首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月03日 星期二
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Dynamic effects of energy sector public investment on sectoral economic growth: experience from Pakistan economy.
  • 作者:Ammad, Syed ; Ahmed, Qazi Masood
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2014
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:This study is an addition to a few studies in the developing countries generally, and in Pakistan particularly, which aim at investigating the effects of public investment in energy sector on sectoral output, investment and employment. This study estimates the dynamic elasticities of private investment with respect to public investment to find crowding-out or crowding-in phenomenon in Pakistan, and also to find out the long term marginal productivity and the share of benefits. In addition the Study also reveals the changes in labour absorption due to additional capital. The study covers eight sectors of the Pakistan economy and uses the annual time series data from 1981 to 2011. Vector Auto Regressive (VAR/VECM) technique as developed by Pereira (2000, 2001), which allows measuring the dynamic feedback effect among the variables is used in the current study.
  • 关键词:Economic growth;Energy industries;Energy industry

Dynamic effects of energy sector public investment on sectoral economic growth: experience from Pakistan economy.


Ammad, Syed ; Ahmed, Qazi Masood


ABSTRACT

This study is an addition to a few studies in the developing countries generally, and in Pakistan particularly, which aim at investigating the effects of public investment in energy sector on sectoral output, investment and employment. This study estimates the dynamic elasticities of private investment with respect to public investment to find crowding-out or crowding-in phenomenon in Pakistan, and also to find out the long term marginal productivity and the share of benefits. In addition the Study also reveals the changes in labour absorption due to additional capital. The study covers eight sectors of the Pakistan economy and uses the annual time series data from 1981 to 2011. Vector Auto Regressive (VAR/VECM) technique as developed by Pereira (2000, 2001), which allows measuring the dynamic feedback effect among the variables is used in the current study.

Twenty four sectoral elasticity coefficients for public investment in energy sector are estimated. Of these seven out of eight confirm crowding-in phenomenon in Pakistan economy. This overwhelming evidence confirms that this public investment has positive effect on private investment. The three out of eight elasticity coefficients show public investment has increased labour absorption and remaining five show labour is substituted by capital as a result of increased public investment. Seven out of eight elasticity coefficients show positive output effect, however the overall marginal productivities are lower compared to several developing countries like Portugal and Spain where such analysis has been conducted.

JEL Classification: C32, E62, H54, E22

Keywords: Public Investment, Economic Performance, Sectoral Analysis, Pakistan

1. INTRODUCTION

The successive economic and financial crisis in recent time has reemphasised the importance of fiscal policy. Modern literature has also revisited the debate regarding the effectiveness of fiscal policy in influencing growth. The issue of the impact of public investment on growth is debated in economic literature since seminal work of Solow (1955). The issue is tackled from different angles. Some have used production function approach [Ligthart (2002), Otto and Voss (1994, 1996), Sturm and de Haan (1995) and Wang (2004)]. Then another seminal work by Aschauer (1989) led a series of work on this issue once again in empirical literature (1989a, 1989b). These approaches used single equation method for estimation and captured only the direct effects of public investment on growth. Periera (2000) gave another twist to this literature by highlighting the indirect effects of public investment on output through its effects on other inputs like private investment and employment. Periera's works (1999, 2000, 2001, 2003, 2005, 2007 and 2011) also contributed empirically to this literature by using vector autoregressive (VAR) technique. This work accounts for both the direct and indirect effects of public investment on growth and also considers the feedback effects of each input to other and finally their effects on output.

The classical school believes that an increment in public spending slows down growth and crowd out the private investment. Since higher spending requires higher taxes at individual or corporate level, it creates distortion in the choice of economic agents and increases interest rate. Barro (1991) in his most famous work associated with government size found a negative relationship between growth and government size. Razzolini and Shughart (1997) in the case of United States found a negative relationship between growth rate and relative size of government. Parker (1995) in case of India found crowding out effect of overall public investment while infrastructure investment crowd in private investment. Alesina, et al. (2002) measured the effect of fiscal spending in case of OECD countries in a Tobin's Q model and confirmed a crowding out phenomena. Many other empirical studies found evidence of crowding out effect of government expenditures including [Ganelli (2003), Voss (2002), Engen and Skinner (1992), Folster and Henrekson (2001), Devarajan, et al. (1996), Milesi and Roubini, (1998) and Majumdar (2007)].

The Keynesians on the other hand, consider government spending as a key variable for economic growth. They argue that development expenditures on health, education and infrastructure increase labour productivity and reduce cost of business, which motivates private investment. Many empirical studies support this view. For instance like Chakraborty (2007) examined the real and financial crowding out effect in India using data from 1971 to 2003 through a VAR model and found that public and private investment are complementary. Easterly and Rebelo (1993) in their work found a positive growth effect of public investment, specially transport and communication. Baotai (2004) analysed the effect of public investment through cointegration model during the period 1961 to 2000 for Canada and found mixed results; some public expenditure such as health and education have a positive effect while infrastructure and social security have a negative growth effect. Bose, Haque and Osborn (2007) using data for 30 developing countries found out that government capital expenditures have a positive effect on growth, while at the disaggregate level only education expenditures are positively correlated with growth.

