Wheat markets and price stabilisation in Pakistan: an analysis of policy options.
Dorosh, Paul ; Salam, Abdul
This article provides a quantitative analysis of the effects of
Pakistan government domestic wheat procurement, sales, and trade
policies on wheat supply, demand, prices, and overall inflation.
Analysis of price multipliers indicates that increases in wheat
procurement prices (one means of promoting domestic procurement) have
relatively small effects on the overall consumer price index. Partial
equilibrium analysis of wheat markets suggests that fluctuations in
production, rather than market manipulation, are plausible explanations
for price increases in recent years. Comparisons of domestic and
international prices suggest that promoting private sector imports is
one alternative for increasing supply and stabilising market prices,
particularly in years of production shortfalls. Overall, this paper
concludes that market forces play a dominant role in price determination
in Pakistan, and that policies that promote the private sector wheat
trade can both increase price stability and reduce fiscal costs.
JEL classification: Q11, Q18
Keywords: Food Policy, Food Price Stabilisation, Agricultural
Policy, Food Price Inflation
I. INTRODUCTION
Wheat plays a central role in Pakistan's food economy, both in
terms of production and consumption. Because of the importance of wheat,
successive governments of Pakistan since Independence have intervened
heavily in wheat markets, procuring wheat at administratively set prices
to support farmer incomes and subsidising wheat sales to flour mills or
directly to consumers with the objective of stabilising prices at levels
affordable to consumers [Cornelisse and Naqvi (1987); Hamid, Nabi, and
Nasim (1990); Dorosh and Valdes (1990); Ashfaq, Griffith, and Parton (2001); Ahmad, et al. (2005)].
Significant steps were taken toward liberalisation of wheat markets
from the late 1980s to 2000. However, after consecutive relatively poor
wheat harvests from 2002 to 2004 led to high market prices for wheat,
the federal government, as well as the government of Punjab, took
several policy measures designed to increase supplies, add to government
stocks and stabilise prices. These policies included subsidised sales of
government imports and the imposition of restrictions on transport of
wheat. Wheat policy again shifted in 2005, as procurement prices were
raised, restrictions on transport of grain were removed, and private
imports encouraged.
These policy measures related to domestic procurement quantities
and prices, private and government imports, and sales prices have had a
major impact on wheat markets, prices and government subsidies in
Pakistan. Moreover, because of the importance of wheat as a wage good
and perhaps as a signal of government policy, increases in the wheat
procurement price are seen as a major factor in determining the overall
level of price inflation in the country.
The purpose of this article is to provide a quantitative analysis
of the effects of these policies on wheat supply, demand, prices and
overall inflation, drawing out implications for government policy to
address wheat price stabilisation issues in both the short and long run.
We first present a brief summary of the wheat economy in Pakistan and
the political economy of wheat policy. Section 3 contains an analysis of
the impacts of wheat procurement and the procurement price on the wheat
market and overall price levels. Thereafter follows a brief analysis of
current (2005) wheat production and prices. The final section includes
concluding observations and policy implications.
II. OVERVIEW OF THE WHEAT ECONOMY OF PAKISTAN
Annual wheat production in Pakistan from 2002 through 2004 averaged
19.0 mn tons, about 80 percent of which was produced in Punjab. Over
this period, current production accounted for about 90 percent of total
supply, with the remainder coming from imports and drawdown of
government stocks.
Provincial governments, particularly the government of Punjab,
intervene heavily in wheat markets. Government procurement averaged 4.0
million tons per year in 2002 and 2003, about 25 percent of production
in these years. Punjab alone accounted for almost 90 percent of
procurement, equivalent to 27 percent of its production.
Pakistan Agricultural Prices Commission (APCOM) surveys [Salam, et
al. (2002)] in major wheat surplus districts in Sindh in 1997 and in
Punjab in 1998 indicate that 42 percent (Sindh) and 55 percent (Punjab)
of wheat production sold within four months of harvest and that overall
about 62 percent of production is sold. (1) Farms larger than 25 acres
accounted for an estimated 81 percent of wheat sales in Sindh and 67
percent of wheat sales in Punjab (Table 1). With 20 percent of wheat
production used as payments for harvesting and threshing, these figures
imply that only 18 percent of wheat production is retained for
own-consumption in these surplus districts. Using the same percentages
for wheat sales/production, total wheat sales (and rents-in-kind) are
estimated at 15.6 mn tons for the period 2001-02 to 2003-04. Government
purchases (domestic procurement) of 3.6 mn tons would then be equal to
19 percent of total market purchases/sales (Table 2).
Nationally, however, perhaps as high as 30 percent of wheat
production is retained for own-consumption. Using this figure, total
wheat sales in Pakistan would be about 13.4 mn tons, and procurement of
3.6 mn tons would be equal to 27 percent of the market. Similar
calculations for the share of government sales of wheat to total
availability suggest that government sales account for 31 to 38 percent
of total purchases. Given that government releases (sales to flour
mills) occur mainly from October through April (the onset of the wheat
harvest), and that household purchases are likely to be concentrated in
these months, these rough estimates suggest that government wheat has
accounted for 80 percent or more of wheat purchases in the last six
months of these years (2001-02 to 2003-04).
