Instrument of managing exchange market pressure: money supply or interest rate.
Khawaja, M. Idrees ; Din, Musleh-ud
The magnitude of exchange market pressure has ramifications for the
overall economy. Countries use instruments ranging from quantitative
controls on movement of foreign currency to variation in the level of
money supply or interest rate to keep the exchange market pressure
within a certain desired band. Each instrument has different
implications fox the economy. Using the sum of exchange rate
depreciation and foreign reserves outflow as a measure of exchange
market pressure, the study seeks to investigate whether the authorities
in Pakistan use interest rate or domestic credit for managing the level
of exchange market pressure, Evidence from the Granger causality test
suggests that during active life of foreign currency deposits (FCDs),
interest rate has been used to manage exchange market pressure. However,
the instrument changed to domestic credit with the freeze on FCDs in May
1998. Use of domestic credit to manage the exchange market pressure
continued in the post 9/11 period. By and large, evidence shows that
money supply is mainly used manage exchange market pressure.
JEL classification: E51, E52, F31
Keywords: Exchange Market Pressure, Monetary Policy
1. INTRODUCTION
Exchange market pressure (emp) reflects disequilibrium in money
market. The traditional approaches used to examine the disequilibrium in
money market include the monetary approach to balance of payments and
monetary approach to exchange rate. Under the former approach the
variation in foreign reserves helps restore the equilibrium while under
the latter one the change in exchange rate does the needful. (1)
The idea of this study stems from the fact that under the managed
float exchange rate regime, changes in foreign reserves or changes in
exchange rate in isolation are not a sufficient guide to characterise the external account situation of an economy. For example, exchange rate
depreciation can be partially avoided or at least delayed if the central
bank injects foreign currency in the forex market by letting its foreign
reserves deplete. Alternatively, central bank can build up foreign
reserves by purchasing foreign currency from the market against domestic
currency. Such intervention would curb the exchange rate appreciation
demanded by fundamentals. Therefore, focus on either of the two, that
is, movement in exchange rate or variation in foreign reserves, to the
complete exclusion of the other, is bound to portray a misleading
picture of the external account situation. Given the foregoing a
composite variable, that incorporates changes in exchange rate as well
as variation in foreign reserves, over a certain period, is needed to
characterise the condition of external account. The requisite composite
variable has been developed by Girton and Roper (1977) as 'simple
sum of exchange rate depreciation and variation in foreign reserves
scaled by monetary base'. They refer to it as exchange market
pressure (emp).
This study uses the composite variable emp rather than foreign
reserves or exchange rate, to examine the interaction between monetary
variables and external account. Specifically the study employs Granger
Causality test to examine the nature of influence of monetary variables
viz. domestic credit and interest rate upon exchange market pressure and
vice versa. The analysis is likely to facilitate monetary management.
The study also seeks to determine whether the instrument of domestic
credit or interest rate has been used by the authorities to manage
exchange market pressure. The use of domestic credit implies
quantitative monetary management i.e. directly varying the level of
money supply whereas the use of interest rate implies market-based
monetary management. The two monetary regimes carry different
implications for the economy.
The study is organised as follows: Section 2 is devoted to review
of literature on emp model, Section 3 shows the theoretical framework
for the study, Section 4 concerns data issues, Section 5 reports and
analyses the results from econometric investigation and Section 6
concludes.
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
Seminal work on exchange market pressure, as a composite variable
is of Girton and Roper (1977). They developed a model to explain both
the exchange rate movement and variation in foreign reserves and
referred to the composite variable (r + e) as exchange market pressure,
where r represents the change in foreign reserves scaled by monetary
base (reserve money) and e reflects the percentage change in exchange
rate over the period under consideration.
2.1. Girton and Roper's emp Model
Girton and Roper (henceforth GR) contend that equilibrium in
domestic money market is achieved through movement in exchange rate and
foreign reserves. Excess domestic money demand causes the exchange rate
to appreciate or the foreign reserves to increase or some combination of
the two. Similarly excess money supply causes the exchange rate to
depreciate or the reserves to decline or some combination of the two.
Under the GR formulation of emp model, the exchange market pressure
is a function of three variables viz. growth in domestic credit, growth
in foreign money supply and the differential between growth in domestic
and foreign real income. The authors assume that, demand for money is
stable (i.e. money multiplier is held constant), purchasing power parity holds, money market enjoys flow equilibrium and that the differential
between domestic and foreign interest rate remains constant.
