FDI and exports in developing countries: theory and evidence.
Majeed, Muhammad Tariq ; Ahmad, Eatzaz
This study analyses the relationship between FDI and Exports, as
well their common determinants in developing countries, using a panel of
49 countries over the period 1970-2004. The analysis shows that both
exports and FDI positively affect each other, though the effect of
exports on FDI is not very significant. Thus, there is no evidence of a
substitution relationship between FDI and exports. The analysis shows
that GDP. economic growth, domestic absorption, and exports positively
affect FDI, a result consistent with market-seeking behaviour of
multinational corporations. On the other hand, external debt and BOP
deficit have negative effects on FDI. The effect of domestic investment
in explaining FDI flow is negative. The study also shows that the lack
of fiscal incentives is a hurdle for FDI. It is also found that
depreciation of real exchange and industrialisation and development of
communication facilities significantly promote exports.
JEL classfication: F21
Keywords: Investment, Foreign Investment, Exports and FDI
I. INTRODUCTION
Multinational enterprises (MNEs) not only generate global flows of
foreign direct investment, but are also extremely for global trade
flows. UNCTAD (2004) estimates that MNEs account for around two-thirds
of world exports. Since MNEs are responsible for a large proportion of
world trade, one may infer that there is a close relationship between
flows of FDI and trade. An MNE network, consisting of a parent and a
network of affiliates, generates simultaneous flows of goods and
investments. In this context the pool of knowledge and associated
models, which explain international trade, has grown substantially in
the recent past, but there is less theoretical consensus about the
relationship between trade flows and FDI. The fact that exporting and
local production are alternative ways for an MNE to serve the demand in
a foreign market suggests a substitutability relationship between FDI
and trade. MNE production in the host country implies that local
production is a substitute for exports from the home country. On the
other hand, MNE affiliates' production in a host country can
generate a demand for intermediate goods from the parent, resulting in a
complementary relationship between flows of FDI and trade (exports).
Theoretical reasoning therefore supports both these possibilities,
providing a strong incentive for empirical analysis.
A multinational can serve foreign demand in two ways, either it can
export its product or it can create productive capacity via foreign
direct investment. The advantage of FDI is that it allows lower marginal
cost than exports. The disadvantage is that FDI is mostly irreversible and, hence, entails the risk of creating under-utilised capacity in case
the market turns out to be smaller than expected. The presence of demand
uncertainty and irreversibility gives rise to an interior solution,
whereby the MNE generates both exports and FDI under certain conditions.
As most developing countries experience a shortage of capital, this
is reflected in their respective savings-investment and import-export
gaps, which implies that developing countries have insufficient savings
and/or foreign exchange to finance their investment needs. To bridge
this gap they need an inflow of foreign capital and exports growth. FDI
is an important source of capital for growth in developing countries. In
the 1960s and 1970s many countries maintained a rather cautions and
sometimes an outright negative, position with respect to foreign
investment. In the 1980s, however, the attitudes shifted radically
towards a more welcoming policy stance. This change was mainly due to
economic problems facing the developing world. Thus, while FDI is
surging, other forms of capital flows to developing countries are
diminishing. Aid has continuously declined as a share of capital inflows
since the 1960s. Commercial loans, a major source of capital flows in
the 1970s has virtually disappeared since the debt crisis of the 1980s.
In the earlier literature the determinants of FDI were described
theoretically without giving empirical results [for example, Lall
(1978)]. Latter on, the studies based on empirical analysis have
increasingly appeared in the literature. These studies differ from the
earlier studies on the basis of theory as well. In the initial
literature pure economic theory international trade and the theory of
firm were adopted as the theoretical base for empirical study of FDI
determinants. These theories assume the presence of perfect competition
and identical production function and attribute FDI flows to difference
in the interest rates across countries. But it hardly explains the large
volume of FDI flows across countries. (1)
Recent theories explaining FDI, in particular of MNCs
(multinational corporations) growth, have turned to the explanations
based on market imperfections, oligoplistic interdependence and the
possession of the monopolistic advantage. It is assumed that for FDI to
take place a necessary condition is that the investing firms have some
monopolistic advantages, not possessed by local competitors.
Given the important role that they have played in rapid expansion
of countries most notably in East Asia during the 1970s [see, e.g.,
Nayyar (1978) and Dunning (1993)], MNEs are increasingly seen as capable
of helping their host countries in promoting their manufacturing
exports. The country experiences with respect to the role of MNEs in
export promotion, however, vary a great deal [see Kumar and Siddharthan
(1997)]. This is because MNEs are highly selective about the location of
export- platform, export-orientation or offshore production.
In a survey article, De Mello (1997) discusses the latest
development in literature on the determinants of FDI and impact of
inward FDI on growth in developing countries. The study argues that
policy regime of the host countries is a potentially important FDI
determinant. The recent literature has provided policy makers in
developing countries with more adequate tools and more accurate
benchmarks for cross-country comparisons and policy evaluation. The
study further argues that foreign investors are motivated primarily by
international rent seeking under standard profit maximising assumptions.
The most important factors explaining the gush of FDI inflows into the
developing countries in recent years have been the foreign acquisition
of domestic firms in the process of privatisation, the globalisation of
production and increased economic and financial integration.
