Transport policy and policy research: some concluding remarks.
Sager, Fritz ; Kaufmann, Vincent
Introduction
As a conclusion to this special issue on transport policy research,
we want to come back to the question of what is the gain of policy
research for the specific needs of the field of transport policy.
Opening this volume, we have outlined some three general axes of
research interest we consider especially interesting for the present
object of analysis. We have argued that the questions of coordination,
of policy design, and of innovation are somewhat inherent to the field
of transport policy.
First, coordination is a major issue in transport policy as it is a
pronouncedly interdependent field of public action, not only interlinked
with planning, housing, and land-use policy, but in a much wider sense
subject of foreign policy, economic policy, and regional equalization attempts to name just a few.
The question of policy design, then, is relevant for every public
policy, of course. In the field of transport policy, however, we have
argued that the chosen instruments are of special interest for the
following reasons: first, as already pointed out, transport policy has
many cross-sectoral implications, which makes its goals largely
interdependent. The policy design, thus, not only has to influence
individual and societal behavior in one direction, but in many
directions at the same time, thereby taking into account the
cross-sectional character of the policy. Second, transport policy is
treating the general societal phenomenon of mobility--the very nature of
today's society rather than a mere characteristic. Transport policy
treats a core trait of the modern world. It cannot be the goal,
therefore, to change mobility itself, but rather the patterns of
mobility in order to find a way to make the said nature of today's
society compatible with actual society. Sustainability in this
understanding is besides its already broad meaning also a question of
speed--social, economic, and regarding the use of natural resources.
This complexity of political goals in transport policy makes the
question of policy design outstandingly interesting for policy research.
Finally, it is for the same reason that we consider the question of
innovation a third major stake for the analysis of transport policy.
Transport is a field, which is almost as much subject to technical
innovation as is the field of information technologies. This important
technological progress offers great opportunities, but embraces also
threats. The opportunities lie in possibility to solve political
problems linked to transport without challenging the mobile nature of
society. The threats, however, are to be found on the very level: it is
a grand illusion to think political problems can be solved on a purely
technical basis, ignoring all their social components. The question of
innovation in the field of transport policy, therefore, is also a
question of the balance between technical and social solutions to
political problems.
It is along these three streams that we discuss the question of
what is the specific contribution of policy research for the field of
transport policy. We will address this question based on the articles
collected in this volume.
The question of coordination
There is not one article in this volume that would not at least
touch on the question of coordination. Policy research identifies the
three forms of coordination: inter-sectoral, between political entities
at the same level, i.e. horizontal, and between higher and lower levels,
i.e. vertical. In most cases, coordination takes place in all three
forms at the same time.
To begin with the supranational level, Liana Giorgi and Michael
Schmidt describe the history of European transport policy as a
"long process of approximation of national transport
policies". Beginning as a mere exchange of ideas without any
decision making ambitions, this process takes its turn with the
development of the Common European Transport Policy in 1985 and starts
producing decisions more binding upon the member states. While Giorgi
and Schmidt highlight the turn from negative towards positive
integration, we might as well speak for the present purposes of a turn
from a negative to a positive coordination as Scharpf (1994, 1997)
describes them. (1) As Giorgi and Schmidt show in their article, this
shift from negative to positive coordination has important effects on
the processes of institutional innovation (cf. below).
A different perspective is taken on by Dirk Lehmkuhl who challenges
in his article assumptions of a broad harmonisation of national
transport policies as a result of vertical coordination activities
within the Common European Transport Policy. On the contrary, Lehmkuhl
identifies a wide range of different national responses to the Common
Policy with the complete railway liberalization in Great Britain on the
one hand and the very low reform capacity in Italy on the other.
Lehmkuhl states: "Europeanisation is not convergence, although
convergence may be one dimension of Europeanisation". Vertical
coordination does not necessarily lead to horizontal coordination.
While Christian Hirschi's, Walter Schenkel's, and Thomas
Widmer's contribution only implicitly concerns the question of
coordination, namely by treating the highly intersectoral concept of
sustainability, it is the two articles concerned with transport policy
at the local level that give deeper insights in the question of
coordination inherent to transport policy.