Pakistan Integrated Household Survey (PIHS) 2001-02 data also
indicate that wheat sales are highly concentrated. The top 10 percent of
wheat farmers in terms of sales account for 47 percent of total wheat
sales; the top 20 percent of wheat farmers in terms of sales (only 5
percent of Pakistan's households) account for 67 percent of total
wheat sales. Overall, only 20 percent of Pakistan's households have
a surplus of wheat production over home consumption, and 23 percent of
wheat farmers are net wheat purchasers. (2) Thus, policies that support
high producer prices directly benefit only the relatively small
percentage of wheat farmers with wheat surpluses.
According to the 2001 FAO Food Balance Sheet for Pakistan,
consumption of wheat provided 1042 calories/person/day, 42 percent of
total caloric consumption (2457 calories/person/day). HIES 2001-02 data
show a slightly higher absolute figure (1052 calories/person/day), but a
much higher caloric share (58 percent of 1819 calories/person/day).
Rural consumption per capita (10.3 kgs/person/month) is 42 percent
higher than urban consumption per capita (7.24 kgs/person/month).
Overall, there is little difference between quantities consumed across
expenditure quintiles in urban areas, though wheat consumption rises
with total expenditures for rural households (Figure 1). Budget shares
of wheat are high for both urban and rural poor households: 12.9 percent
for the poorest urban quintile and 15.8 percent for the poorest rural
quintile.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Per capita net availability has declined in recent years, because
of sub-par harvests that were not completely offset by increased
government imports and draw down of stocks. From 1990-91 to 2001-02, per
capita wheat consumption averaged 131 kgs/person/year. For the three
year period, 2002-03--2004-05, however, per capita wheat availability
(consumption) fell by 14 percent to 113 kgs/year. As a result of the
reduced availability, real prices of wheat and wheat flour rose by 21
and 19 percent, respectively, from 2001-02 to 2004-05 [Pakistan (2005);
Figure 2].
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Government Wheat Policy
Government wheat policy in Pakistan attempts to balance competing
interests of producers and consumers. On the production side, policy is
aimed at increasing wheat productivity (yields) and output, as well as
supporting farmer incomes. Increased wheat production has also been seen
as part of an overall national food security strategy of reducing
dependence on food imports. On the consumption side, the government has
attempted to enhance household food security, particularly through
ensuring availability of wheat flour at affordable prices and
maintaining price stability. Food policy options are constrained,
however, by overall fiscal constraints, as well as a desire to minimise
fiscal subsidies on food. Moreover, the wheat procurement price has been
seen as a major determinant of overall inflation because of its role as
a wage good and an indicator of overall government price policy [Khan and Qasim (1996)]. Thus, wheat policy is to some degree constrained by
inflation targets and inflation policy.
To achieve these objectives, the federal and provincial governments
have employed various instruments, including setting of procurement and
release prices, domestic procurement and sales, government imports,
maintenance of security stocks and at times, promotion of private sector
international trade. Domestic procurement quantities and prices are the
major instruments for spurring domestic production and improving wheat
farmers' incomes. The national procurement price and procurement
quantity targets are set at the federal level, in consultation with
provincial governments, though the implementation of procurement policy
is the responsibility of provincial governments and PASSCO (Pakistan
Agricultural Storage and Supplies Corporation). Likewise, sales of
government wheat, almost exclusively to flour mills on a quota basis are
largely the responsibility of provincial governments.
Provincial governments have generally set procurement targets aimed
at securing enough grain for planned distribution and stock build-up.
Lack of consistency between procurement prices, procurement quantity
targets and market conditions has at times led government to impose
severe restrictions on markets instead of adjusting either procurement
levels or procurement prices, however. (3) Restrictions on the transport
of wheat were widely used until the mid-1990s to help insure that
district officials of the provincial Departments of Food were able to
meet their procurement targets. Marketing of wheat was subsequently
liberalised, but in 2004 the Punjab government re-imposed restrictions
on transport of wheat in an effort to meet procurement targets and then
removed once again in 2005. Imports of wheat, undertaken by the federal
government, have been used to supplement provincial food stocks and
enable sufficient wheat sales to keep domestic price levels from rising
too high. The government (and private sector contractors) also exported
wheat in the 2000-01 through 2003-04 May-April marketing years following
record levels of procurement in 2000.
There are major fiscal subsidies and economic rents involved in the
sales of wheat to flour mills at below-market rates. Wheat issue prices
(the price of wheat sales to flour mills) do not cover the full cost of
procurement (domestic or imported), storage and handling. Provincial
food subsidies in 2002-03 reached Rs 6.8 bn. This subsidy was 12 percent
greater than total Public Sector Development Programme budget for the
Health Division in 2004-05 (Rs 6.05 bn). Subsidies on sales of imported
wheat accounted for another Rs 1.2 bn in that year [World Bank (2007)].
These rents appear to accrue mainly to wheat millers who receive
government wheat and perhaps to those involved in these transfers.
Although there may be a stipulated sales price of flour, there is no
effective enforcement mechanism. Since wheat flour produced from
government wheat is not distinguishable from wheat flour produced from
market wheat, their prices are the same. Profits from sales of wheat
milled using government wheat are thus substantial, and there are many
wheat mills that operate only in the November-April period and mill only
government-supplied wheat.