De Mello (1997) also present a brief summary of the case studies
such as O'Sullivan (1993), Bajorubio and Sovilla-Rivero (1994),
Wang and Swain (1995), Milner and Pentecost (1996), and Lee and
Mansfield (1996), which specify inflation, exchange rate, domestic
expenditures and net trade ratio as important determinants of FDI.
Wang and Swain (1995) test the relative importance of independent
variables, including market size, cost of capital, labour costs, tariff
barriers, exchange rates, import volumes and economic growth in OECD countries as well as political stability, within the framework of a
one-equation model. (2) Time series data between 1978 and 1992 for
Hungary and China are fitted into one-equation models OLS method.
Estimates suggest that the size of host country market plays a positive
role, while the cost of capital variable and political instability are
negatively correlated with investment inflows. These results support the
hypotheses that low-cost labour and currency depreciation are important
factors in explaining how much capital into particular country. There is
little evidence to support the classical hypotheses concerning tariff
barriers and import variables. The OECD growth rates show significant
positive correlation with FDI in Hungry.
Funke and Holly (1992) argue that the majority of the previous
approaches have emphasised demand factors. Such models have generally
been rather unsuccessful in explaining long run trends in export
performance. The study takes into account both supply side and demand
side factors and applies the model to the West German manufacturing
sector using quarterly data over the period 1961-1 to 1987-4. The
findings of the study suggest that supply side factors are more
important for explaining export performance than demand side factors.
Togan (1993) investigates changes in the structure of export
incentives in Turkey from 1983 to 1990. The export incentives considered
are export credits, tax rebate scheme, premium from the "Support
and Price Stabilisation Fund", duty free imports of intermediates
and raw materials, and exemption from the value added tax, foreign
exchange allocations, exemption from the corporate income tax and other
subsidies. The study finds that during the 1980s the levels of
economy-wide subsidy rates and inter-industry dispersion of incentives
have substantially been lowered. The study also finds that the Turkish
export- and import-competing industries have benefited from the export
incentives more than the other sectors.
In a study based on small sample, Riedel, Hall and Grawe (1984)
investigate the determinants of export performance in India on the basis
of time-series analysis over the period 1968-1978. The study analyses
the effects of relative price of exports, relative domestic demand and
domestic profitability on export performance. The dependent variable
used is the ratio of index of constant price exports to the index of
industrial production. Exports are expressed as a ratio to output in
order to account for the effect of expansion of production capacity. The
results support the view that domestic market conditions strongly
influence export behaviour. The variable measuring domestic
profitability or relatively domestic demand is found to be statistically
significant in explaining export behaviour in 23 of 30 sectors. Relative
price, incorporating export policy incentives and the exchange rate turn
out to be statistically significant in only 10 of the 30 sectors.
A more recent study of Sharma (2000) investigates exports
determinant in India using annual data for the period 1970-98. The
results of study suggest that demand for Indian exports increase when
its export price falls in relation to world prices. Furthermore, the
real appreciation of the rupee adversely affects Indian exports. Exports
supply is positively related to the domestic relative price of exports
and higher domestic demand reduces export supply. Foreign investors
appear to have statistically no significant impact on export
performance, although the coefficient of FDI is positive.
Hoekman and Djankov (1998) analyse the magnitude of change in the
export structure in Central and Eastern European countries. The study
investigates the relative importance of processing (subcontracting)
trade, imports of input, and FDI as determinants of the countries'
export performance in European Union markets. The findings of the study
suggest that in most countries export of intermediate goods and
machinery drive the changes in export structure. Local enterprises
apparently exploit the opportunity to acquire foreign inputs and
know-how in order to improve production quality, thereby expanding their
export market share in the European Union.
The study observes that FDI has been concentrated in the sectors
where the Central and Eastern European countries do not have a revealed
comparative advantage (that is, they are not relatively specialised in
terms of their export share in Eastern Union markets). Of the five
countries for which data are available, Poland is the only one with a
significant positive association between FDI and exports structure. The
negative relationship for the other countries implies that FDI could be
a force for change. Foreign investors must perceive the industries
concerned to be viable in the median term, and over time this FDI may
lead to greater changes in the countries' export composition. Thus
FDI complements efforts by domestic industries to restructure and
upgrade production facilities.
It appears from the above review that studies on FDI determinants
are mostly based on host country characteristics that play important
role in determining FDI inflows. While studies on export determinants
are mostly based on country specific factors as export expansion
schemes, subsidies; etc. There is hardly any study that conducted panel
data estimation on export determinants and FDI determinants with
specific emphasis on their interrelationship for a large number of
developing countries.
The objective of the study is, therefore, to find out common
determinants of exports and FDI. The study also explores the
relationship between exports and FDI to determine whether the two are
substitutes or complements for each other. The rest of the paper is
organised as follows. Section 2 explains the model and framework of
analysis. Section 3 introduces the data set and estimation procedure.
Section 4 puts forward the main findings from empirical analysis.
Section 5 presents a summary of results with a few policy implications.
2. METHODOLOGY
We now formulate a framework of analysis to determine the effects
of various factors on FDI and exports in developing countries, which we
have taken in our sample. The underlying objective is to explain the
rational behind foreign direct investment and exports. It is generally
believed that MNCs invest in those countries where they expect higher
rates of return on their investments. There are many economic and non-
economic factors, which determine the profits of firms on foreign direct
investment. The indicators of economic factors are the typical
macro-economic indicators of performance such as external debt,
inflation rate, trade and investment policies of the government and
physical infrastructure. The non-economic factors include political
instability, bureaucratic bottlenecks and law and order situation in the
country.