Pereira (2000) investigated the effects of aggregate public investment and infrastructure investment at a disaggregate level by using the VAR model for U.S and found that both at aggregate and disaggregate levels, public investment positively affects output and crowd in private investment. This study estimated a marginal productivity of 4.46 indicating that a one dollar investment will increase private output by about $4.46 and found out that the highest rate of return is in electric, gas, transit system and airfield sectors.

Pereira and Oriol (2001) analysed the marginal productivity of private investment, output and employment with respect to public infrastructure investment in the case of Spain by using VAR methodology. The study used five VAR models, one for aggregate level and remaining four for agriculture, services, manufacturing and construction. The results indicate that at aggregate level public infrastructure investment has positive marginal productivity for each variable while at sectoral level manufacturing, services and construction have positive output, private investment and employment marginal productivity but in the case of agriculture there is negative marginal productivity of output, private investment and employment. The highest output marginal productivity was found in the case of manufacturing being 2.43 indicating one peseta of public investment will generate 2.43 pesetas of output.

Pereira and Andraz (2005) analysed the effect of aggregate public transportation infrastructure investment and its components (national roads, municipal roads, highways, ports, airports and railways) on aggregate private investment, aggregate output and employment in Portugal by using a VAR approach on annual data from 1976 to 1998. They found out that in the long term, aggregate public infrastructure investment of one euro will generate an output of 9.5 euros and also have a positive effect on private investment and employment. At a disaggregate level, they found similar trends for output, employment and revenue. Pereira and Sagales (1999) using the VAR model for Spain found a crowding in effect of public capital on private output and employment. Pina and Aubyn (2006) examined the rate of return of public investment in the case of U.S economy using VAR model for a period of 1956-2001. The four variables used were real private investment, real public investment, private employment and real GDP and found a positive Partial-cost dynamic feedback rate of return of 7.33 percent while the total or Full-cost dynamic feedback came out to be 3.68 percent.

Pereira and Pinho (2011) using the data of twelve euro-zone countries for 1980 to 2003 employed the same methodology and found diverse results. For example, they established that public investment has a positive effect on private investment and employment in all countries except Austria, Belgium Luxembourg and Netherland, while public investment has a positive effect on output in all countries except Luxembourg and Netherland. They also concluded that in the case of Austria, Belgium, Luxembourg and Netherland the public investment has a negative output affect. But in Finland, Portugal and Spain public investment has a positive growth effect; still it is unable to generate sufficient tax revenue. While in case of France, Greece and Ireland public investment pays for itself and finally in the case of Germany and Italy, public investment not only pays for itself but also generates extra tax revenue.

Afonso and Aubyn (2008) utilised accumulated impulse response function of VAR model, which consists of real interest rate, real output, real taxes, real public investment and real private investment for 14 European Union countries and some non-European countries including Japan, Canada and the United States. The results show that output elasticity of private investment is higher than public investment. Further in most of the countries they found a positive marginal productivity accompanied with a crowd-in effect. Voss (2002) investigated the crowding in or out effects in case of Canada and U.S using quarterly data through a VAR model, using real GDP, real interest rate, and share of public and private investment in the GDP. In both countries he found a negative effect of public investment on private investment. Mittnik and Neumann (2001) examined the relationship between public investment, private investment and output using the VAR model for six industrial countries. Results reveal that public investment crowd in private investment in three countries only; however the public investment has a positive output effect in all six countries.

Kamps (2005) measured the elasticites of private investment, employment and output with respect to public investment using a VAR estimation technique based on the variables: "net public capital stock", "number of employed persons", "real GDP" and "private net capital stock". The study was based on 22 countries and showed that public capital stock has a positive effect on output in majority of the countries excluding Japan and Portugal. Further public investment and private investment are complementary and crowding in exists except for Belgium, Japan and U.S. However in the case of employment there is no significant role of public capital.

Pereira (2001) estimated the VAR model using private gross domestic product; private investment, public investment and private employment for U.S economy and both private and public investment are further disaggregated into highways and streets, electric and gas facilities, sewage, water supply, education, hospital building and development structure. At aggregate level he found that public investment has a positive effect on private investment, the marginal productivity was $4.5 with an annual rate of return of 7.8 percent. Pereira and Andraz (2003) examined the effect of aggregate public investment on aggregate private output, employment and investment in the case of U.S using VAR impulse response methodology and found at aggregate level, public investment exerts positive effect on all variables. The study found that an investment of one million dollars will generate 27 new jobs in the long term and one dollar investment of public investment will create $1.112 of private investment and $4,991 of output with an annual rate of return of 8.4 percent. Pereira and Andraz (2003) further analysed the effect of aggregate public investment at disaggregate level and found in six out of twelve industries public investment has a positive employment effect; in five industries crowding in prevailed, while in eight out of twelve industries, public investment has a positive effect on output.

Hyder (2001) examined the effect of real public investment on private investment and growth through a VEC model during 1964 to 2001 and found a complementary relationship between public and private investment and positive growth effect. Saeed et. al (2006) examined the effect of public investment at aggregate and disaggregate level in a VAR model using the variables i.e. public investment, employed labour force, GDP and private investment. The study reveals that in agriculture there is crowding in effect while in manufacturing there is crowding out effect and at the aggregate level the evidence is inconclusive. For example Hussain, et al. (2009) found that defense and debt servicing crowd out investment while development expenditures crowd in investment. Naveed (2002) showed that public capital formation has a crowding in effect. Haque and Montiel (1993) found a crowding out effect in case of Pakistan.