The distinguishing features of GR's monetary model of balance
of payments (BOP) include; one, the dependent variable is exchange
market pressure, defined as the sum r + e, rather than the BOP per se,
second, GR's model holds for all exchange rate regimes (of the
dependent variable r +e, r and e are respectively zero, under floating
and fixed exchange regimes, rest of the model remains unchanged). Third,
the model views a country's monetary policy as tight or loose only
in a relative sense i.e. by reference to the monetary policy, generally,
being practiced in rest of the world.
The extensive applications of the GR model include, Cannolly and
Silveira (1979) to Brazil, Paradhan, et al. (1989), to India, Modeste
(1981) to Argentina, Kim (1985) to Korea and Wohar and Lee (1992) to
Japan, Thornton (1995), Tanner (2001) for six East Asian countries,
Kamaly and Erbil (2000) for three MENA region countries, Tanner (2002)
for 32 countries and Bautista and Bautista (2005) for Philippines.
The recent emp models assume a small open economy and thus step
aside from monetary dependence apparent in GR's model. In recent
models foreign shocks influence the domestic economy through change in
interest rate differential and inflation differential while in earlier
models external shocks are transmitted to the domestic economy through
growth in foreign money supply. The recent models have also relaxed the
assumption that purchasing power parity holds. Another improvement
effected at empirical stage in recent studies is that the use of VAR
methodology takes care of the endogeneity in the emp model, that earlier
studies failed to tackle. Till Thornton (1995) the emp model was
primarily used only to validate the monetary approach however recent
studies also tend to examine whether the tool of monetary policy,
vis-a-vis exchange market pressure, has been domestic credit or interest
rate.
Kamaly and Erbil (2000), Tanner (2001, 2002) and Bautista and
Bautista (2005) have examined Granger causality between exchange market
pressure and monetary variables using the emp model. The results vary
across the countries examined and it is difficult to develop a common
argument from the results examined.
3. THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL FRAMEWORK
3.1. The Model
To examine Granger causality between exchange market pressure and
monetary variables, we use a model similar to the one used by Kamaly and
Erbil (2000), Tanner (2001, 2002) and Bautista and Bautista (2005). The
model is:
[emp.sub.t] = [dc.sub.t - j] + [i.sub.t - j] + [y.sub.t - j] +
[z.sub.t - j] + [[pi].sup.*.sub.t - j] (1)
Where:
[emp.sub.t] : Exchange Market Pressure at time t,
[dc.sub.t] : Growth in domestic credit (scaled by monetary base),
[y.sub.t] : Growth in real income,
[i.sub.t] : Growth in nominal interest rate,
[[pi].sup.*.sub.t] : Growth in international inflation,
[z.sub.t] : Deviation from Purchasing Power Parity,
J : Number of lags.
3.2. Theoretical Underpinnings of the Model
Domestic Credit: Positive Relationship with EMP
The positive influence of domestic credit upon exchange market
pressure has roots in monetary approach. The approach posits that excess
money supply will be corrected by way of deficit on BOP while surplus on
BOP will take care of the excess money demand. Under the fixed exchange
rate regime the adjustment burden, falls on foreign reserves, under free
float; on exchange rate and both the foreign reserves and exchange rate
share the adjustment burden under managed float. The adjustment
proportion is determined by the monetary authority in its own
discretion.
Given the above an increase in domestic credit causes the exchange
rate depreciate or foreign reserves to flow out or some combination of
the two, that is, increase in exchange market pressure. Hence the
positive impact of change in domestic credit upon exchange market
pressure.
Interest Rate: Positive Relationship with EMP
Keynesian theory of money demand holds that interest rate bears
negative relationship with money demand. The following flow chart shows
the channel through which interest rate exercises influence upon
exchange market pressure.
Increase in interest rate [right arrow] decrease in real money
demand (leading to excess supply) [right arrow] Foreign reserves
outflow/exchange rate depreciation [right arrow] increase in
exchange market pressure.
We predict a positive relationship between interest rate and
exchange market pressure. Frenkel (1979) discusses conflicting views,
viz. Chicago view and Keynesian view regarding the relationship between
interest rate and exchange rate. The essence of Chicago view is
indicated in the flow chart given above i.e. the increase in interest
rate causes the money demand to decline which in turn causes the
exchange rate to depreciate. This view predicts negative relationship
between interest rate and exchange rate. The Keynesian view argues that
increase in domestic interest rate given foreign interest rate makes the
domestic securities more attractive. This attracts foreign capital into
the country that causes the foreign reserves to increase and exchange
rate to appreciate. Thus Keynesian view predicts a positive relationship
between interest rate and exchange rate (i.e. increase in interest rate
would lead to appreciation of exchange rate). The view assumes perfect
capital mobility and one condition for capital mobility is that domestic
and foreign securities should be equally risky.