2.1. Determinants of FDI
In empirical literature a number of economic, social and incentive
variables have been used that determine FDI and exports. Our study
incorporates the following variables.
Market Size
The market size hypotheses argue that inward FDI is a function of
the size of the host country market. We take GDP as a proxy for the
market size. High demand, prospects for economies of scale, good
economic health and absorptive capacity are the factors that give green
signal to foreign investors. Combined effect of such factors can be
captured by market size. Large market size is expected to have a
positive impact on FDI. The positive impact is also justified in
literature in Schneider and Fry (1985), Wheeler and Mody (1992), and
Zhang and Markusen (1999).
Growth of GDP
Market size exhibits existing demand in an economy, while growth
represents the future potential. A rate level of economic growth is a
strong indication of market opportunities. The growth of the host market
is deemed to be significant for expansionary direct investment [Clegg
and Scott-Green, 1998]. Growth is also important because higher rates of
economic growth are usually associated with increase in the
profitability of corporations [Gold (1989)]. This variable has received
less support in literature as compared to the market size variable
[Goldberg (1972); Scaperlanda and Balough (1983); Culem (1988) and Clegg
(1995)].
Domestic Absorption
Higher the domestic absorption, the higher will be the inflow of
FDI [De Mello (1999)]. We measure the domestic absorption as the sum of
GDP and trade deficit. Since GDP is already present among the
determinants of FDI, any variations in domestic absorption that are not
explained by GDP, must be explained by trade deficit. In other words keeping GDP constant, changes in trade deficit translate one to one into
changes in domestic absorption. Hence we expect the positive impact of
this variable of FDI.
Exchange Rate
Exchange rate affects FDI in several ways. Froot and Stein (1991)
have discussed the relative wealth effect of exchange rates. A rise in
the exchange rate in terms of host country currency over the home
country currency implies a depreciation of the host country currency. A
real depreciation of the host country currency favours home country
purchases of host country assets and therefore leads to an increase in
inward FDI in the host country. Gushman (1985) and Culem (1988)
emphasise the effect of exchange rate changes on relative labour cost. A
real depreciation of the host country currency allows home country
investors to hire more labour for a given amount of the home country
currency, and therefore real depreciation is associated with an increase
in inward FDI in the host country. Klein and Rosengren (1994) support
the significance of the relative wealth effect and fail to support the
relative labour cost effect.
Balance-of-Payments Deficit
The expected sign of the coefficient of balance of payments (BOP),
as measured by current account balance is negative, because large
deficit in accounts mean a country is living beyond its means and
foreign investors feel the danger of restrictions on free capital
movement and the profit of the firms will be difficult to transfer
[Schneider and Frey (1985)].
External Debt Burden
It shows the external imbalances. Higher debt burden creates
constraints not only in terms of new private lending but also in terms
of FDI flows [Nunnenkamp (1991)]. Hence it is expected to discourage FDI
and the coefficient on external debt could be negative.
Savings
Feldstein and Horioka (1980) proposed that there should be no
relationship between domestic saving and domestic investment. Saving in
each country responds to the worldwide opportunities for investment
while investment in that country is financed by the worldwide pool of
capital. Conversely, if international savings tend to be invested in the
country of origin, differences among countries in investment rates
should correspond closely to differences in saving rates. This
relationship between domestic savings and domestic investment is an
indirect approach to test the degree of capital mobility. We expect
favourable effect of savings on FDI.
Domestic Investment
Domestic investment may be a substitute or a complement for FDI,
depending on the types of FDI and investment climate in the host
country. However, the literature shows mixed results. When domestic
investment increases marginal productivity of investment decreases and
if the marginal productivity of FDI also decreases then relationship
will be that of substitutes. This may happen when domestic investment
dominates in production sector. On the contrary, if marginal
productivity of FDI increases then relationship will be complement. This
may happen when domestic investment dominates in infrastructure.
Further, if domestic investors and foreign investors compete for joint
ventures then domestic investment and FDI will be substitutes [see, for
example, Buffie (1993].
Credit Facilities
Credit facilities create investment climate for domestic investors.
Better credit facilities mean more domestic investment. In this
situation there will be little room for foreign investors. So we expect
negative influence of this variable on FDI.
Government Consumption
Government consumption leads to higher level of fiscal deficit,
which in turn generates macroeconomic instability and poor credit
position of a country. Increase in government consumption also leads to
higher rates of interest, which crowd out investment including foreign
investment. Hence we expect adverse effect of this variable on FDI.
Official Development Assistance
Official development assistance is taken as an indicator of
development activities. Expenditures financed by official development
assistance favourably determine infrastructure and also indicate the
good terms with international institutes that buildup the confidence of
foreign investors. So, foreign investors like to come in these
countries. Luger and Shetty (1985) have presented suggestive evidence on
this relationship.