The impact of aggregate public investment on growth is examined vastly in the economic literature. This paper captures both the direct and indirect effects of public investment in energy sector on sectoral output, private investment and employment. This will highlight first the size of the impact of public energy investment on sectoral output and second its impact on private investment. This study also indicates which sector of Pakistan's economy is getting most benefit of energy investment. This will be useful information for the policy-makers.

The remaining study is organised as follows: Section 2 illustrates methodological framework, Section 3 gives data and diagnostic test, Section 4 is based on empirical results and finally conclusions and policy implications are presented in Section 5.

2. METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK

The selection of the methodology and the variables for the present study are based on the empirical studies such as Pereira (2000) and Kamps (2005); where a Vector Auto Regressive (VAR/VECM) technique is used for measuring the dynamic effects of public investment. This methodology significantly differs from the one used in the previous studies related to Pakistan, although some studies applied Vector Auto Regressive (VAR/VECM) models, yet their findings are based on error correction term; other studies measured causality among public investment, private investment and output or their results are merely based on impulse response graphs for measuring the nature of effects either positive or negative. For our analysis, we have divided Pakistan's economy into the following sub sectors; Agriculture, Manufacturing (large and small scale), Mining and Quarrying, Construction, Electricity and Gas Distribution, Transport Storage and Communication, Finance and Insurance plus Ownership of Dwellings and Public Administration, Defence and Community Services. Hence, total eight VAR models are estimated; one for each of eights sectors. The VAR model corresponding to each sector is specified as follow:

[X.sub.t] = C + [p.summation over (i=1)] [A.sub.t] [X.sub.t-i] + [[epsilon].sub.t] ... (2.1)

Where X is the vector of (4x1), C is the intercept vector also (4x1), A is the matrix of coefficient (4x4) and [epsilon] is the vector of error term. Each VAR model consists of Public sector energy investment, Private investment, Output and employment for each sector. The linear form of the model is

Xt = [DELTA]log lpub, [DELTA]log lpriv, [DELTA]log Y, [DELTA]log Emp ... (2.2)

Where lpub, lpriv, Emp and Y are log of real public investment, log of real private investment, log of real output and employment respectively.

Dynamic Feedback Effects

For measuring the effect of public investment on other variables, an impulse response function for each VAR model was generated. By definition an impulse response function measures the effect of a shock in an endogenous variable due to other variables in the model. It is known that residual of the VAR are contemporaneously correlated. For measuring the effect of shock in one variable due to other variable, these residuals should be uncorrelated. The VAR model is modified in such a way that contemporaneous correlation among the residuals is diagonal, called orthogonalisation. To attain these uncorrelated residuals, Choleski decomposition is used and accumulated impulse response is calculated to measure the cumulative response of all variables due to innovation in policy variables i.e. Public investment in energy. The outcome of accumulated impulse response function provides the accumulated long term elasticity of the selected variables due to shock in policy variable where the long term is defined as the time period in which shock disappeared.

Long Term Accumulated Marginal Productivity

The long term accumulated marginal productivity of policy variable measures the unit change of the dependent variable due to one unit change in policy variable. This concept of marginal productivity is different from the conventional concept. One of the main distinctions is that it is not based on the assumption of ceteris paribus; it refers to the accumulated marginal product and captures all the dynamic feedback among the variables. The value of marginal productivity is obtained by multiplying the accumulated long term elasticity with the ratio of policy variable to the response variable.

[[epsilon].sub.IPUB] = [DELTA] log [Y.sub.i]/[DELTA] log [IPub.sub.i] ... (2.3)

The above Equation (2.3) is the long term elasticity, which is obtained directly from an accumulated impulse response function against each sector; which measures the accumulated change in growth rate of different variables. The numerator is the accumulated change in output growth rate of the ith sector, while the denominator is the accumulated change in growth rate of public investment in the ith sector.

The above elasticity is transformed into long term marginal productivity by using following formula

MP [equivalent to] [DELTA]Y/[DELTA]IPub = [[epsilon].sub.IPUB] [Y.sub.i]/[IPub.sub.i] ... (2.4)

In this fashion for each sector; marginal productivities of private investment, output and employment (in terms of number of jobs creation) are measured.

3. DATA SOURCES AND DESCRIPTION

This study is based on annual time series data from 1981 to 2011 obtained from the State Bank of Pakistan Annual Report, 50 Years of Pakistan Economy and various issues of Economic Survey of Pakistan. All variables are converted into real terms based on 1999-2000 prices (2) and their first differences in log form are used in the analysis.

Univariate Analysis

Stationarity of each variable is one of the necessary conditions for forecasting using the VAR model and if there is cointegration then the order of integration must be the same. Augmented Dickey-Fuller (1979) and Philips Perron (1988) test are used to check the order of integration. The final decision based on Philips Perron test results reported in Table 1 show (3) that all the variables are non-stationary at levels using a 5 percent confidence interval, except three variables, which are level stationary. However, at first differences, all the variables are stationary.

