
Then we move on to estimating structural equation, which helps
estimating the structural parameter, the probability that a particular
firm could not set its price in the current period--the degree of price
stickiness in the economy. Using nonlinear GMM approach we have
estimated Equation (2) with both types of orthogonality conditions we
find the following results. (20)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (10)
With the degree of price stickiness [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
We find the same result for the case of parameters on real marginal
cost and expected future inflation as in the case of reduced form
evidence. Results of structural estimation show that there is high
degree of price stickiness. Our results are robust as we find almost
same results with the other orthogonality condition as follows
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)
With the degree of price stickiness [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
We have also estimated the structural NKPC restricting discount
factor equals one. Our results remain robust to even this specification.
For detailed results of structural estimation see Appendix. Finally as a
test of robustness we have estimated all equations increasing one more
lag of all instruments and none of our results changed significantly.
V. CONCLUSION
In this paper the issue of inflation dynamics in Pakistan based on
New Keynesian Phillips Curve has been investigated. Standard NKPC is
estimated both in reduced and structural form considering real marginal
cost and output gap as driving force of inflation. We have also
estimated hybrid model both with expected future inflation and lagged
inflation as determinant of current inflation.
It has been found that future inflationary expectations play
significant role in inflation determination. Dynamic correlations
between inflation and real marginal cost show that inflation co-moves
positively with real marginal cost, both at leads and lags. Similarly by
comparing results of NKPC with real marginal cost and output gap we find
that real marginal cost and not the output gap is driving force of
inflation. For the case of hybrid NKPC results show that the inflation
does not posses backward inertia rather it is dominated by
forward-looking behaviour. We have also found that the degree of price
stickiness in Pakistan is very high while the fraction of firms using
backward-looking rule in price setting is quite low.
Considering it is the first attempt in this area regarding Pakistan
economy, there are certain issues that can be investigated in future.
Inflation adjustment equation could be derived based on the assumptions
consistent with the Pakistan's economy regarding price setting
behaviour, market structure etc. Another point is NKPC represents only
supply side and not the whole picture of the economy. So there is a need
for building a complete Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium model
based on the assumptions suitable for Pakistan's economy.
APPENDIX
Table 1
Estimation Results of Structural Model
[theta] [beta] [lambda]
GDP deflator
(1) 0.904346 0.585414 0.049774
(0.012781) (0.165706)
(2) 0.906405 0.61883 0.04534
(0.013972) (0.159869)
Restricted 0.005275
[beta]
(1) 0.929961 1
(0.038363)
(2) 0.974769 1 0.000653
(0.113256)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Authors' Note: We are thankful to Muhammad Waheed, Tasneem
Alam, Mahmood Khalid, Syed Akhtar Hussain Shah, and Abdul Sattar for
their valuable comments.
REFERENCES
Calvo, G. A. (1983) Staggered Prices in a Utility Maximising
Framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12:3, 983-998.
Estrella, A. and J. C. Furher (2002) Dynamic Inconsistencies:
Counterfactual Implications of a Class of Rational Expectations Models.
American Economic Review 92:4, 1013-1028.
Fanelliy, Luca (2005) Testing the New Keynesian Phillips Curve
through Vector Autoregressive Models: Results from the Euro Area, First
Italian Congress of Econometrics and Empirical Economics (ICEEE),
Venezia, January.
Fischer, S. (1977) Long-term Contracts, Rational Expectations and
the Optimal Money Supply Rule. Journal of Political Economy 85:1,
191-206.
Furher, J. C. (1997) The (Un)Importance of Forward-looking
Behaviour in Price Specifications. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking
29:3, 338-350.
Furher, J. C. and G. R. Moore (1995) Inflation Persistence.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 110:1, 127-159.
Gali, J. and M. Gertler (1999) Inflation Dynamics: A Structural
Econometric Analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 44, 195-222.
Gali, J., M. Gertler, and J. Lopez-Salido (2001) European Inflation
Dynamics. European Economic Review 45, 1237-1270.
Linde, Jesper (2001) Estimating New-Keynesian Phillips Curves: A
Full Information Maximum Likelihood Approach. (Sveriges Riksbank Working
Paper Series No. 129.)
Malik, W. S., A. H. But, and M. A. Tashfeen (2007) Phillips Curve
Relation over the Business Cycle: Evidence from Pakistan. Kashmir
Economic Review 16:1, January.