Indirect Taxes
Indirect taxes are expected to have negative effect on FDI because
high taxes increase the cost of production, which is a disincentive for
foreign investors [Coughlin, Terza, and Arromdee (1991)]. However, in
empirical literature the effect of this variable is controversial. (3)
Urbanisation
The extent of urbanisation is a social variable, which is expected
to have positive impact on FDI as proposed by Root and Ahmad (1979).
Urban demand for manufactured goods is higher than the rural demand.
Moreover, if a country covers a vast area under urbanisation, the
production environment for MNCs would be better. However, urbanisation
also creates overcrowding, crime, and burden the existing facilities.
Hence it can also affect FDI adversely.
In the light of the above discussion, we specify the following
equation for the determination of FDI inflow.
FDI = f ([EX.sub.it] [GDP.sub.it] [GROW.sub.it] [DA.sub.it]
[EXCH.sub.it] [BOP.sub.it] [ED.sub.it] [SAV.sub.it] [DI.sub.it]
[CRED.sub.it] [GC.sub.it] [OD.sub.it] [IT.sub.it], [TV.sub.it]
[TP.sub.it] [UP.sub.it] [FDI.sub.it - 1])
where the subscript i (=1,... n) represents country and t (= 1,...
T) the period of time (year). The variables appearing in the equation
are defined as follows.
FDI = Foreign direct investment as a percentage of GDP,
EX = Exports as a percentage of GDP,
GDP = Gross domestic production in constant prices of 1989,
GROW = Annual percentage of growth rate of GDP,
DA = Domestic absorption, which is equal to GDP plus trade deficit,
EXCH = Real exchange rate, obtained by multiplying the nominal
exchange rate by US CPI and divided by domestic CPI,
BOP = Balance of payments as a percentage of GDP,
EL) = External debt as a percentage of GDP,
SAV = National savings as percentage of GDP,
DI= Domestic investment as a percentage of GDP,
CRED = Credit facilities to domestic sector as a percentage of GDP,
GC = General government consumption expenditures as a percentage of
GDP,
OD = Official development assistance as a percentage of GDP,
IT = Indirect taxes as a percentage of GDP,
TV = Number of television sets per 1000 persons,
TP = Number of telephone sets per 1000 persons,
UP = Urban population as a percentage of total population,
FDI (-1) = Foreign direct investment as a percentage of GDP in the
previous year.
2.2. Determinants of Export
Export promotion strategies gain added importance in trade
liberalisation regime. On one hand developing countries are facing twin
deficits, namely, fiscal deficit and trade deficit. On the other hand,
external debt crises create further financial problems. In such sorry
state of financial position, the sole inflow of FDI is not sufficient
and the expansion of export sector for the improvement of financial
disturbance also needs to be addressed. In this respect, we identify
various determinants of exports. Export growth is basically determined
by external factors, for this we employ two variables FDI and real
exchange rate. However, exports are also affected by domestic factors.
In this respect we incorporate GDP, GDP growth rate, indirect taxes,
communication facilities, savings, industrialisation, labour force and
official development assistance.
Production Level
It is the supply side determinant of exports [see Bertil (1968)]. A
higher level of production is the main cause of export expansion,
because surplus of output can be exhausted in international markets. In
a close economy surplus of production leads to fall in prices, which, in
turn, creates pessimism among producers. In an open economy such
surpluses create foreign reserves by exporting production. So we expect
the positive impact of GDP on exports growth. In empirical literature
Kumar (1998) confirms the positive impact of GDP on exports.
Real Exchange Rate
A fall in the relative domestic prices due to exchange rate
depreciation, which makes exports cheaper in international markets and,
hence result in increased demand for exports. Therefore we expect
positive impact of real exchange rate on export growth.
Communication Facilities
In this era, when time is shrinking, the importance of
communication facilities has become more important. For the measurement
of communication facilities we employ two variables, namely, the number
of television sets and the number of telephone sets in use. These two
variables have also been justified in empirical literature [Kumar
(1998)]. Expansion of such facilities has favourable effect for
exploration and excess to the world markets. Hence, we expect that the
provision of such facilities will favourably affect exports.
Indirect Taxes
The effect of this variable is expected to be adverse on production
decisions. But we cannot rule out the possibility of positive effect on
exports due to fiscal incentives by government. Specifically, if
government provides tax exemptions for the exports sector, higher rates
of indirect taxes can have the negative effect on domestic demand
resulting in exportable surplus.
Savings
Generally, in developing countries the proportion of savings used
for nonproductive factors, for example purchasing of jewelry, property,
etc., is larger. Therefore higher savings result is large volume of
goods made available for exports. So we expect positive impact of this
variable on exports.
Industrialisation
The agricultural output is subjected to uncertainty, particularly
because of operation of nature's vagaries. Accordingly, now a day,
just on the basis of agricultural output no country has greater incomes
and outputs. On the other hand, it is the industrialisation that results
in maximum utilisation of natural and human resources of the country and
industrial output is more or less stable. Thus industrialisation will
provide greater stimulus to output and national income of the country.
Industrialisation also promotes agriculture sector and agriculture
uplifts the industrial sector. The industrial development will have the
effect of developing the allied and related sectors.
The situation of persistent deficit in balance of payments is
attributed to concentration in agriculture exports, falling prices of
exports, the imports restrictions by rich countries and the increasing
import bill due to increased demand for oil and manufactured products,
etc. Through industrialisation a country can enhance industrial
production; replace the agriculture exports by the industrial exports,
which command reasonable and stable prices in the world markets.