To assess the applicability of Keynesian channel in Pakistan let us
assume that interest rate in Pakistan is sufficiently higher than that
in US. Can we expect that Americans will transfer money from their banks
in US to banks in Pakistan? Certainly not, the reason is that money in
Pakistani banks is not considered as safe as in US. As Pakistani
securities are perceived more risky relative to foreign ones therefore
we do not expect the Keynesian view to hold in Pakistan. Given the non
applicability of the Keynesian view we feel that only the Chicago view
is at work in Pakistan and therefore we posit a positive relationship
between interest rate and exchange market pressure.
3,3. Hypotheses
We test the following hypotheses using Granger Causality (2)
* [dc.sub.t] causes [emp.sub.t]
* [emp.sub.t] causes [dc.sub.t]
* it causes [emp.sub.t]
* [emp.sub.t] causes [i.sub.t]
The Granger Causality has been estimated using the following:
[[??].sub.t] = [k.summation over (j = 1)] [A.sub.j][Y.sub.t - j] +
[X.sub.t] (2)
Where Y is a vector of (emp, dc, i and y) endogenous variables and
X is a vector of ([z.sub.t] [[pi].sup.*.sub.t]) of exogenous variables.
4. THE DATA
4.1. Data Span
Data span of the study is: 1991:04-2005:12. Given that exchange
market pressure model is particularly applicable to managed float
(though it is possible to use the model for other exchange rate regimes
as well), therefore one logical starting point of the data span is
January 08, 1982--the day Pakistan adopted managed float. However we use
1991 as the starting point because of the following. Prior to March 1991
interest rate was regulated by SBP, interest rate on Government Treasury
Depository Receipts (GTDRs), whose features are similar to that of
Treasury Bills now in vogue, was changed only once during the eight
years preceding March 1991. This is enough to conclude that interest
rate was not being used as an instrument of monetary policy prior to
1991. Our objective being to determine whether the dominant tool of
monetary policy vis-a-vis exchange market pressure is 'interest
rate' or 'domestic credit', we cannot include data prior
to March 1991. Hence the small sample of 14.9 years that we have.
Besides we use three sub-spans spanning over 7.2, 7.7 and 4.4 years. The
characteristics of these sub-spans are indicated in Table 1 below.
The motivation for the full span of 14.9 years has been discussed
above. The motivation for the sub spans follows:
4.1.1. Sub-spans: 1991:04-1998:05 and 1998:06-05
Foreign Currency Deposit Accounts (FCDs) during their short active
life (1991-98) (3) had been not only a key source of foreign currency
for the authorities but had led to dollarisation as well. Both in turn
influenced exchange market pressure and the monetary policy. The
developments call for analysis of the relationship that prevailed
between the exchange market pressure and the monetary variables.
Secondly in May 1998, as Pakistan went Nuclear, foreign aid sanctions were imposed on Pakistan. The post-freeze/post-sanctions span will allow
us to examine as to how the authorities managed the pressure in the
crises period.
4.1.2. Sub-span: 2001:10-2005:12
Certain events triggered by 9/11 led to dramatic reduction in
exchange market pressure. It is important to see how the monetary policy
reacted to the change in the direction of exchange market pressure.
Hence we use the data-span 2001:09-2005:12.
4.2. Frequency
Data frequency is monthly. The motivation for using high frequency
data is that the data among others, includes, domestic credit, interest
rate, exchange rate and foreign reserves. These variables have dynamic
properties that can be best captured with high frequency data. Besides,
as mentioned above, we have a relatively small sample of 14.9 years.
Given the small sample size, the use of annual data is ruled out for
reliable econometric investigation. Similarly, the smaller sub-spans,
referred above, rules out the use of quarterly data as well.
4.3. Variables
The variables included in the empirical model given by Equation (2)
are: Exchange Market Pressure ([emp.sub.t]), Domestic Credit
([dc.sub.t]), Interest rate [Six month T-bill rate: ([i.sub.t])], Real
income [Proxy: Industrial production ([y.sub.t])] (4), International
inflation [Proxy: U.S. inflation ([[pi].sup.*.sub.t)]] and Deviation
from purchasing power parity ([z.sub.t]).