Various groups of stakeholders are affected by and often attempt to
influence these policies. Farmers, particularly those with net sales,
benefit from increases in procurement prices and quantities. Flour
millers gain from low issue (sales) prices of wheat that are typically
below open market prices. Low market prices for wheat and wheat flour
benefit net consumers, who account for about 80 percent of
Pakistan's population. Provincial food departments make great
efforts to achieve domestic procurement targets which provide most of
the grain for subsequent distribution. Large-scale procurement creates
and subsidised sales also create the possibility of substantial economic
rents. Sales of grain (at the issue price) from the surplus provinces
(typically Punjab) to other provincial food departments involve an
implicit cross-subsidisation to the receiving provinces since issue
prices do not cover the full costs of procurement, storage and
distribution. The provincial and federal governments are also concerned
with minimising fiscal subsidies and overall inflation. Finally, donors
have generally pushed for reductions in food subsidies and an increased
role of the private sector in wheat marketing.
Wheat policies have varied over time, however (Table 3).
Substantial wheat market liberalisation took place in the late 1980s
with the abolition of wheat ration shops and liberalisation of private
wheat imports (which were subsequently disallowed). Throughout the
1990s, Pakistan was a net importer of wheat, with domestic production
typically accounting for about 90 percent of availability. A bumper
wheat harvest in early 2000 (i.e. the 1999-2000 crop year) led to a
record procurement of 8.6 million tons and a large increase in stocks,
some of which were subsequently exported (with an export subsidy).
However, as noted above, crop shortfalls from 2001-02 through 2003-04,
rising market prices, problems with government import tenders in early
2004, and low quantities of domestic procurement led the Punjab
provincial government to place restrictions on transport of wheat across
district and provincial boundaries in 2004. Procurement prices were
raised sharply for the 2003-04 and 2004-05 wheat crops in an effort to
spur procurement, but these price increases have raised concerns about
their effects on overall inflation.
III. IMPACTS OF GOVERNMENT WHEAT POLICIES
Determination of Domestic Wheat Prices
In an importing country with free trade, domestic price levels
would be determined by the international price adjusted for tariffs,
transport and marketing costs (the import parity price). Throughout most
of the 1990s, Pakistan's domestic wheat prices were below import
parity price levels, however, in large part because subsidised sales of
government commercial imports added to domestic supplies and reduced
market prices (4) In the wake of a bumper wheat harvest in 2000,
domestic wholesale prices in Karachi and Lahore remained below their
respective import parity levels (Figure 3), although in the 2000-01 and
2001-02 crop marketing years (May-April) Pakistan was essentially
self-sufficient in wheat, drawing on the stock build-up from the 2000
harvest. Note that there was also no incentive for trade from India
during this period, even if this trade had been legal (Figure 4).
With the relatively poor harvests in 2004 and 2005, however,
domestic prices have risen substantially and since mid-2004 wholesale
prices in Karachi have essentially been at import parity levels.
Wholesale prices in Lahore remained at about 18 percent above import
parity levels in 2004-05. (5) The implication is that if private trade
were permitted with no tariffs, private sector imports would likely
supply the Karachi market, adding to domestic availability of wheat at
no cost to the government.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Impacts of Domestic Procurement on Market Prices
Given that government policies have limited private imports and
kept domestic prices below import parity in most recent years, changes
in quantities purchased or sold by the government in domestic markets,
and the prices at which the government buys and sells have the potential
to affect domestic market prices. In particular, the effect of the
volume and price of domestic procurement on market prices of wheat
depends crucially on whether the government buys less than the amount of
wheat that farmers and traders are willing to sell (i.e. whether
procurement is infra-marginal) (6) and the volume of subsequent
distribution of wheat (i.e. the net procurement or distribution). (7)
Ratios of market prices to procurement prices during the May-August
procurement season suggest that in several years (from 2000-01 to
2003-04), the procurement price did not have a direct effect on the
market price. From 1990-91 to 1998-99, the average ratio of the Lahore
wholesale price to the procurement price during the procurement season
was 1.085, reflecting marketing costs from villages with procurement
centres to the Lahore wholesale market. In some of these years,
procurement targets were raised during the procurement season so as to
enable government to buy all grain offered for sale. However, during the
four-year period, 1999-2000 to 2002-03, this price ratio fell to 0.974
(a 10 percent decline), evidence that procurement during these years was
less than the amount offered for sale at the government procurement
price, (i.e. that procurement was infra-marginal). The implication is
that in these years the procurement price was generally higher than
market prices, and that quantity of procurement was exogenously
determined (i.e. determined by government policy). Thus, the procurement
price did not have a direct effect on market prices in these years.
Rather, the procurement quantity determined the market price effects. In
2003-04, however, a year when procurement quantities fell short of
targets, the price ratio rose again to 1.100, evidence from market
prices that the government purchased all grain offered for sale at the
procurement price.