Moreover, industrialisation reduces dependence on imports by initiating
the process of import substitution. Keeping in view all such arguments,
we expect that industrialisation will have favourable effect on exports.
Foreign Direct Investment
In empirical literature the role of FDI in exports promotion is
controversial. Many studies [e.g. Pfaffermayr (1996)] find positive
effect of FDI on exports. The main reason underlying is the export
orientation of MNCs. Furthermore in order to promote exports government
can adopt FDI-led export growth strategies with twin objectives of
capturing the benefits of both FDI inflow and exports growth. On the
other hand, many studies find insignificant or weak impact of FDI on
exports [see Hoekman and Djankov (1997); Majeed and Abroad (2006)]. Such
studies point out that the role of FDI in export promotion in developing
countries remains controversial and depends crucially on the motive for
such investment. If the motive behind FDI is to capture domestic market
(tariff-jumping type investment), it may not contribute to export
growth. On the other hand, if the motive is tap exports markets by
taking advantage of the country's comparative advantage, then FDI
may contributes to export growth. The specified equation for exports is
as follow.
[EX.sub.it] = f ([FDI.sub.it], [GDP.sub.it], [SAV.sub.it],
[IT.sub.it], [EXCH.sub.it], [TV.sub.it], [TP.sub.it], [VAD.sub.it]),
where
EX = Exports as a percentage of GDP,
FDI = Foreign direct investment as a percentage of GDP,
GDP = Gross domestic production in constant prices of 1989,
SAV = National savings as a percentage of GDP,
IT = Indirect taxes as a percentage of GDP,
EXCH = Real exchange rate, obtained by multiplying the nominal
exchange rate by US CPI and divided by domestic CPI,
VAD = Industry value added as a percentage of GDP,
TV = Number of television sets per 1000 persons,
TP = Number of telephone sets per 1000 persons.
3. DATA AND ESTIMATION PROCEDURE
The data for this study have been taken from World Development
Indicators (WDI) 2005. Originally a sample of 155 countries was selected
but after screening process 49 countries were chosen for which data on
most of the variables were available for at least 15 years. All the
variables are measured in US dollar at constant prices.
We now discuss estimation procedure for our model. Pooling of the
time-series and cross-section data provides a large sample, which is
expected to yield efficient parameter estimates. Since political,
structural and institutional characteristics vary from country to
country, imposing a single relationship to all units is likely to
suppress information. In order to overcome this problem we will use the
approach of uniform shifts. The econometric literature suggests two
approaches for shifts across countries namely the fixed effects model
and random effects model. Another problem in the estimation is
simultaneity in the FDI and exports equations as both the variables
appear in the two equations. In order to overcome both the problems of
simultaneity bias and non-uniformity across countries we adopt Three
Stage Least Squares method to the fixed effects model.
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS AND INTERPRETATION
In this chapter we report the empirical results based on pooled
data for 49 developing countries over the period 1970 to 2004. The main
findings of the study are as follows. The variable GDP, which is a
suitable proxy for market size, turned out to be significant. The effect
of growth rate is also significant. The variable growth is much
important because higher rates of economic growth are usually associated
with an increase in the profitability of MNCs. The variables BOP and
external debt have negative and significant effects on FDI inflows. The
increasing debt burdens and persistent deficit in BOP mean that a
country is suffering financial distress. Furthermore, debt service
charges also create financial disturbance. Such situation reflects that
government will be left with fewer resources to spend on development
activities and will be likely to raise import duties and other taxes
that create negative effects on FDI.
The affect of domestic investment is insignificant with negative
sign. This is so because an increase in domestic investment has two
effects on foreign investment. On one hand domestic investment is likely
to crowd out foreign investment, on the other hand it may also
complement foreign investment, particularly if it is in the form of
infrastructure development and those industries that produce inputs to
be used in the production activities undertaken by foreign investors.
According to our results the crowding-out effect dominates the
complementary role of domestic investment. The impact of communication
facilities is found to be significant with positive signs in explaining
FDI flow and export growth. Such facilities are helpful in exploring and
access to new markets.
The effect of FDI on exports is significant and positively. This is
in lines with the success stories of Asian countries in the form of FDI
led export growth. Most of MNCs are export oriented and tend to use
developing countries as export platform. Further, export sector is
facilitated by various fiscal incentives. Such advantages of export
promotion policy are exhausted by MNCs. (4) The MNCs through which most
FDI is undertaken have the well-established contacts and the up-to-date
information about foreign markets. If the motive behind FDI is to
capture domestic market (tariff-jumping type investment), it may not
contribute to export growth. On the other hand, if the motive is top tap
exports markets by taking advantage of the country's comparative
advantage, then FDI may contribute to export growth to the extent
permissible under the prevailing policy regime. By now it is well known
that an outward oriented regime encourages export-oriented FDI. Export
growth is an indicator of trade liberalisation and friendly investment
climate in the host countries. Export growth favourably affects the
macroeconomic variables that in turn attract foreign investors.
The effect of GDP is significant with positive signs in explaining
exports, indicating that higher production level in a country makes it
possible to generate surplus output for exports purpose. Developing
countries have relative advantages for agriculture goods. They can
exhaust benefits of lower cost production by export growth policies.