Of the six variables mentioned above, data for the series'
[i.sub.t], [y.sub.t] and [[pi].sup.*.sub.t] are directly available in
published statistics while data for the series [dc.sub.t], [emp.sub.t]
and [z.sub.t] is to be generated. This in turn requires data on some
more variables. (The generation of the series' is discussed in
Annexure A). In all we require data on: nominal exchange rate, foreign
reserves, Industrial production index, domestic credit, interest rate
and CPI (US and Pakistan). The data has been obtained from International
Financial Statistics (IFS) CD-ROM (May 2006).
4.4. Stationarity
All the data series have been tested for absence of unit root. The
tests employed include Dickey Fuller/Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) and
the seasonal unit root test proposed by Baeulieu and Miron (1993). We
employ the seasonal root test because the monthly data is more prone to
seasonality. The ADF test as well as the seasonal unit root test shows
that all the series exhibit stationarity. The result is not surprising
as the model employs all variables in growth form.
5. ESTIMATION OF THE EMP MODEL
To conduct the Granger causality test we have estimated Equation 2
using appropriate restrictions depending upon the hypothesis to be
tested. Before estimating
Equation 2 we have determined the lag structure of the variables
using the standard AIC method. Besides we have additionally ensured that
residuals of the concerned regressions do not exhibit serial
correlation. The foregoing process delivers the lags mentioned against
the respective data spans in Table 2.
Granger causality test results for the hypotheses indicated in
section 3.3 are reported below in Table 3 below.
5.1. Causality from Domestic Credit to Exchange Market Pressure (5)
As evident from Table 3 the test results show that domestic credit
causes exchange market pressure in the Granger-sense only in the post
FCD freeze and post 9/11 span. The causality from domestic credit to
exchange market pressure observed during the two spans implies that
volume of domestic credit, during the two period referred above, has at
least partially been determined by the level of upcoming magnitude of
exchange market pressure. In other words monetary policy has been
influenced by exchange market pressure considerations. An evidence of
this is the intervention activity of the central bank in the forex
market from 1999-04. The exact year-wise volume of intervention during
these years is indicated below in Table 4.
The intervention activity for the period 1999-00 to 03-04 can be
separated into two sub-periods with opposing exchange market pressure
scene. The objectives of intervention in the two periods are discussed
below.
The first period, starting with May 1998 reflects the period when
economic-aid sanctions were imposed on Pakistan in the wake of going
Nuclear then. The foreign reserves held by the central bank stood at a
relatively level low of $1.28 billion and the foreign currency accounts
with commercial banks stood freezed i.e. depositors were not allowed to
encash their deposits in foreign currency.
Under the foreign currency deposits (FCDs) scheme initiated in
March 1991 the residents were allowed to hold foreign currency accounts
with commercial banks. The foreign currency mobilised by banks under the
scheme was surrendered to SBP against Rupee equivalent. Thus the foreign
currency deposits used to augment the foreign currency resources at the
disposal of central bank, though technically the deposits were not a
part of foreign reserves. As the FCDs mobilised by banks were
surrendered to SBP therefore the foreign reserves were a natural hedge
against default on foreign currency deposits. Upon imposition of
sanctions in May 1998, with foreign reserves at a rather low level and
prospects of improvement in foreign reserves being rather dim, due to
aid sanctions, it was but logical for the people to expect that the
government/SBP will not be able to fulfill its obligation regarding the
redemption of FCDs.
In the light of the above, the government feared a run on foreign
currency deposits. To cope with the situation the government imposed a
freeze on foreign currency deposits. The foreign currency account
holders were allowed to withdraw only Rupee equivalent of the foreign
currency held in their accounts. The default on the part of the
government, to redeem FCDs in foreign currency besides shattering the
confidence of the depositors had an adverse impact on foreign investment
as well.
The following flowchart indicates the mechanics as to how
remittances at different times had fed the foreign reserves.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The flow chart, shows that FCDs were merely a channel of
transferring remittances from the kerb market to the SBP. The freeze on
FCDs closed the channel for such transfers. The premium between open
market exchange rate and the official exchange rate being rather high at
that point in time (i.e. May 1998), the inflow of remittances through
formal banking channel was not expected then. (6) Under the given
scenario the SBP purchased foreign currency in exchange for domestic
currency, from the kerb/inter bank market in 99-00 and 00-01 to bolster its depleted reserves. The purchase obviously resulted in expansion of
domestic credit. This shows that the increment in reserves, resulting
from expansion in domestic credit, relieved the exchange market
pressure. Thus exchange market pressure consideration led to expansion
in domestic credit or in other words monetary policy became subordinate
to external account situation.