McCallum, B. T. and E. Nelson (1999) An Optimising IS-LM
Specification for Monetary Policy and Business Cycle Analysis. Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking 31:3, Part 1, 296-316.
Rotemberg, J. J. and M. Woodford (1997) An Optimising-Based
Econometric Model for the Evaluation for Monetary Policy. NBER Macroeconomics Annual. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 297-346.
Rudebusch, G. D. (2002) Assessing Nominal Income Rules for Monetary
Policy with Model and Data Uncertainty. The Economic Journal 112,
402-432.
Sarget, T. J. and N. Wallace (1975) Rational Expectations, the
Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule. Journal
of Political Economy 83:2, 241-254.
Sbordone, A. M. (2001) An Optimising Model of U.S. Wage and Price
Dynamics. Rutgers University.
Stock, J. H., J. H. Wright, and M. Yogo (2002) A Survey of Weak
Instruments and Weak Identification in Generalised Method of Moments.
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20, 518-529.
Taylor, J. B. (1979) Staggered Wage Setting in a Macro Model.
American Economic Review 69:2, 108-113.
Taylor, J. B. (1980) Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts.
Journal of Political Economy 88:1, 1-24.
Tillmann, Peter (2005) The New Keynesian Phillips Curve in Europe:
Does It Fit or Does It Fail? (Discussion Paper, Series 1: Studies of the
Economic Research Centre, No. 04/2005.)
Walsh, E. Carl (2003) Monetary Theory and Policy. MIT Press.
(2) See for instance, Gali and Gertler (1999), Gali and Gertler and
Lep-sid (2001) for GMM; Fanelliy (2005) and Tillmann (2005) for VAR; and
Jesper Linde (2001) for MLE, among others. Results based on GMM normally
support the NKPC while for ML it is not the case.
(3) See for instance, Fanelliy (2005).
(4) Workers, when engaging in wage contracts, have information only
on previous period's inflation so they make decisions based on past
trend in inflation. On the other hand policy-maker sets policy
instrument with complete information on agents' position.
(5) In the Keynesian setup policy is effective for the period of
wage contract but in the monetarists' view effect of policy lasts
for the time, workers do not have information on their relative price
change.
(6) Iterating equation ... forward yields
[[pi].sub.t] = k [[infinity].summation over (i=0)]
[[beta].sup.i][E.sub.t][mc.sub.t+i]
(7) For details see Walsh (2003), chapter 5.
(8) Expectations are self-satisfied.
(9) Empirical evidence on the importance of the backward-looking
behaviour in the price setting, in these studies, is mixed.
(10) Furher (1997) and Rudebusch (2002) include output gap as
explanatory variable while Gali and Gertler (1999); and Gali, Gertler
and Lopez-Salido (2001) include real marginal cost.
(11) when [beta]=1 and equation ... is lagged one period, we obtain
[[pi].sub.t]=[[pi].sub.t-1] - [k.sup.l]([y.sub.t-1] -
[y.sup.f.sub.t-1]), [see Gali and Gertler (1999)].
(12) Standard error in parentheses.
(13) Figure 1 in Appendix.
(14) Empirical evidence indicates that GMM estimates are biased
towards supporting inflation dynamics implied by NKPC.
(15) With Cobb-Douglas production function [Y.sub.t] =
[A.sub.t][K.sup.[alpha].sub.t][N.sup.1-[alpha].sub.t], marginal cost is
given by [MC.sub.t] = [S.sub.t] /(1-[alpha]), where [S.sub.t] =
[W.sub.t][N.sub.t] / [P.sub.t][Y.sub.t].
(16) Data on GDP deflator is corrected for rebasing of GDP in
1999-2000.
(17) It contradicts the supposition that people in developing
countries are forward-looking while making economic decisions.
(18) Gali and Gertler (1999) highlights the importance of using
real marginal cost as opposed to output gap.
(19) See also Rudebusch (2002) for evidence on U.S. data.
(20) For details on orthogonality conditions, see Gali and Gertler
(1999).
Ahsan ul Haq Satti <
[email protected]> is PhD student at the
International Islamic University, Islamabad. Wasim Shahid Malik
<
[email protected]> is Research Economist at the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad, Ghulam Saghir
<
[email protected]> is PhD student at the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.