In order for the procurement price to directly determine the market
price, the government must purchase all wheat offered at that price. (8)
Moreover, in terms of the average annual price, and ignoring regional or
intra-annual price variations, what is important is annual net
procurement, i.e. the difference between the volume of procurement in
the immediate post harvest period and gross sales that take place mainly
at the end of the crop year. (9) In this case, the price effect of net
procurement is determined in the short-run only by net supply
(production plus net procurement/sales--private imports are assumed to
be zero) and the price-responsiveness of consumer demand (the own-price
elasticity of wheat demand, defined as the percentage change in wheat
demand given a one percent change in wheat prices). (10)
For example, increasing net procurement by 0.5 million tons in
2004-05 would have reduced availability by 3 percent and raised market
prices by an estimated 6 to 10 percent. These calculations also suggest
that in order to achieve this additional volume of procurement without
coercing traders or placing movement restrictions on grain, the
procurement price would need to be 6-10 percent higher than originally
set.
Impacts of Domestic Procurement on Inflation: Price Multiplier
Analysis
Assuming that government procurement and trade policies are
effective in raising the procurement and market price of wheat, there
remains the question as to the overall effect of the procurement price
on inflation. One approach to address this question is a
price-multiplier model that assumes that all increases in costs and
prices are passed on to purchasers, i.e. that quantities demanded and
supplied are fixed, and that the overall price level is determined by a
cost-push mechanism. (11)
For example, given a wheat flour budget share of 8.9 percent, a
13.8 percent increase in the price of wheat flour (equal to the April
2004 to April 2005 actual price increase) results in an estimated 1.23
percent increase in urban poor CPI without multiplier effects (equal to
the budget share times the percent increase in price). Using the fixed
input-output production coefficients derived from a 2001-02 Social
Accounting Matrix for Pakistan [Dorosh, Niazi, and Nazli (2003)], the
urban poor CPI rises by 1.27 percent, only a slight increase since wheat
flour is not a major input into other sectors (Table 5). Assuming that
incomes (wages and returns to capital) and household spending also
increase to leave levels of employment and quantities of consumption
unchanged, multiplier effects are increased. Under these full multiplier
assumptions, the wheat flour price increase leads to a 3.0 percent
increase in the CPI of the urban poor. By comparison, under the same
assumptions, the 17.7 percent increase in fuel prices in 2004-05 leads
to a 3.7 percent increase in the CPI of the urban poor.
These estimates of inflation effects are an upper-bound estimate of
the impacts of procurement price on other domestic prices (apart from
possible monetary policy effects) since the analysis assumes that the
market price is equal to the procurement price and the demand for all
goods and services in the economy is exogenously determined.
Impacts of Domestic Procurement on Inflation: Econometric Analysis
Econometric analysis by Khan and Qasim (1996) using annual data
from 1971-72 to 1994-95 found that a 10 percent increase in the wheat
procurement price would increase the food price index by 7.4 percent.
Assuming the same relationship held in 2004, the 16.7 percent increase
in the wheat procurement price in 2003-04 would increase the food price
index by 12.3 percent.
This econometrically estimated effect of wheat prices on inflation
is roughly 4 times the magnitude suggested by the price-multiplier,
which itself overstates price transmission due assumptions of exogenous demand. Arguably, the econometric analysis captures mechanisms other
than simply passing on of costs or adjustments to current prices. This
analysis may also capture formulation of price expectations by various
actors in the economy, perhaps because these actors interpret the wheat
procurement price as a signal of overall government policy. The short
annual time series data available, periodic changes in wheat policy,
gradual changes in the structure of the economy over time, and the
influence of other factors make it difficult to produce definitive
econometric estimates or conclusive interpretations of the results,
however.
Implications of Production Shortfalls: Wheat Market Prices in 2005
Preliminary estimates in early 2005 suggested a record wheat crop,
but market prices remained high even after the produce started arriving
in the market and continued to rise through early June. This rise in
market prices was most likely not due to manipulation of the market by
private traders, but due to lower than expected production caused by
damage from rains and high winds leading to poor grain filling and
lodging of wheat. Even a small reduction in the wheat crop would have a
major effect on market prices. Crop losses of just 5 percent in Punjab
could lead to 8-14 percent increase in prices relative to expected
prices with no production losses (Table 6). (12)
Private traders are unlikely to have significant ability to
manipulate market prices given the large size of the wheat market. For
example, the estimated value of wheat consumption in Lahore is about 19
crore Rs ($3.0 mn)/week and Karachi about 28 crore Rs ($4.5 mn)/week.
(13) Given the large number of traders involved and relatively free
movement of grain and flour into these cities, it would be extremely
difficult and financially risky for a small group of traders to restrict
market flows and store large enough quantities to affect market prices.
IV. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The analysis presented in this paper suggests that market forces
are major determinants of wheat prices in Pakistan and that government
wheat policies involving domestic procurement and government sales in
most years have been infra-marginal, involving substantial rents,
particularly on sales. Moreover, analysis of price multipliers using a
recently developed Social Accounting Matrix for Pakistan indicates
little evidence of major effects on overall price levels and inflation
of increases in the procurement price, even under the assumption that
the procurement price actually directly determines the market price.
Thus, setting the procurement prices at levels near expected open market
price levels is not likely to significantly add to overall inflation.