The intervention activity undertaken post 9/11 was undertaken in an
entirely different backdrop. Post 9/11 the exchange market pressure in
Pakistan improved dramatically. The substantial improvement in exchange
market pressure was mainly due to three reasons: (i) quantum jump in
remittances from overseas Pakistanis, (ii) Reprofiling/waiver of foreign
loans, and (iii) some improvement in macroeconomic fundamentals. Table 5
gives an idea about the extent of improvement in exchange market
pressure.
In just two months since 9/11 the exchange rate had appreciated by
5.2 percent and the foreign reserves had registered an improvement of
almost 50 percent over the figure just prior to 9/11. The appreciation
of exchange rate was hurting the export competitiveness of the country.
Given this the authorities decided to stall/slowdown the appreciation of
exchange rate. Consequently the central bank purchased foreign currency
to the tune of $9.7 billion from July 01-June 04 (Table 4), from the
interbank as well as the kerb market, in exchange for domestic currency,
thereby increasing domestic credit (money supply). Thus once again
domestic credit was used to manage exchange market pressure--this time
to contain the appreciation of Rupee rather than manage an increase in
foreign reserves. The foregoing discussion shows that, domestic credit
was extensively used to manage exchange market pressure. The following
statement included in SBP annual report confirms the point.
Over the last few years, while monetary policy gained a degree of
independence from fiscal policy, it remained captive to the exchange
rate considerations. Interestingly, these shackles persisted through the
whole of FY02 despite the current account surpluses seen post-September
2001, which led to a considerable appreciation of the Rupee. However,
the focus changed dramatically during the year as the emphasis shifted
from preventing a depreciation of the Rupee, to avoiding a very abrupt
appreciation (SBP Annual Report: 2001-02).
Thus the central bank followed a proactive monetary policy to stall the appreciation of Rupee, that is, in anticipation of the expected
level of exchange market pressure the central bank changed the level of
domestic credit to manage exchange market pressure.
5.2. Causality from Exchange Market Pressure to Interest Rate
Now we take up the causality observed from exchange market pressure
to interest rate during the FCD span. For the interest rate channel to
work some avenue is needed through which foreign funds may flow. Foreign
currency accounts had been the said avenue during the period 1991:04 to
1998:06. With the freeze on foreign currency accounts in May 1998 the
avenue stood closed and hence the absence of causality from exchange
market pressure to interest rate for the spans that encompass post
FCDs-freeze period. To substantiate our point we present a comparison of
yield on FCDs and deposits denominated in domestic currency in Table 6.
The data in Table 6 shows that yield on FCDs was always above the
weighted average rate paid on deposits denominated in local currency and
was also more often greater than average return on Defence Savings
Certificates--the highest yield securities denominated in local
currency. (7)
From 1991 to 1998, the exchange market pressure had generally been
positive and relatively higher, during this period the interest rate had
also exhibited a rising trend. The causality from exchange market
pressure to interest rate leads us to infer that during the years the
authorities used the interest rate to defend the Rupee. Remittances from
overseas workers after having reached a peak of $2.8 billion in 1982 had
started tapering-off. To cope with the shortage of foreign currency the
government allowed the residents to hold foreign currency accounts. The
yield on FCDs being higher than the deposits denominated in domestic
currency, there was trend among residents to hold their savings as FCDs
for which the foreign currency was being purchased from the kerb market.
It is noteworthy here that the non-resident FCDs that were allowed in
1991 stood at $6.9 billions at the time of freeze in 1998. The
dollarisation, in this manner, increased the demand for foreign currency
in the open market and there by led to the depreciation of Rupee. To
avoid importing inflation the SBP had to defend the Rupee by increasing
the return (interest rate) on domestic assets [Mirakhor and Zaidi
(2006)]. Thus the exchange rate depreciation, a component of exchange
market pressure, led to increase in interest rate. This explains the
Granger causality from exchange market pressure to interest rate during
the FCD span. The impact of the causality observed in the FCD span (a
sub-span) is strong enough so as to make it observable in the full span
as well.