VAR Order Selection

Appropriate number of lags is a crucial decision for VAR estimation. There are different information criteria available for choosing a more parsimonious model and we have applied Schwarz (1978) information criterion (SC) and Akaike (1974) information criterion (AIC). For each model lag selection was made on the basis of Schwarz information criterion. The results reveal (4) that in most cases one lag is showing minimum information criterion value while maximum of four lags were incorporated to avoid too many parameters.

Diagnostic Test

The results of the diagnostic tests are given in Table 2. The results indicate that there is no Heteroskedasticity in any model. The results of LM test also support no serial correlation in all the cases except services sector model. The assumption of Normality is also tested in all the cases and the results do not support the normality assumptions in five out of eight cases, but we can ignore this issue as Lutkepohl (1991) discussed that the VAR parameters estimators do not depend on the normality assumption.

Cointegration Analysis

Finally, to decide whether to use Vector Autoregressive Model (VAR) or Vector Error Correction (VEC), a cointegration test is applied to all the models by using Engle-Granger (1987) and Johansen (1991, 1995) approaches. The cointegration results based on Engle-Granger test (5), in all the models reject the existence of cointegration, while in a few models only Johansen test shows the existence of cointegration. The reason for using Engle-Granger approach is based on the finding of Gonzalo and Lee (1998) and Gonzalo and Pitarakis (1999) who mentioned that Johansen approach has small sample bias for cointegration when it does not exist. These findings are similar to other related studies e.g. in the case of Portugal, Pereria and Andraz (2005) and in the case of U.S, Pereria and Andraz (2003) did not find any cointegration.

4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS

This section discusses the empirical effects of public energy investment on sectoral output, private investment and employment. These effects are based on accumulated impulse response function. The effect of a shock in public energy investment on sectoral GDP is traced in terms of output elasticities. The effect of a shock in public energy investment on sectoral private employment is traced in terms of private investment elasticities, similarly the effects of a shock in public energy investment on employment are measured in terms of employment elasticities.

Table 3 gives summary of results of the impact of public investment on output, private investment and employment and detailed graphs are given in Appendix-A which are based on accumulated impulse response function with a time horizon of 20 years. These unit shock effects of public energy investment on output show that public energy investment has a positive effect on the output of all sectors except electricity and gas distribution sector. In case of private investment the impulse response functions indicate that public energy investment also has a positive effect on private investment in all the sectors except finance and insurance, while in case of employment the impulse response function graphs show that only three sectors out of eight have a positive employment effect with respect to public energy investment. One more important feature of these graphs, which is worth mentioning here is that in all the cases the shocks effect dies out after five years, except three sectors.

Measuring the Long-term Accumulated Effect of Public Capital Formation

The Effects of Public Investment on Output

The effect of public investment on sectoral output is presented in Table 4. The results indicate that public investment has positive output effects for all the sectors except electricity and gas distribution. The result shows the sum of marginal productivities across the sectors is 3.57 i.e., one rupee public investment will collectively generate the output of rupees 3.57, which is low as compared to the relatively advanced countries, such as in Spain; Pereira and Oriol (2001) found the aggregate marginal productivity for output of 5.5, similarly in the case of Portugal; Pereia and Andraz (2007) found aggregate marginal productivity of output of 8. On the sectoral level, the public investment's highest benefit share goes to manufacturing followed by mining and quarrying, transport and communication, services, agriculture, finance and insurance and then construction. The share distribution is 24 percent, 21 percent, 17 percent, 11 percent, 10 percent and 3 percent respectively.

The Effects of Public Investment on Private Investment

Table 4 also discusses the impact of public investment on private investment. The empirical results show that public investment has a positive impact on private investment supporting the hypothesis of crowding-in; in seven out of eight sectors i.e. except the services sector. The results show the sum of marginal productivities of private investment across the sectors is 1.35 indicating one rupee public investments will increase private investment by Rs 1.35. These results show that overall impact of public investment on private investment is also low in Pakistan as compared to the other countries. In the case of Spain Pereira and Oriol (2001) found the aggregate marginal productivity of private investment is 10.18, similarly in the case of Portugal, Pereia and Andraz (2007) found aggregate marginal productivity is 9.45. On the sectoral level, the highest benefit share of public energy investment goes to manufacturing followed by agriculture, services, transport and communication, mining and quarrying, electricity and gas and then construction. The share distribution is 47 percent, 11.5 percent, 11 percent, 6 percent, 6 percent and 5 percent respectively.

The Effects of Public Investment on Employment

The employment effect of public investment is presented in Table 4. On the sectoral level, public investment has positive employment effect in agriculture, construction and electricity and gas. The one million rupees public investment will create highest employment in agriculture sector followed by construction and then electricity and gas. In comparison with other studies such as in the case of Portugal, Pereia and Andraz (2007) found the highest benefit share of infrastructure investment in the case of construction followed by finance, services, and real estate. These results show in many sectors it is negative, however these results are also consistent with other studies. For example Pereira and Andraz (2007) found negative employment effect of public infrastructure investment in agriculture, food, textile, other manufacturing and real estate sectors in the case of Portugal.

5. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATION

The objective of this study is to find empirical evidence of the effectiveness of public energy investment in Pakistan. In literature, usually the production function approach is applied for such analysis while this study uses the VAR methodology which allows capturing dynamic feedback effect of public investment on private investment, employment and output.

The study is one of the pioneer attempts on the subject by estimating the long term marginal productivities of public investment at sectoral level. The study uses data of eight sectors of Pakistan economy from 1981-2011. The study estimates eight elasticity coefficients to investigate the impact of public investment on sectoral private investment and confirms crowding-in phenomenon in seven out of eight sectros in Pakistan's economy. This overwhelming evidence confirms that public investment has positive a effect on private investment. The three out of eight elasticity coefficients show public investment has increased labour absorption and the remaining five show labour is substituted by capital as a result of increased public investment. The highest marginal productivity is 0.88 in manufacturing followed by 0.766 and 0.61 in mining and quarrying and transport and communication sectors. This implies one rupee public investment in these sectors will generate rupees 0.88, 0.766 and 0.61 in these sectors respectively. Generally the marginal productivity is lower as compared to several developed countries like Portugal and Spain where such analysis has been conducted.

The results of this study provide the answers to some important policy questions and also help in formulating future policy. This study calculates the marginal productivities, which are useful in project evaluation and investment decisions. The positive output effect indicates that public energy investment is growth stimulating through its direct effect and indirect effects.

Syed Ammad <[email protected]> is PhD Research Fellow, Department of Economics, University of Karachi. Qazi Masood Ahmed <[email protected]> is Professor/Director, Centre for Business and Economics Research, Institute of Business Administration, Karachi.

APPENDIX-A

Impulse Response Graphs

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

REFERENCES

Afonso Antonio and Aubyn Miguel St (2008) Macroeconomic Rates of Return of Public and Private Investment Crowding-in and Crowding-Out Effects, ECB. (Working Paper Series No 864).

Akaike H. (1974) A New Look at the Statistical Model Identification. IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, Ac-19, 716-723.

Alesina, A., S. Ardagna, R. Perotti, and F. Schiantarelli (2002) Fiscal Policy, Profits, and Investment. The American Economic Review 92:3, 571-89.

Alfred, M. Pereira and Oriol Roca-Sagales (2001) Infrastructures and Private Sector Performance in Spain .Journal of Policy Modeling 23: 4, 371-384,

Aschauer, D. (1989a) Is Public Expenditure Productive? Journal of Monetary Economics 23:2, 177-200.

Aschauer, D. (1989b) Does Public Capital Crowd Out Private Capital? Journal of Monetary Economics 24:2, 171-188.

Baotai, Wang (2004) Effectiveness of Government Expenditure on Private Investment: Canadian Empirical Evidence. Empirical Economics 30: 2, 493-504.

Barro, R. (1991) Economic Growth in Cross-Section of Countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106:2, 407-443.

Bose, Niloy, M. Emranul Haque and Denise R. Osborn (2007) Public Expenditure and Economic Growth: A Disaggregated Analysis for Developing Countries. The Manchester School 75: 5, September.

Chakraborty, Lekha (2006) Fiscal Deficit, Capital Formation and Crowding Out: Evidence From India. (NIPFM Working Paper 06/43).

Devarajan, S., V. Swaroop, and H. Zou (1996) The Composition of Public Expenditure and Economic Growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 313-344.

Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller (1979) Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series With A Unit Root. Journal of the American Statistical Association 74, 427-431.

Easterly, W. and S. Rebelo (1993) Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 417-458.

Engen, Em and J. Skinner (1992) Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth. (NBER Working Paper 4223).

Engle, R. F. and C. W. J. Granger (1987) Cointegration and Error Correction Representation: Estimation and Testing. Econometrica 55, 251-276.

Folster, S. and M. Henrekson (2001) Growth Effects of Government Expenditure and Taxation in Rich Countries. European Journal of Political Economy 45, 1501-1520.

Ganeli, Giovanni (2003) Useful Government Spending, Direct Crowding-Out and Fiscal Policy Interdependence. Journal of International Money and Finance 22, 87-103.

Gonzalo, J. and T. Lee (1998) Pitfalls in Testing for Long Run Relationships. Journal of Econometrics 86, 129-54.

Gonzalo, J. and J.-Y. Pitarakis (1999) Dimensionality Effect in Cointegration Analysis. In R. Engle and H. White (eds) Festschrift in Honour of Clive Granger. Oxford: Oxford University Press

Haque, N. U. and P. J. Montial (1993) Fiscal Adjustment in Pakistan: Some Simulation Results. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 40:2, 471-80.

Hussain Adnan, Muhammad Sulaiman D., Akram Kamran and Lai Irfan (2009) Effectiveness of Government Expenditure Crowding-In Or Crowding-Out: Empirical Evidence in Case of Pakistan. European Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Sciences 16.

Hyder, Kalim (2001) Crowding-Out Hypothesis in a Vector Error Correction Framework: A Case Study of Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 40: 4, 633-650.

Johansen, S. (1991) Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of Cointegrating Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models. Econometrica 59, 1551-1580.

Johansen, S. (1995) Likelihood-Based Inference in Cointegrated Vector Autoregressive Models. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Kamps, Christophe (2005) The Dynamic Effects of Public Capital: VAR Evidence For 22 OECD Countries. International Tax and Public Finance, Springer 12:4, 533-558.