In his comparison of transport policies in five European cities,
Bernard Jouve points out a whole catalogue of reasons for coordination
in urban transport planning in order to be able to link content and
form, i.e. policy and polity: do different problems lead to different
solutions? In his in depth analysis of the problems of urban transport,
he enumerates coordination needs ranging from public finance to
participation and inter-organisational exchange.
Mario Gualdi and Carlo Sessa describe the major shift in
Rome's planning policy from a sectoral to an intersectoral approach
resulting in a new Master Plan somewhat integrating land use planning culture and transport planning culture. The benefits from this
integration are evident: Identifying different urban zones leads to road
classification according to their actual function and enables
authorities to meet the demands for public transportation by proper
planning.
Both articles, however, take the lack of coordination as the
starting point for institutional and procedural innovation.
Taken together, the articles presented here show the important
relevance of the question of coordination for the analysis of transport
policy. However, what we also find is how policy research concepts help
a lot in order to fully understand dynamics of transport policy
processes.
The question of policy design
As we have seen before, the analysis of transport policy measures
and instruments is of specific interest due to the lack of a clear
sectoral goal instead of the highly inter-sectoral character of
transport policy. It is this problem of choosing political goals which
takes Giorgi and Schmidt to the prognosis of a paradigm shift on the
EU-level towards a re-definition of transport policy, thereby pondering
the problems of pollution and congestion stronger than they are within
the actual paradigm of liberalisation.
Lehmkuhl shows us in his contribution how much the national
responses to the Common European Transport Policy differ, and makes a
strong point that the choice of policy measures adopted remains to a
great extent determined by the preexisting political conditions in a
member state.
It is then Hirschi, Schenkel, and Widmer who pose the question of
the actual effects of transport policy design. From their cross-country
as well as cross-issue comparison, they draw three crucial conclusions:
First, they find that the acceptance of regulatory measures depends on
the politico-administrative traditions of a country rather than on the
actual instruments chosen.
Both this first finding of Hirschi et al.'s as well as
Lehmkuhl's conclusion strongly support the culturalist thesis held
by sociologist neo-institutionalists (March and Olsen 1989) postulating
that the main character of political institutions such as regulatory
policy designs is their appropriateness with their socio-structural
context (Hall and Taylor 1996). Institutions will not develop nor last
unless they 'fit in'. A trivial finding, one should think, but
often left unconsidered when new policy designs are being formulated.
In a second finding, Hirschi, Schenkel and Widmer state on the
impact-side that an inclusive policy design, i.e. a policy design in
accordance with the inter-sectoral character of transport policy and
thus meeting the need for coordination, is not less accepted than a more
sectoral policy design. Gualdi and Sessa expect the same effect when
they describe the changing planning paradigm from sectoral to
inter-sectoral planning, integrating both transport and land use
approaches (an imperative for urban planning policy as highlighted by
Jouve). The output of this shift so far is an inclusive Master Plan for
Rome. Hirschi et al.'s finding has quite an optimistic implication
regarding the omnipresent goal of sustainability--a goal that Giorgi and
Schmidt expect to become more important than now also on the European
level.
The third conclusion of Hirschi et al.'s then formulates the
big challenge for the future: The better a transport policy's short
term elements can be connected to its long term measures, the better it
can be communicated to the public and the higher its acceptance will be.
It is these two latter conclusions which show us that transport
policy analysis not only profits from concepts provided by policy
research, but that the analysis of transport policy also highlights
specific aspects of policy design and thus can enrich policy research as
a whole.
The question of innovation
As a both very technical and very social field of public action,
transport policy, more than other policies, is confronted with the
question of how to balance technical and political innovation. The
present articles put the respective political institutions in a very
pivotal position between the technical and the social, i.e. political
level of innovation. So, what triggers institutional innovation?