5.3. Causality from Interest Rate to Exchange Market Pressure
Causality from interest rate to exchange market pressure is
observed in the post 9/11 span. 9/11, for reasons outlined earlier, did
cast a favourable impact upon the exchange market pressure, at least, in
the immediate future. Post 9/11, the external account position improved
dramatically; the foreign reserves registered a quantum jump and the
exchange rate was on an appreciation for the first time in
Pakistan's history. Given the exchange rate appreciation and the
comfortable foreign reserves position the need to defend the Rupee was
no longer there. Therefore the central bank could afford to practice a
loose monetary policy, which otherwise was also required to give a much
needed boost to the economy, and this is what the central bank actually
did, as the interest on 6-months treasury bills declined by 929 basis
points in 22 months (Oct. 01-July 03). Thus the improvement in exchange
market pressure led to the decline in interest rate. This point of view
is supported by the following excerpt from SBP annual report:
The continued forex inflows coupled with low inflationary pressures
during FY03 allowed, the SBP to reduce the discount rate to an all-time
low at 7.5 percent in November 2002. This led to a lowering of lending
rates. (SBP Annual report: 2002-03 p. 147).
Given this we should have observed the causality from exchange
market pressure to interest rate in the post 9/11 span, however, in
practice the causality observed is the other way round. The reason lies
in the fact that the post 9/11 span encompasses a period of 52 months in
total out which the interest rate was on a downward course for the
initial 22 months only. For the remaining 30 months (Aug.03-Dec.05),
interest rate followed an upward path and the exchange rate after ending
the appreciation spell in December 2003 was on the depreciation course
for remaining 2 years of the post 9/11 data span. Thus it was the
upcoming pressure on exchange rate that forced the SBP to raise interest
rate--to defend the Rupee. This suggests that we should be able to
observe causality from interest rate to exchange market pressure in the
post 9/11 span, as in practice is the case. Having described above the
possibility of causality in two opposing directions, the fact that
causality observed during the post 9/11 span is from interest rate to
exchange market pressure and not the other way round implies that that
the depreciation pressure on exchange rate since January 2004 outweighed
the positive effect of exchange rate appreciation during the earlier
part of the span so that the ultimate causality observed, during, the
span is from interest rate to exchange market pressure.
6. CONCLUSION
The magnitude of exchange market pressure carries implications for
the level of inflation and host of other macroeconomic variables. Given
this the authorities tend to manage exchange market pressure. The
instruments used range from quantitative controls to influencing the
level of interest rate or money supply. The use of interest rate implies
greater reliance on the market forces and the tilt of the managed float
towards floating exchange rate regime while the use of money supply
implies more reliance on the monetary authority and tilt of the managed
float towards fixed exchange rate regime.
We have examined the interaction between exchange market pressure
and monetary variables viz. interest rate and domestic credit (reserve
money) using Granger causality test. Causality in the Granger sense is
observed from exchange market pressure to interest rate during the
active life of FCDs (1991-98). However the instrument of managing
exchange market pressure seems to have undergone a change with the
freeze on FCDs as causality from interest rate to exchange market
pressure has been replaced by causality from domestic credit to exchange
market pressure in the post FCD freeze span and post 9/11 span.
During the active life FCDs (1991-98) dollarisation led to
depreciation of Rupee that in turn contributed to inflation. To avoid
importing inflation the SBP had to defend the Rupee with the increment
in interest rate. With the freeze on FCDs, dollarisation came to a
grinding halt therefore the increment in interest was no more needed to
defend the Rupee. However the low level of foreign-reserves forced the
authorities to resort to outright purchase of foreign currency from the
open market thereby increasing domestic component of money supply. Thus
the instrument of managing exchange market pressure changed from
interest rate to money supply. Post 9/11 given the unanticipated foreign
inflows SBP purchased foreign currency from the market to maintain
competitiveness of our exports--again using money supply to manage the
exchange market pressure. Thus the use of monetary instrument vis-a-vis
exchange market pressure has varied with need of the day. However the
use of interest rate being a consequence of FCDs and dolarisation only,
it is mainly the money supply that is ordinarily used to manage exchange
market pressure.
ANNEXURE--A
Domestic Credit Reserve Money being composed of domestic and
foreign components, the domestic credit is worked out as the difference
between total Reserve Money and the foreign component of Reserve Money.
The foreign component is obtained by multiplying the month-end foreign
reserves outstanding with the relevant month-end nominal exchange rate.
To work out the Domestic Credit in the manner referred above, we need
data on the following series.