Ligthart, J. (2002) Public Capital and Output Growth in Portugal: An Empirical Analysis. European Review of Economics and Finance 1: 2, 3-30.

Lutkepohl, H. (1991) Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis. Berlin: Springer.

Majumder, Md. Alauddin (2007) Does Public Borrowing Crowd-Out Private Investment? The Bangladesh Evidence. Policy Analysis Unit Research Department Bangladesh Bank (Wp#0708).

Milesi-Ferretti, G. and N. Roubini (1998) On the Taxation of Human and Physical Capital in Models of Endogenous Growth. Journal of Public Economics 70, 237-254.

Mittnik, S. and T. Neumann (2001) Dynamic Effects of Public Investment: Vector Autoregression Evidence from Six Industrialised Countries. Empirical Economics 26, 429-446.

Naqvi, Naveed H. (2002) Crowding-in or Crowding-out? Modeling the Relationship between Public and Private Fixed Capital Formation. The Pakistan Development Review 41:3, 255-76.

Otto, G. and G. Voss (1994) Public Capital and Private Sector Productivity. The Economic Record 70: 209, 121-132.

Otto, G. and G. Voss (1996) Public Capital and Private Production in Australia. Southern Economic Journal 62: 3, 723-738.

Parker, K. (1995) The Behaviour of Private Investment. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund. (IMF Occasional Paper No. 134).

Pereira, Alfredo M. and Pinho Maria De Fatima (2013) On the Economic Effects of Public Infrastructure Investment: A Survey of the International Evidence. The College of William and Mary. (Working Paper).

Pereira, Alfredo M. and Pinho Maria De Fatima (2011) Public Investment, Economics Performance and Budgetary Consolidation: VAR Evidence for the 12 Euro Countries. Journal of Economic Development 36:1, 1-20.

Pereira, Alfredo M. and Jorge M. Andraz (2003) On the Impact of Public Investment on the Performance of U.S Industries. Public Finance Review 31:1, 66-90.

Pereira, and Sagales (1999) Public Capital Formation and Regional Development in Spain. Review of Development Economics 3:3, 281-294.

Pereira, A. (2000) Is All Public Capital Created Equal? Review of Economics and Statistics 82:3, 513-518.

Pereira, A. and J. M. Andraz (2007) Public Investment in Transportation Infrastructures and Industry Performance in Portugal. Journal of Economic Development 32, 1-20.

Pereira, A. M. and J. M. Andraz (2005) Public Investment in Transportation Infrastructure and Economic Performance in Portugal. Review of Development Economics 9, 177-196.

Pereira, Alfredo M. (2001) Public Capital Formation and Private Investment: What Crowds in What? Public Finance Review 29:1, 3-25.

Phillips, P.C.B. and P. Perron (1988) Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression. Biometrika 75, 335-346.

Pina, A. and M. St. Aubyn (2006) How should we Measure the Return on Public Investment in a VAR? Economics Bulletin 8:5, 1-4.

Razzolini, Laura, and William F. Shughart Ii (1997) On the (Relative) Unimportance of Balanced Budget. Public Choice 90, 215-233.

Saeed, Hyder and A. Ali (2006) The Impact of Public Investment on Private Investment: A Disaggregated Analysis. The Pakistan Development Review 45:4, 639-663.

Schwarz, G. (1978) Estimating the Dimension of a Model. The Analysis of Statistics 6, 461-464.

Sturm, J. and J. De Haan (1995) Is Public Expenditure Really Productive? New Evidence for the U.S.A. and the Netherlands. Economic Modelling 12: 1, 60-72.

Voss, G. (2002) Public and Private Investment in the United States and Canada. Economic Modeling 19, 641-664.

Wang, B. (2004) Effects of Government Expenditure on Private Investment: Canadian Empirical Evidence. Empirical Economics 30, 493-504.

Comments

It is an awesome topic to work on in the current scenario because the country is facing acute problem of energy which is among the major input in industrial as well as agriculture production. While reading the paper I felt that if authors can incorporate the following comments, it would enhance the quality of their paper.

Authors have used Growth model. Mankiw, Romer Weil (1991) already showed that human capital is extremely important in case of growth modeling, therefore, human capital is extremely important to include in the growth equation.

Since not all the sectors need energy such as finance and insurance thus all the sectors do not need to regress on energy. Therefore, I would recommend to exclude irrelevant variables from the analysis. Moreover, investment in public sector energy ventures are the investment in the manufacturing sector by the public sector, but rest of the investment is missing in the model. The variable is extremely important and should be included in the model to get correct partial association with the main variables.

Paper did not explain procedure adopted to fill the gaps in employment data. As a reader it is a useful information which is missing.

Cointegration in case of growth equation may not be a feasible technique because there are significant chances that labour, capital, human capital and growth are interlinked to each other and there is a problem of endogeneity. Therefore, proper technique should be applied to get the parameters.

The exercise done in Tale 4 is a very good exercise. However, the magnitude and signs of few variables seems to be incorrect. I believe that by including the human capital variables, inclusion and exclusion of relevant and irrelevant variables and adopting proper estimation technique may help in getting correct signs.