Moreover, large size of GDP also creates environments for investment
decisions. The results further show that industrial value added as a
percentage of GDP is a highly significant variable in explaining
exports. Therefore, the exports performance of a country improves when
the composition of GDP changes as a result of industrialisation.
The effect of real exchange rate on export growth is insignificant
with positive sign, indicating a weak relationship. Thus, the real
depreciation of domestic currency is not necessarily fruitful for export
promotion. This result is consistent with theory as well as empirical
evidence found in other studies [e.g. Sharma (2000)].
The results show that increase in savings significantly contributes
to exports. Higher savings imply lower interest rates that promote
investment opportunities. The investment is the key channel for export
growth. In developing countries government provide many incentives for
export promotion strategies. The domestic investment take place in
different sectors but it is much responsive in trade sector to
incentives provided by government. After the activism of WTO developing
countries are enhancing export oriented investment schemes. These are
the arguments that support the proposition of investment led export
growth. Over and above, savings are the source of removal of internal
and external gaps in developing countries. As two-gap theory explains
saving-investment and exports-imports gaps in developing countries,
large savings are the source of removal of domestic gap that in turn
remove external gap by enhancing export growth.
In the globalisation era, when the value of time is most important,
the need of wide spread communication facilities is becoming most
important. For the measurement of communication facilities we employed
two variables, namely, number of Televisions and number of Telephones.
The effects of expansions in communication facilities are positive and
both the variables turned out to be significant. Thus expanding the net
of such facilities is helpful in exploration of new international
markets. Further, these networks make it easy to access the world
markets. As developing countries' exports are concentrated in few
markets they can reap the benefits of global communication facilities.
The results are in line with Kumar (1998).
5. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The objective of this study has been to find out factors, which are
important in determining the inflow of FDI and exports in developing
countries and to determine relationship between exports and FDI. For
this purpose the study used a sample of panel observations for 49
developing countries over the period 1970-2004. The data are derived
from the World Development Indicators (WDI) 2005. Fixed effects (country
specific intercepts) model, with system of equations, is employed for
the estimation of the relationship of exports and FDI with their
potential common determinants based on the panel data. A number of
conclusions can be drawn from the study, which are summarised as
follows.
The analysis shows that GDP, economic growth, domestic absorption
and exports positively affect FDI, a result consistent with market
seeking behaviour of multinational corporations. On the other hand,
external debt and BOP deficit have negative effects on FDI. It is found
that the effects of increase in domestic investment on FDI inflow is
negative Thus the crowding out effect of domestic investment outweighs
the potential complementarity created by domestic investment. This
indicates that domestic investment in developing countries is not of
facilitating nature and these countries cannot absorb much investment.
The effect of taxes is negative and insignificant. The negative
relationship implies that lack of fiscal incentives is a hurdle for FDI.
It is also found that depreciation of real exchange and
industrialisation and development of communication facilities
significantly promote exports. This study provides a significant
complementary relationship between FDI and exports with causation in
both directions. The effect of increased FDI has been found
significantly positive, whereas, in the reverse direction, the positive
impact from increased exports on FDI is confirmed at lower levels of
significance. Thus, there is no evidence of a substitution relationship
between FDI and exports.
It is pertinent to maintain the importance role of a high and
sustainable economic growth in attracting foreign investment. The study
shows that a sustainable growth patterns attract FDI and promotes
exports. The developing countries can attract FDI inflows by removing
the artificial barriers and control on exports and imports. An open and
export-oriented policy can be promoted with lower tariffs and allowing
free mobility of capital. Widening of the net of communication
facilities is also instrumental in attracting FDI inflows and exports
growth. To this end subsidies may be provided to the communication
sector.
REFERENCES
Aggarwal, J. P. (1980) Determinants of FDI: A Survey.
Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 116, 739-773.
Bajorubico, O. and S. Sosvilla-Rivero (1994) An Econometric
Analysis of FDI in Spain. Southern Economic Journal 61, 104-120.
Bartik, T. J. (1985) Business Location Decisions in the United
States: Estimates of the Effects of Unionisation, Taxes, and Other
Characteristics of States. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics
3, 14-22.
Bertil, O. (1968) Model Construction in International Trade Theory.
Oxford: Published in Induction, Growth and Trade. Clarendon Press.
325-341.
Buffie, S. E. (1993) Direct Foreign Investment, Crowding out and
Underemployment in the Domestic Economy. Oxford Economic Paper 45,
639-667.
Carlton, D. W. (1983) The Location and Employment Choices of New
Firms: An Econometric Model with Discrete and Continuous Endogenous Variables. This Review 65,440-490.
Clegg, J. (1995) The Determinants of United States Foreign Direct
Investment in the European Community: A Critical Reappraisal. Paper
Presented at the 21st Annual Conference of the European Business
Academy, University of Urbino.
Clegg, J. and S. Scott-Green (1998) The Determinants of Japanese
Foreign Direct Investment Flows to the European Community, 1963-1990. In
J.-L. Mucchielli (ed.) Multinational Location Strategy 6, 29-49.
Coughlin, C. C., J. V. Terza, and V. Arromdee (1991) State
Characteristics and the Location of FDI within the United States. Review
of Economics and Statistics 73, 675-683.