* Reserve Money
* Foreign Reserves
* Nominal Exchange Rate
Exchange Market Pressure
Exchange market pressure (emp), defined as sum of exchange rate
depreciation and foreign reserves outflow scaled by monetary base
(Reserve money) requires data on the following:
* Nominal Exchange Rate
* Foreign Reserves
* Reserve Money The data required for generating the Exchange
market pressure series is exactly the same as required for generating
domestic credit series.
Deviation from Purchasing Power Parity
As explained earlier under theoretical framework deviation from
purchasing power parity (PPP) is to be worked out as per Equation (A-l)
which after slight algebraic manipulation is reproduced below for ready
reference.
[z.sub.t] = [e.sub.t] + [[pi].sup.*.sub.t] - [[pi].sub.t] (A-1)
To generate the series 'Deviation from PPP' ([z.sub.t])
we need data on the following:
* Nominal Exchange Rate
* International Price Level (Proxy: US CPI)
* Domestic Price Level (CPI).
REFERENCES
Baeulieu, Joseph J. and Jaffrey A. Miron (1993) Seasonal Unit Roots
in Aggregate US Data. Journal of Econometrics 55, 307-28.
Bautista, G. and C. C. Bautista (2005) Monetary Policy and Exchange
Market Pressure: The Case of Philippines. Journal of Macroeconomics 27:1, 153-68.
Connolly, Michael, and Jose Dantas Da Silveira (1979) Exchange
Market Pressure in Postwar Brazil: An Application of Girton-Roper
Monetary Model. American Economic Review June, 448-54.
Frenkel, J. A. (1976) A Monetary Approach to Exchange Kate:
Doctrinal Aspects and Empirical Evidence. Scandinavian Journal of
Economics 78, 200-224.
Girton, Lance and Don Roper (1977) A monetary model of Exchange
Market Pressure Applied to the Postwar Canadian Experience. American
Economic Review 67:4, 537-48.
Gujrati, Damodar N. (1998) Basic Econometrics. McGraw-Hill:
Singapore, p. 636.
Kamaly, A. and N. Erbil (2000) A VAR Analysis of Exchange Market
Pressure: A Case Study for the MENA Region. Economic Research Forum,
Cairo, Egypt. (Working Paper, 2025.)
Kim, Inchul (1985) Exchange Market Pressure in Korea: An
Application of Girton-Roper Monetary Model. Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, May, 285-63.
Mirakhor, A. and Iqbal Zaidi (2006) Foreign Currency Deposits and
International Liquidity Shortages in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development
Review 45:1, 49-85.
Modeste, Nelson C. (1981) Exchange Market Pressure during the 1970s
in Argentina: An Application of Girton-Roper Monetary Model. Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking May, 234-40.
Mussa, M. (1976) The Exchange Rate, the Balance of Payments, and
Monetary and Fiscal Policy Under a Regime of Controlled Floating.
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 78, 229-48.
Paradhan, Hemanta K., et al. (1989) Exchange Market Pressure in
India: An Empirical Test of Monetary Hypothesis. Parajnan 18:1.
Pilbeam, K. (1999) International Finance. City University. London:
Macmillan Business.
Tanner, Evan (2001) Exchange Market Pressure and Monetary Policy:
Asia and Latin America in the 1990s. IMF Staff Papers 47:3.
Tanner, Evan (2002) Exchange Market Pressure, Currency Crises, and
Monetary Policy: Additional Evidence from Emerging Markets. (IMF Working
Paper, WP/02/14.)
Thornton, John (1995) Exchange Market Pressure in Cost A Rica,
1986-92: An Application of the Girton-Roper Model. International
Economic Journal 9:1.
Wohar, Mark E. and Bun Song Lee (1992) An Application of the
Girton-Roper Monetary Model of Exchange Market Pressure: The Japanese
Experience, 1959-86. Indian Journal of Economics April, 379-407.
(1) For further exposition of the mechaism that restores
equilibrium under different exchange rate regimes, see Frenkel (1976),
Mussa (1976), and Pilbeam (1999).
(2) For technical details of Granger Causality consult Gujrati
(1998).
(3) Fresh foreign currency accounts with banks were allowed shortly
after the freeze on FCDs in May 1998. However given the confidence
shattering freeze, the fresh accounts have failed to mobilise the
volumes that characterised the FCDs during 1991-98. Therefore we refer
to the time period (1991-98) as active life of FCDs.
(4) Monthly data on real income is not available. The use of
industrial production as proxy for: real income is well established.