As much as I am not convinced with the estimation technique applied in the paper, I am also not convinced with the application of impulse response function on annual data. Impulse response function gives us the response of shock in any variable within the system. By using this technique we know the divergent or converging behavior of the variables. However, it also tells us the duration of period in which shock is either absorbed or tells. Using the technique on annual data, mostly, do not give meaningful results. Therefore, in my view either this technique is not used on annual data or the results should be interpret with caution because "variable will adjust after 8 periods implies 8 years", which in most of the cases is not a meaningful result.

M. Ali Kemal

Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

(2) The data is available in real terms at different base years. For this study as suggested by the discussant we have used a common base of 1999-2000, for the conversion of the nominal variables into real variables.

(3) Due to lack of space just Philips Perron results are reported, but the complete results are available on demand.

(4) Due to lack of space results are not reported, but available on demand.

(5) For the sake of brevity results are not reported, but available on demand.
Table 1
Unit Root Test

                    Phillips-Perron Test Statistic

                                 Level

                                          With Trend and
                   Without Trend             Intercept

Variable      t-Statistic   Prob. *   t-Statistic   Prob. *

LAgr_IPub     -0.544194     0.8729    -1.961717     0.6065
LAgr_IPrv     -0.771485     0.8178    -2.679558     0.2494
LAgr_Emp       1.355936     0.9986    -2.668833     0.2537
LMing_GDP     -0.487884     0.8843    -2.191037     0.4833
LMing_IPrv     0.053368     0.9585    -1.956587     0.6092
LMing_Emp     -2.396637     0.1481    -2.754807     0.2207
LMfg_GDP      -0.292774     0.9181    -2.522159     0.3166
LMfg_IPrv     -0.657962     0.8472    -1.986704     0.5933
LMfg_Emp      -0.321594     0.9136    -1.962546     0.6061
LConst_GDP    -2.153902     0.2254    -1.578453     0.7865
LConst_IPrv   -1.263144     0.6389    -3.388271     0.0652
LConst_Emp    -3.485632     0.0127    -5.753265     0.0001
LElec_GDP     -3.033429      0.039    -1.417099      0.843
LElec_IPub    -1.954775     0.3053    -1.363139     0.8589
LElec_IPrv    -1.212813     0.6613    -1.613274     0.7726
LElec_Emp     -2.104588     0.2439    -3.762389     0.0277
LTranp_GDP    -0.911304      0.776    -3.171151     0.1027
LTranp_IPrv   -0.737195     0.8271    -2.069132      0.549
LTranp_Emp    -3.044822      0.038    -18.15966        0
LFinc_GDP     -0.907251     0.7724    -2.47431      0.3375
LFinc_IPrv    -1.352439     0.5923    -2.562142     0.2987
LFinc_Emp     -1.937825     0.3114    -2.648321     0.2634
LSrv_GDP      -1.509704     0.5201    -2.513062     0.3208
LSrv_IPrv     -0.310469     0.9154    -2.38316      0.3832
LSrv_Emp      -0.072283     0.9464    -6.040012        0
LAgg_GDP      -1.01663      0.7399    -3.168162     0.1033
LAgg_IPrv     -0.246937     0.9247    -2.376024     0.3868
LAgg_Emp       1.100535      0.997    -1.926615     0.6249

                     Phillips-Perron Test Statistic

                            First Difference

                                          With Trend and
                   Without Trend             Intercept

Variable      t-Statistic   Prob. *   t-Statistic   Prob. *

LAgr_IPub     -9.31261         0      -9.993371        0
LAgr_IPrv     -6.833569        0      -6.749098        0
LAgr_Emp      -8.362981        0      -8.815865        0
LMing_GDP     -6.817256        0      -6.751895        0
LMing_IPrv    -7.043074        0      -7.235855        0
LMing_Emp     -5.685598        0      -5.644688     0.0001
LMfg_GDP      -5.750705        0      -5.68134      0.0001
LMfg_IPrv     -5.112176     0.0001    -5.053197     0.0008
LMfg_Emp      -6.843413        0      -6.833039        0
LConst_GDP    -5.429063        0      -5.744962     0.0001
LConst_IPrv   -10.32539        0      -10.17403        0
LConst_Emp    -15.32939        0      -16.14105        0
LElec_GDP     -7.213615        0      -9.89615         0
LElec_IPub    -7.555604        0      -13.90007        0
LElec_IPrv    -5.892388        0      -6.015573        0
LElec_Emp     -12.33055        0      -12.90363        0
LTranp_GDP    -6.598544        0      -6.506002        0
LTranp_IPrv   -4.622056     0.0005    -4.566332     0.0034
LTranp_Emp    -31.51532     0.0001    -33.01162        0
LFinc_GDP     -5.001994     0.0003    -4.92316      0.0021
LFinc_IPrv    -5.476395     0.0001    -5.471944     0.0005
LFinc_Emp     -6.564159        0      -6.570572        0
LSrv_GDP      -7.695887        0      -7.932222        0
LSrv_IPrv     -6.381415        0      -6.31137         0
LSrv_Emp      -16.19263        0      -15.71361        0
LAgg_GDP      -10.29256        0      -9.94885         0
LAgg_IPrv     -5.751953        0      -5.703555     0.0001
LAgg_Emp      -6.48744         0      -6.597266        0

LAgr is representing the log of agriculture sector, Lming is
representing the log of mining sector, LMfg is representing the log
of manufacturing sector, Lconst is representing the log of
construction sector, Lelec is representing the log of electric and
gas sector, LTranp is representing the log of transport and
communication sector, LFinc is representing the log of finance and
insurance sector, LSrv is representing the log of services sector
and LAgg is representing the log of Aggregate economy.
EMP is representing the employment, IPub is representing the public
investment, Iprv is representing the private investment.