In recent years of production shortfalls, (particularly 2004),
movement restrictions in Punjab province have been only partially
effective in achieving procurement targets. The partial equilibrium
analysis of price movements presented above, suggest that the production
shortfalls, rather than uncompetitive market behaviour and hoarding are
the major reason for price increases. Moreover, these movement
restrictions may inhibit market development in medium run, by
discouraging investments in storage.
Instead of movement restrictions and forced procurement,, sales of
government imports could add to market supplies and limit the rise in
market prices in years of apparent production shortfalls. In 2004-05,
government imports were 1.4 million tons. Increasing the volume of
imports and sales to 2.4 million tons for 2005-06 would reduce market
prices by an estimated 10-16 percent relative to prices with only 1.4
million tons of imports (Table 6).
In order to promote efficiently functioning markets, it is
important that any government imports and sales be transparent, with
planned volumes of import announced in advance. A policy of reducing
market prices through sales of additional imports is not necessarily
costless, however. If imports with an estimated import parity cost of
13.3 Rs/kg in Lahore were sold in the wholesale market price there, the
estimated subsidy would be Rs 4-6 billion (Rs 400-600 crore). If the
issue price for this wheat was lower than the market price, the subsidy
would rise accordingly.
One alternative to government imports in years of high domestic
prices and moderate international price levels is to allow private
sector imports of wheat with little or no tariff, a policy which was
actually adopted in mid-2005. With domestic prices in Karachi in already
near import parity, there was an opportunity for private trade to add to
domestic supplies. After private imports were liberalised, private
sector imports began to flow into the country in mid-2005, stabilising
wheat markets at no cost to government.
Other policy reforms could also enable provincial governments to
reduce their wheat subsidies substantially and still maintain the
ability to address short-term market shortfalls. Retaining a separate
security stock, but reducing domestic procurement and sales volumes,
would substantially reduce costs, For example, a year-end security stock
of about 1.0 million tons (the average in recent years in Punjab
province), could be maintained with far less procurement and sales
volumes (typically about 3 million tons of wheat). Similarly, setting
the sales price to flour mills at levels that cover full costs would
also reduce subsidy. It would also encourage investment in wheat
marketing and storage.
Given the complexity of wheat markets and wheat policy in Pakistan,
further analysis is warranted, particularly since wheat markets are
constantly changing due to changes in annual production, income shocks
to households and changes in international markets. Nonetheless, the
analysis presented in this paper suggests that market forces play a
dominant role in price determination in Pakistan and that policies that
promote the private sector wheat trade can both increase price stability
and reduce fiscal costs.
Annex 1
Methodology for the SAM-based Price Multiplier Analysis
The Social Accounting Matrix (SAM)-based price multiplier analysis
presented in this paper is based on the methodology of Roland-Holdst and
Tarp (2005) and the 200102 Pakistan SAM [Dorosh, Niazi, and Nazli
(2004)]. This original SAM included 117 accounts (34 activities, 33
commodities, 27 factors of production, 19 household groups, enterprises,
government, rest of world and capital). For the cost-price analysis, the
SAM was aggregated to 22 accounts, including 11 activities/commodities
(wheat, paddy, cotton, other agriculture, wheat flour, rice, yarn,
textiles, petroleum, other industry and services), 3 factors of
production (land, labour and capital), enterprises, government, rest of
world and capital. (14)
In the multiplier analysis, following Roland-Holdst and Tarp
(2005), we consider production activities, factor incomes and household
incomes to be endogenous, with exogenous levels of spending by
enterprises, government, rest of world (exports) and capital
(investment). The methodology used is similar to that of standard
semi-input output (SIO) quantity multiplier used to measure the growth
linkages generated from an exogenous increase in production of a given
sector or an exogenous increase in demand [Haggblade, Hammer, and Hazell
(1991)]. Instead of considering the effect of a policy shock on
quantities with prices exogenous, however, we consider the effect of a
policy shock (in this case, an exogenous increase in the price of wheat)
on other prices with all quantities exogenous.
Splitting the SAM into four groups (activities, factors, households
and other), we define four sub-matrices [A.sub.ij] and [X.sub.ij] where
each element of sub-matrix [A.sub.ij] is defined as the corresponding
element of the SAM [X.sub.ij] divided by the column j total, (see Annex
Table 1).
Annex Table 1
Structure of the Pakistan SAM
Activities Factors Households Exogenous
Activities X11 0 X13 X14
Factors X21 0 0 0
Households 0 X32 X33 X34
Exogenous X41 X42 X43 X44
Defining P as the price vector of endogenous accounts (with
[p.sub.1] as the price vector for activities, [p.sub.2] as the price
vector for factor accounts, [p.sub.3] as the price vector for household
accounts) and [[tau].sub.4 ]as the price vector for exogenous accounts
gives the following equations as determined by the accounting identities
from the columns of the SAM: (15)
[p.sub.1] = [p.sub.1][A.sub.11] + [p.sub.2][A.sub.21] +
[[pi].sub.4][A.sub.41]
[p.sub.2] = [p.sub.3][A.sub.32] + [[pi].sub.4][A.sub.42]
[p.sub.3] = [p.sub.1][A.sub.13] + [p.sub.3][A.sub.33] +
[[pi].sub.4][A.sub.43]
Re-defining the matrix A as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and
v = [[pi].sub.4]A(4)
where A(4) is the sub-matrix of the original A matrix composed by
adjoining the columns of A41, A42 and A43, gives:
p = p A + v = v[(I-A).sup.-1] = v M
where v is the vector of exogenous costs (taxes, import costs).