(5) Before we discuss the results from Granger causality test it is
important to emphasise that Granger causality does not essentially imply
economic causality [Hamilton (1994)]. For example expectations of
changes in reserves could cause domestic credit to change. This would
cause domestic credit to change today, so that the Granger causality
would seem to run from domestic credit to reserves but the true
causality goes from expectations of reserves to domestic credit.
(6) As the open market exchange rate was at a premium over the
official rate, the conversion of $s into Rupees yielded more Rupees in
the open market. Therefore the overseas Pakistanis preferred to send
money through the informal channel (i.e. hundi) instead of remitting it
through banks. The foreign currency thus remitted ended up in the open
market rather than in SBP.
(7) To make the comparison between returns on FCDs and domestic
instruments more meaningful it is note worthy that unlike FCDs domestic
instruments were subjected to taxes and Zakat deductions. Accounting for
such deduction would make the return on domestic instrument lesser than
that shown in the Table 6.
M. Idrees Khawaja <
[email protected]> and Musleh-ud Din
<
[email protected]> are respectively Consultant and Dean,
Faculty of Economics, at the Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Data Span: Characteristics
Length
From To Peculiarity (Years)
1991:04 2005:12 Initiation of the move
towards market
based monetary policy
(Full span) 14.9
1991:04 1998:05 Life period of Foreign
Currency Deposits
(FCDs) 7.2
1998:06 2005:12 Post-FCDs freeze / 9/11 7.7
2001:09 2005:12 Post 9/11 4.4
Table 2
Data Spans: Lags of Dependent Variables for VAR System
Duration: Lags of
No. of Dependent
Interval Years Variable
Full Span 1991:04-2005:12 14.9 4
Post Liberalisation 1995-2005 11 3
FCD Span 1991-04-1998-05 7.2 2
Post FCD Freeze/Post-aid
sanctions/ 9/11 1998:06-2005:12 7.7 2
Post 9/11 2001:09-2005:12 4.4 2
Table 3
Granger Causality Test: Results
Full: FCD: OMOs FCD- 9/11
91:04- 91:04- Initiation Freeze 01:10-
Null Hypothesis 05:12 98:05 95-05 98-05 05:12
[dc.sub.t] causes no no no yes yes
[emp.sub.t] (1.37) (0.74) (0.31) (2.40) (3.87)
[emp.sub.t] causes no no no no no
[dc.sub.t] (0.87) (1.86) (0.69) (1.10) (0.66)
[i.sub.t] causes no no no no yes
[emp.sub.t] (0.79) (0.48) (1.35) (1.10) (2.11)
[emp.sub.t] causes yes yes yes no no
[I.sub.t] (4.03) (2.48) (3.25) (0.21) (0.51)
F-statistics in parenthesis.
Table 4
Purchase/Sale of Foreign Currency by SBP
US $: in Millions
Interbank Kerb Net Addition
Period (Net) Purchases FR *
1999-2000 -797.0 ** 1633.4 836.4
2000-2001 -1125.6 ** 2157.3 1031.7
2001-2002 2483.0 1375.7 3858.7
2002-2003 4546.0 429.3 4975.3
2003-2004 896.8 0.00 896.8
Source: SBP annual reports (various reports).
* FR stands for foreign reserves.
** The negative sign with the figures indicates
sale of foreign currency.
Table 5
Exchange Rate Appreciation and Increase in Foreign Reserves
Appreciation/
Sept.2001 Dec.2003 Increase
Exchange Rate RS. 64.20 RS. 57.21 12%
Foreign Reserves $2,149 $10,941 409%
Table 6
Yield Comparison: FCDs and Domestic Deposits
(4) *
(1) * (3) Wtd. Avg. (5)
Avg. (2) '=(1)+(2) Rate on T.Bill
Return on Exch.Rate FCDs Domestic Rate
Year FCDs Depreciation Yield * Deposits (6 months)
91-92 6.0 3.42 9.42 7.59 12.22
92-93 6.0 8.08 14.08 7.70 12.43
93-94 6.0 12.70 18.70 8.04 10.96
94-95 6.0 1.31 9.31 8.18 12.73
95-96 6.0 13.19 19.19 8.24 13.03
96-97 6.0 15.27 21.27 8.49 16.05
97-98 6.0 13.69 19.69 8.38 15.70
Note: The average rate on Defense Savings Certificate (DSC)
was 13.8 percent however this includes the rats on DSCs of
longer term maturity (5-10 years) whereas the FCDs were
mainly of short-term maturity.
* SBP annual report 97-98 p.116.
** SBP statistical handbook.