Table 2
Diagnostic Test: Dynamic impacts of Public Energy Spending

                                       Numbers   Autocorrelation
                                         of           Test
Sectors/Model                           Lags      (p-value) (1)

Agriculture(Major and Minor Crops,
  Livestock, Fishing and Forestry)        1          0.1958
Mining and Quarrying                      2          0.5828
Manufacturing                             1          0.3933
Construction                              1          0.1936
Electricity and Gas Distribution          1          0.8288
Transport, Storage and Communication      1          0.5089
Finance and Insurance                     1          0.5292
Services (Community Services, Public
  Administration and Defense and
  Ownership of Dwellings)                 1          0.0019

                                         Normality     Heteroskedas-
                                           Test         ticity Test
Sectors/Model                          (p-value) (2)   (p-value) (3)

Agriculture(Major and Minor Crops,
  Livestock, Fishing and Forestry)        0.1381          0.6523
Mining and Quarrying                      0.9435          0.5831
Manufacturing                              0.145          0.9859
Construction                               0.978          0.8569
Electricity and Gas Distribution             0            0.9359
Transport, Storage and Communication       0.766          0.8618
Finance and Insurance                      0.001          0.5744
Services (Community Services, Public
  Administration and Defense and
  Ownership of Dwellings)                 0.0017          0.1813

(1.) Based on VAR residual serial correlation LM test with null no
serial correlation.

(2.) Multivariate Jarque-Bera residual normality test. For the null
hypothesis of normality.

(3.) VAR Residual Heteroskedasticity Tests. For null hypothesis of
no Heteroskedasticity.

Table 3
Long Term Accumulated Impulse Response Effects
of Public Energy Investment

                                         On     On Private       On
Sectors                                Output   Investment   Employment

Agriculture(Major Crops, Minor
  Crops, Livestock, Fishing  and
  Forestry)                              +          +            +
Mining and Quarrying                     +          +            -
Manufacturing                            +          +            -
Construction                             +          +            +
Electricity and Gas Distribution         -          +            +
Transport, Storage and Communication     +          +            -
Finance and Insurance                    +          -            -
Services (Community Services, Public
  Administration and Defense,
  Ownership of Dwellings)                +          +            -

Table 4
Effects of Public Energy Investment on Output, Private Investment
and Employment

                                  Share Contribution

                         % of total   %of total    % of total
                           Output      Private     Employment
Sectors                               Investment

Agriculture                21.38        12.09        43.82
Mining and Quarrying        2.93         4.66         0.17
Manufacturing              18.09        25.55        13.42
Construction                2.35         1.45         6.24
Electricity and Gas
  Distribution              2.33         2.62         0.7
Transport, Storage and
  Communication            12.67        18.65         5.51
Finance and Insurance       4.48         4.70         0.91
Services                   18.02        27.22        14.23
Sum                        82.27        96.95          85

                                  Elasticities

                         Output     Private     Employment
                                   Investment
Sectors

Agriculture              0.0085      0.0640       0.0061
Mining and Quarrying     0.1220      0.0766      -0.1831
Manufacturing            0.0227      0.1025      -0.0190
Construction             0.0214      0.1884       0.0142
Electricity and Gas
  Distribution           -0.0074     0.1268       0.0038
Transport, Storage and
  Communication          0.0227      0.0325      -0.0219
Finance and Insurance    0.0372     -0.1371      -0.0245
Services                 0.0125      0.0237      -0.0356
Sum

                              Marginal Productivity

                         Output     Private     Employment
                                   Investment
Sectors

Agriculture              0.3892      0.2107       3.0902
Mining and Quarrying     0.7666      0.0971      -0.3669
Manufacturing            0.8830      0.7132      -2.9306
Construction             0.1080      0.0746       1.0190
Electricity and Gas
  Distribution           -0.0370     0.0903       0.0302
Transport, Storage and
  Communication          0.6172      0.1650      -1.3880
Finance and Insurance    0.3576     -0.1756      -0.2560
Services                 0.4850      0.1754      -5.8241
Sum                       3.57        1.35        -6.63

                             Shares of Benefits (%)

                         Output    Private     Employment
                                  Investment
Sectors

Agriculture              10.79%     13.81%       74.65%
Mining and Quarrying     21.25%     6.36%          --
Manufacturing            24.48%     46.73%         --
Construction             3.00%      4.89%        24.62%
Electricity and Gas
  Distribution             --       5.92%        0..73%
Transport, Storage and
  Communication          17.11%     10 81%         --
Finance and Insurance    9.91%        --           --
Services                 13.44%     11.49%         --
Sum

Source: Authors' own estimation.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有