Row j of M can then be interpreted as the effects on prices
resulting from a unit increase in costs of sector j. For the wheat price
analysis in this paper, we examine the effects of exogenous increases in
the prices of wheat and wheat flour separately, by utilising the
elements of their respective rows in matrix M.
REFERENCES
Ahmad, Munir (2003) Agricultural Product Markets in Pakistan.
Background Paper for World Bank Pakistan Rural Factor Markets Study.
(Processed).
Ahmad, Munir, Abdul Qayyum, Muhammad Iqbal, et al. (2005) Impact of
Domestic Policies Towards Agricultural Trade Liberalisation and Market
Reform on Food Security in Pakistan. (Processed).
Ashfaq, M., G. Griffith, and K. Parton (2001) Welfare Effects of
Government Interventions in the Wheat Economy of Pakistan. Pakistan
Journal of Agricultural Economics 4:1.
Cornelisse, Peter A. and Syed Nawab Haider Naqvi (1987) The Wheat
Marketing Activity in Pakistan. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics and Centre for Development Planning, Erasmus
University, Rotterdam.
Dorosh, Paul A. (2001) Trade Liberalisation and National Food
Security: Rice Trade between Bangladesh and India. World Development
29:4, 673-689.
Dorosh, Paul A., Muhammad Khan Niazi, and Hina Nazli (2003)
Distributional Impacts of Agricultural Growth in Pakistan: A Multiplier
Analysis. The Pakistan Development Review 42:3, 249-275.
Dorosh, Paul and Alberto Valdes (1990) Effects of Exchange Rate and
Trade Policies on Agriculture in Pakistan. Washington, DC: IFPRI.
(International Food Policy Research Institute Research Report No. 84.)
Food and Agriculture Organisation (FAO). Food Balance Sheets.
www.fao.org.
Haggblade, Steven, Jeffrey Hammer, and Peter Hazell (1991)
Modelling Agricultural Growth Multipliers. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 73:2, 361-374.
Hamid, Naved, Ijaz Nabi, and Anjum Nasim (1990) Trade, Exchange
Rate, and Agricultural Pricing Policies in Pakistan. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
India, Government of (Various Issues). Reports of the Commission
for Agricultural Costs and Prices. Department of Agriculture and
Co-operation, Ministry of Agriculture, New Delhi.
International Monetary Fund (2007) International Financial
Statistics. Washington, DC.
Khan, Ashfaque H., and Mohammad Ali Qasim (1996) Inflation in
Pakistan Revisited. The Pakistan Development Review 35:4, 747-759.
Pakistan, Government of (2002) Household Income and Expenditure
Survey (HIES) 2001-02. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pakistan, Government of (2002a) Pakistan Integrated Household
Survey (PIHS), 200102. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pakistan, Government of (2005) Pakistan Economic Survey, 2004-05.
Islamabad: Finance Division, Economic Adviser's Wing.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Agricultural Statistics of
Pakistan. Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Livestock.
Roland-Hoist, David, and Finn Tarp (2005) Globalisation, Economic
Reform, and Structural Price Transmission: SAM Decomposition Techniques
with an Empirical Application to Vietnam. In de Janvry Alain and Ravi
Kanbur (eds.) Poverty, Inequality and Development. Essays in Honour of
Erik Thorbecke. Amsterdam: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Salam, Abdul, M. B. Siddiqui, and Syed Wasim Raza Zaidi (2002)
Economics of Wheat Production: Results from Field Surveys in Punjab and
Sindh. Agricultural Prices Commission. Islamabad: Government of
Pakistan. (APCOM Series No. 202.)
World Bank (2004) Pakistan Rural Factor Markets: Policy Reforms for
Growth and Equity. Washington, DC: World Bank. (Report No. 30381-PK.)
World Bank (2007) Pakistan: Promoting Rural Growth and Poverty
Reduction. Washington, DC: World Bank. (Report No. 39303-PK.)
(1) This calculation uses the 1999-2000 to 2001-02 production
weights for Punjab and Sindh provinces (80/12).
(2) Net purchases are calculated on the basis of household
production and an assumed per capita consumption of 140 kgs/person/year.
(3) In general, it is not possible to independently set both the
procurement price and the procurement quantity target if the government
neither refuses to buy nor forces producers to sell at the procurement
price. When procurement prices are set too high (relative to current
levels of production and market demand), the amount of wheat offered for
sale to the government exceeds the procurement target. When procurement
prices are set too low, the amount of wheat offered for sale falls short
of the procurement target.
(4) See Ahmad (2003) and World Bank (2004).
(5) Note that the import parity price for Lahore is higher than
that for Karachi (approximately 13.2 and I 1.9 Rs/kg, respectively in
2004-05), due to additional transport costs from Karachi port to Lahore
for imported wheat. Import parity prices are authors' calculations
as described in the notes to Figure 4.