Culem, C. (1988) The Locational Determinants of Direct Investment
among Industrial Countries. European Economic Review 32, 885-904.
De Mello, L. R. (1999) Foreign Direct Investment--Led Growth:
Evidence from Time Series and Panel Data. Oxford Economic Papers 51,
133-151.
De Mello, L. R. (1997) FDI in Developing Countries and Growth: A
Selective Survey. The Journal of Development Studies 34:1, 1-34.
Dunning, J. H. (1993) Multinational Enterprises and the Global
Economy. Working- ham: Addison-Wesley.
Feldstein, M. and C. Horioka (1980) Domestic Saving and
International Capital Flows. Economic Journal 30, 314-329.
Froot, K. A. and J. C. Stein (1991) Exchange Rates and Foreign
Direct Investment: An Imperfect Capital Market Approach. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 106:4, 1191- 1217.
Funke, M. and S. Holly (1992) The Determinants of West German
Exports of Manufactures: An Integrated Demand and Supply Approach.
Weltwirtschafiliches Archive 128:3, 498-512.
Gold, D. (1989) Foreign Direct Investment. In A. P. Harvey (ed.)
International Corporate Finance.
Goldberg, M. A. (1972) Determinants of U.S. Direct Investment in
the EEC: Comments. American Economic Review 62, 692-699.
Gushman, D. (1985) Real Exchange Rate Risk, Expectations, and the
Level of Direct Investment. Review of Economics and Statistics 67:2,
297-308.
Hoekman, B. and S. Djankov (1997) Determinants of Export Structure
of Countries in Central and Eastern Europe. The World Bank Economic
Review 11:3, 471-487.
Jeon, Y. D. (1992) The Determinants of Korean Foreign Direct
Investment in Manufacturing Industries. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 128,
527-541.
Jorgenson, D. W. (1963) Capital Theory and Investment Behaviour.
American Economic Review 53, 247-259.
Klein, M. W. and E. Rosengren (1994) The Real Exchange Rate and
Foreign Direct Investment in the United States. Journal of International
Economics 36, 373-389.
Kumar, N. (1998) Multinational Enterprises, Regional Economic
Integration, and Export-Platform Production in the Host Countries: An
Empirical Analysis for the US and Japanese Corporations.
Weltwirtschafiliches Archiv 134, 450-483.
Kumar, N. and N. S. Siddharthan (1997) Technology, Market Structure
and Internationalisation: Issues and Policies for Developing Countries.
London: Routledge.
Lall, S. (1978) Transnationals, Domestic Enterprises and the
Industrial Structure in Host LDCs: A Survey. Oxford Economic Papers 30,
217-248.
Lee, J. Y. and E. Mansfield (1996) Intellectual Property Protection
and US Foreign Direct Investment. Review of Economics and Statistics 30,
217-248.
Luger, M. I. and S. Shetty (1985) Determinants of Foreign Plant
Start-Ups in the United States: Lessons for Policymakers in the
Southeast. Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law 18, 223-245.
Majeed, M. T. and E. Ahmad (2006) Determinants of Exports in
Developing Countries. The Pakistan Development Review 45:4, 1265-74.
Milner, C. and E. Pentecost (1996) Locational Advantage and US
Foreign Direct Investment in UK. Applied Economics 28, 605-615.
Nayyar, D. (1978) Transnational Corporations and Manufactured
Exports from Poor Countries. Economic Journal 88, 59-84.
Nunnenkamp, P. (1991) Developing Countries' Attractiveness for
Foreign Direct Investment, Debt Overhang and Sovereign Risk as Major
Impediments? The Pakistan Development Review 3:4, 1145-1158.
O'Sullivan, P. J. (1993) An assessment of Irelands'
Export-Led Growth Strategy via Foreign Direct Investment, 1960-1980.
Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 129, 139-158.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Economic Advisors Wing, Ministry of Finance.
Petrochilos, G. A. (1989) Foreign Direct Investment and the
Development Process: The Case of Greece. Avebury: Gower Publishing
Company Ltd.
Pfaffermayr, M. (1996) Foreign Outward Direct Investment and
Exports in Austrian Manufacturing: Substitutes or Complements?
Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 132:2, 501-522.
Riedel, J., C. Hall, and R. Grawe (1984) Determinants of Indian
Exports Performance in the 1970s. Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 120:1,
40-63.
Root, F. and A. Ahmed (1979) Empirical Determinants of
Manufacturing Direct Foreign Investment in Developing Countries.
Economic Development and Cultural Change 27, 751-767.
Scaperlanda, A. E. and R. S. Balough (1983) Determinants of U.S.
Direct Investment in the E. E. C. Revisited. European Economic Review
21, 381-390.
Schneider, F. and B. S. Frey (1985) Economical Political
Determinants of FDI. World Development 13:2, 161-175.
Sharma, K. (2000) Export Growth in India: Has FDI Played a Role?
at:http://www.econ.yale.edu/~egcenter/
Togan, S. (1993) How to Assess the Significance of Export
Incentives: An Application to Turkey. Weltwirtschafiliches Archive
129:4, 777-799.
UNCTAD (2004) World Investment Report 2004: The Shift Towards
Services. United Nations, Geneva.
Wang, Z. Q. and N. J. Swain (1995) The Determinants of Foreign
Direct Investment in Transforming Economies: Evidence from Hungary and
China. Weltwirtschaftliches Archive 131,359-382.