(6) In this case, market prices will remain above the procurement
price and will be set by the marginal supply and demand of wheat.
(7) Seasonal movements are complex and depend on private market
price expectations, private storage behaviour and other factors,
including the volume and timing of procurement and sales. This article
does not cover these issues, though it is important to note that a
government sales price that does not cover the cost of storage from the
time of procurement to the time of sales will discourage private storage
of grain.
(8) This assumes that the procurement price is high enough so that
at least some government (unforced) purchases take place. Otherwise, the
government must raise its procurement price to levels at which it
actually purchases wheat in order to affect the market price.
(9) To illustrate this, consider the case of the government buying
and selling the same amount of wheat. Again abstracting from regional
and intra-annual considerations, with no change in net supply in the
market, the average market price is unchanged.
(10) The time period for this analysis is from just after the wheat
harvest until the next wheat harvest; thus, production is fixed
(exogenous). Net government sales are taken as exogenous. For a fuller
description of a similar model, see Dorosh (2001).
(11) This model is the dual of quantity multiplier model used in
growth linkage analysis. See RolandHolst and Tarp (2004). See Annex 1
for details of the model specification.
(12) The partial equilibrium model simulations in Table 5 assume
exogenous levels of production, total imports and world prices (an
import parity wholesale price of wheat in Lahore of Rs 13.30/kg, based
on a CIF price of wheat in Karachi of $186/ton). The market-clearing
real domestic wheat prices is estimated using a wheat demand function
based on 2004-05 base year levels of per capita wheat demand, an assumed
5 percent growth in real per capita incomes from 2004-05 to 2005-06, and
an income elasticity of wheat demand of 0.2. See Dorosh (2001) for
details of a similar model.
(13) The calculations for Lahore are as follows: 10 million people
x 90 kgs/person/year = 0.90 mn tons/year or 75,000 tons/month (about
19,000 tons/week) with a value of about 190 mn rupees per week at 10
Rs/kg. For Karachi, a population of 15 million is assumed.
(14) In the aggregated SAM, imports (shown in the intersection of
the Rest of World row and the commodity columns were re-classified as
negative exports (shown in the intersection of the
activities/commodities rows and the Rest of World column).
(15) Note that since there are no direct payments from the activity
account columns to households, the matrix A31 is a zero matrix;
similarly, the matrices AI2, A22, and A23 are also zero matrices.
Paul Dorosh <
[email protected]> is Senior Economist,
Spatial and Local Development Unit, Sustainable Development Network,
World Bank, Washington, DC. Abdul Salam <
[email protected]>,
former Chairman, Pakistan Agricultural Prices Commission, Islamabad, is
currently Professor of Economics, Federal Urdu University of Arts,
Science and Technology, Islamabad.
Authors' Note: We wish to thank Sohail Malik, David Orden, and
two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments on this paper. We also
thank Hina Nazli, who assisted with various tables and statistical
calculations. Any errors and omissions are the responsibility of the
authors. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and
do not necessarily represent the views of their respective institutions.
Table 1
Production and Sales by Farm Size, Sindh 1996-97 and Punjab 1997-98
% Sold
(w/in 4 % Sold % Sales
Production Months) (Est. Total) (Est. Total)
Sindh: 1996-97
< 12,5 Acres 4.2 55% 55%
12 to 25 Acres 9.4 50% 63%
25 to 50 Acres 15.6 49% 67%
50+ Acres 47.0 37% 68%
Total 16.8 42% 66%
Punjab: 1997-98
< 12,5 Acres 3.9 42% 42%
12 to 25 Acres 10.7 49% 60%
25 to 50 Acres 20.2 59% 65%
50+ Acres 53.0 61% 68%
Total 12.3 55% 61%
Total Sindh 12.9 53% 62%
and Punjab
% In-kind (Tons/
Production (Est. Total) Farm)
Sindh: 1996-97
< 12,5 Acres 8% 17.7%
12 to 25 Acres 11% 17.1%
25 to 50 Acres 16% 16.7%
50+ Acres 65% 19.4%
Total 100% 18.6%
Punjab: 1997-98
< 12,5 Acres 11% 23.5%
12 to 25 Acres 22% 20.9%
25 to 50 Acres 23% 19.8%
50+ Acres 44% 20.1%
Total 100% 20.8%
Total Sindh 100% 20%
and Punjab
Source: Calculated using APCOM survey data from Salam, et al. (2002).
Note: Years indicated are May-April crop marketing years.