Wheeler, D. and A. Mody (1992) International Investment Location
Decisions: The Case of US Firms. Journal of International Economics 33,
57-76.
Zhang, K. H. and J. R. Maskusen (1999) Vertical Multinationals and
Host Country Characteristics. Journal of Development Economics 59,
233-252.
(1) The FDI flows to developing countries increased manifold,
rising from us $ 33.7 billion in 1990 to $ 172.9 billion in 1997
[Pakistan (2000-2001)].
(2) Except the cost of capital and the average growth rates in home
countries, most of these independent variables could be found in
Agrawal's (1980) article. Many empirically studies [for example,
Petrochilos (1989)] have supported Jorgenson's (1963) hypotheses
that FDI is determined by cost of capital. Other suggests that faster
growth of the home countries has played a role in promoting FDI in host
countries [Jeon (1992)]. A variable OECD growth rate is, therefore,
applied to test whether economic prosperity in the major FDI home
countries helps directly or indirectly parent firms to get bigger and
accumulate assets for both licensing and FDI in both Hungary and China.
(3) Evidence of conflicting results is plentiful. For example,
Carlton (1983) concludes that taxes did not have major effects on the
location of new plants. However, Bartik (1985) finds that taxes deter
the location decisions of MNCs.
(4) Empirical literature offers a great deal in this regard. See,
for example, Kumar and Siddharthan (1997).
Muhammad Tariq Majeed <
[email protected].> is Lecturer at the
University of Glasgow, U.K. Eatzaz Ahmad <
[email protected]> is
Professor of Economics at Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
Table 1a
Parameter Estimates of the Fixed Effects Model
Variables Export Equation FDI Equation
Export .002 (1.64)
FDI 0.011 (1.873 **)
GDP 2.17E-18 (2.486 *) 2.21E-18 (2.296 *)
GROW 0.017 (2.545 *)
VAD 0.007 (9.082 *)
BOP -0.064 (-1.998 *)
ED -0.0007 (-3.134 *)
DI -0.052 (-1.274)
TV 0.0004 (3.688 *) 5.68E-08 (1.166)
TP 0.0001 (0.894) 0.0003 (3.921 *)
EXCH 1.56E-06 (1.122) -3.49E-08 (-0.060)
SAV 0.080 (1.747 **) 0.034 (1.083)
IT 0.325 (4.853 *) -0.072 (-1.168)
DA 0.071 (1.6308)
CR 0.075 (1.065)
GC 0.075 (1.069)
OD 0.022 (0.361)
UP 0.0007 (1.853 **)
FDI (-1) 0.002 (3.854 *)
[R.sup.2] 0.84 0.88
Adj. [R.sup.2] 0.82 0.85
DW 1.63 1.92
Note: The numbers in parentheses are the computed t-values. The
statistics significant at 5 percent and 10 percent levels are
indicated by * and ** respectively.
Table 1b
Country Specific Intercepts of the Fixed Effects Models
Export FDI
Country Equation Equation
Argentina -0.382 * -0.039
Benin 0.107 * 0.033 **
Burkina Faso -0.081 * 0.005
Brazil -0.342 * 0.040
Botswana 0.092 * 0.065 *
Chile -0.101 * 0.073 **
Cote d'Ivoire 0.148 * 0.047 *
Cameroon -0.023 0.043 *
Colombia -0.147 * 0.047
Costa Rica 0.032 0.037 *
Dominican Rep. -0.012 0.046 *
Algeria -0.201 * 0.045 **
Ecuador -0.084 * 0.047 *
Arab Rep Egypt -0.066 * 0.054 *
Fiji 0.282 * 0.062 **
Gabon 0.066 ** 0.075 *
Ghana -0.015 0.026 **
The Gambia 0.347 * 0.045
Guatemala -0.027 0.034 *
Honduras 0.065 * 0.041 *
Indonesia -0.094 * 0.048 *
Jamaica 0.097 * 0.046 **
Jordan 0.144 * 0.046 *
Kenya 0.089 * 0.031 **
Rep. Korea -0.152 * 0.001
Sri Lanka 0.056 * 0.026
Lesotho -0.203 * -0.032
Madagascar 0.031 0.015 **
Mexico -0.131 * 0.050
Mauritius 0.213 * 0.031
Malaysia 0.220 * 0.091 *
Niger 0.044 0.021
Nigeria -0.005 0.076 *
Nicaragua 0.061 * 0.041 **
Pakistan -0.089 * 0.028 *
Peru -0.208 * 0.047
Philippines -0.028 0.047 *
Papua New Guinea 0.155 * 0.074
Paraguay 0.044 * 0.045 *
Senegal 0.120 * 0.035 *
El Salvador -0.105 * 0.011
Swaziland 0.364 * 0.078
Thailand -0.049 ** 0.035 *
Togo 0.233 * 0.047
Trinidad and Tobago -0.082 * 0.072 *
Tunisia 0.077 * 0.063 *
Turkey -0.252 * 0.001
Venezuela, RB -0.142 * 0.034
Zimbabwe 0.016 0.033
Note: The numbers in parentheses are the computed t-values. The
statistics significant at 5 percent and 10 percent levels are
indicated by * and ** respectively.