Table 2
Pakistan: Estimates of Size of Wheat Market (2002-03 to
2004105)
2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 Average
Estimate 1: APCOM Survey
Production 18.2 19.2 19.5 19.0
Sales (62% of Production) 11.3 11.9 12.1 11.8
Rents (In-kind; 20% 3.6 3.8 3.9 3.8
of Production)
Subtotal Sales, Rents 14.9 15.7 16.0 15.6
Own Consumption 3.3 3.5 3.5 3.4
Govt. Procurement 4.0 3.5 3.4 3.6
Govt. Releases 3.4 5.1 4.1 4.2
Availability 19.1 15.8 16.7 17.2
Total Purchases 15.9 12.4 13.2 13.8
Govt. Proc/Production 22.2% 18.3% 17.3% 19.2%
Govt. Proc/Total 27.1% 22.3% 21.1% 23.4%
Sales, Rents
Govt. Sales/Total 21.3% 41.5% 31.0% 30.4%
Purchases
Govt. Sales/Total 17.6% 32.4% 24.5% 24.4%
Consumption
Estimate 2: (Sales: 50%
of Production)
Subtotal Sales and Rent 12.8 13.4 13.6 13.3
Govt. Proc/Total 31.7% 26.2% 24.7% 27.4%
Sales, Rents
Govt. Sales/Total 24.7% 51.0% 37.7% 36.4%
Purchases
Govt. Sales/Total 17.6% 32.4% 24.5% 24.4%
Consumption
Notes: Estimate 1 uses shares of the 1997 and 1998 APCOM surveys of
wheat farmers.
These calculations assume that all in-kind payments for harvesting
and threshing are re-sold. Years shown are May-April crop marketing
years.
Table 3
Chronology of Major Events in Pakistan Wheat Policy and Markets
* Independence to early 1980s: substantial government market
intervention: ration shops with fixed prices, but substantial
leakages and malpractices
* November 1987: abolition of wheat ration shops
* Late 1980s: broad trade liberalisation; private sector wheat
imports allowed in late 80s, but subsequently disallowed
* Bumper harvest in 1999-00 (i.e. March-April 2000)
** 8.6 million tons procurement; large increase in stocks
** Subsequent subsidised exports of stocks, including private
sector exports
** Incentives for private investment in storage
** Public investments in laboratories for grain testing
* Crop shortfalls in 2001-02, 2002-03 and 2003-04
* Government policy response to shortfalls: 2004
** Restrictions on inter-provincial transport of wheat (and
inter-district transport of wheat in Punjab)
** Government tenders for imports (but some shipments rejected on
quality basis in early 2004)
** Increased procurement price for 2004-05 crop (to 400 Rs/40 kg)
* Production recovery and market liberalisation: 2005
** Good harvest 2004-05 (21.1 million tons)
** Lifting of restrictions on transport of wheat
** Encouragement of private sector commercial wheat imports
Table 4
Support, Market and Issue Prices for Wheat, 1990-91 to 2006-07
Nominal Prices of Wheat (Rs/40 kg)
Year Support Price Market Price Issue Price
1990-91 112 121 104
1991-92 124 134 124
1992-93 130 139 136
1993-94 160 170 142
1994-95 160 176 175
1995-96 173 185 175
1996-97 240 273 194
1997-98 240 259 260
1998-99 240 261 260
1999-00 300 297 320
2000-01 300 275 320
2001-02 300 292 337
2002-03 300 305 337
2003-04 350 385 350
2004-05 400 425 389
2005-06 415 418 425
Market Price /
Year Support Price
1990-91 1.080
1991-92 1.081
1992-93 1.069
1993-94 1.063
1994-95 1.100
1995-96 1.069
1996-97 1.138
1997-98 1.079
1998-99 1.088
1999-00 0.990
2000-01 0.917
2001-02 0.973
2002-03 1.017
2003-04 1.100
2004-05 1.063
2005-06 1.007
Source: Pakistan Economic Survey (Various Issues); Pakistan
(Various Issues); authors' calculations.
Table 5
Price Multiplier Analysis of the Impacts of Wheat and Fuel Price
Increases on General Inflation in 2005
Production Full Production Full
Multiplier Multiplier Multiplier Multiplier
Wheat Flour Wheat Flour Fuel Fuel
Price Increase 13.80% 13.80% 17.70% 17.70%
CPI Rural Rich 0.80% 2.50% 1.20% 3.60%
CPI Rural Poor 1.10% 2.80% 1.20% 3.60%
CPI Urban Rich 0.60% 2.30% 1.30% 3.70%
CPI Urban Poor 1.27% 3.00% 1.26% 3.70%
Weight Urban Poor 0.089 0.089 0.013 0.013
Weight x Change
in Price 1.23% 1.23% 0.22% 0.22%
Source: Price multiplier model simulations using the 2001 Pakistan SAM.
Note that the weights for wheat flour and fuel in the CPI of the urban
poor are calculated from the 2001 Pakistan SAM.
Table 6
Price Effects of Domestic Procurement in Pakistan:
Partial Equilibrium Analysis for 2005
Imports (mn tons) 0.0 1.4 1.4 2.4
Production Level Target Target Low Low
Production (mn tons) 21.400 21.400 20.535 20.535
Imports (mn tons) 0.000 1.400 1.400 2.400
Supply (mn tons) 18.260 19.660 18.882 19.882
Wholesale Lahore (Rs/kg) 13.0 10.2 11.7 9.8
% change Real Price 5.8% -17.3% -5.4% -20.3%
% change Nominal Price 16.4% -9.0% 4.1% -12.4%
Import Subsidy (bn Rs) 0.0 4.4 2.3 8.4
High Elasticity: (-0.5)
% change Real Price 3.4% -10.8% -3.3% -12.7%
Source: Partial equilibrium model simulations.
Notes: Base own-price elasticity of wheat demand is -0.3.