As stated above, some of the findings presented in this volume are
in line with certain claims of the so-called 'limited
rationality'-school of the new institutionalism. When we draw our
attention to the question of institutional innovation, though, we will
find that also postulates from both the public choice-school and the
historical new institutionalism are supported.
We already have seen that Lehmkuhl's as well as Hirschi et
al.'s findings support the culturalist assumption that new
institutions only develop and existing institutions only change when the
innovation is appropriate for the social and political culture of their
context. The slow start of the European transport policy described by
Giorgi and Schmidt also fits in this line of argument.
A competing assumption to this thesis is the 'calculus
approach' pursued by the public choice-school linking institutional
innovation to the interests of their members. Hall and Taylor (1996)
have labeled this approach the "logic of consequences" as
opposed to the mentioned "logic of appropriateness". This
functional line of reasoning is well suited to the explanation of the
further process of European transport policy as observed by Giorgi and
Schmidt. While Lehmkuhl highlights the limits to a future European
Transport Policy, Giorgi and Schmidt focus on its requirements, thus
sticking to the functional approach: the main challenge of a future
transport policy is the political agreement on "a suitable
institutional framework on how to reach policy decisions". The same
logic is adopted by Sessa and Gualdi who see the urgent need for more
coordination in urban planning as the trigger for institutional
innovation in Rome. The centralization of tasks in the new independent
agency is a rational decision by the involved actors in order to solve a
well-defined problem.
Finally, Jouve evaluates the innovation capacity in five European
cities with a strong focus on the technical aspects of transport policy.
While generally in accordance with the sociological school, Jouve
observes a strong path dependency in policy change. Historical
institutionalists use this concept in order to explain why chosen policy
options are not always fit for the problems at stake but rather well
compatible with policy options adopted in former policy choices. A way
out of this somewhat vicious circle is proposed, though. By adopting a
culturalist perspective, Jouve argues that the reconstruction of
political leadership sensitive to questions of transport policy can be a
way to change social norms and categories, thereby preparing the context
for innovative policy solutions that address the present problems.
"We have to hold on to both ends of the cord", Jouve
concludes: "'technify' public matters and democratise technical debate."
Conclusion
We have introduced this volume by outlining three research
interests we consider specific for the analysis of transport policy,
namely the questions of coordination, of policy design, and of
innovation. We have checked in these concluding remarks how the articles
collected in this issue treat these questions in order to find out what
is the contribution of policy research for the specific field of
transport policy.
As we hope we could show here, not only does the policy benefit
from the research, but the theorizing profits from the specific policy
field. On the one hand, concepts of policy research not only help
understand coordination processes and institutional innovation, but also
contribute to the drawing of lessons and the formulation of practical
recommendations. In this vein, we have to hallmark the high relevance of
political institutions as it is introduced by the different schools of
new institutionalism. This theoretic approach helps a great deal in
understanding transport policy, as the different contributions show, by
recognizing the salience of action or choice and defining choice as
expressions of expectations of consequences in the policy process.
On the other hand, the deeper analysis of the specific features of
transport policy in turn offers new insights relevant for policy
research as a whole and contributes to the further development of its
concepts and theories.
As a final point to this collection of scientific articles we would
like to emphasize this high mutual relevance of social sciences and
practical politics. Social science does not only contribute to the
solving of political problems, it also profits from the twists and turns
politics comes up with on a daily basis.
(1) "In welfare-theoretical terms, successful negative
co-ordination will ensure that new policy initiatives must be
Pareto-superior to the status quo, while positive co-ordination aims at
the more ambitious Kaldor optimum. Procedurally, positive co-ordination
is associated with multilateral negotiations in intra- or
interministerial task forces whose mandate includes consideration of all
policy options of all participating units. By contrast, negative
co-ordination will typically take the form of bilateral
'clearance' negotiations between the initiating department and
other units whose portfolios might be affected--but whose own policy
options are not actively considered. Moreover, explicit clearance will
often be reduced to a mere formality when the initiating unit is able to
anticipate objections and to adjust the design of its proposal
accordingly" (Scharpf 1994: 39).
Bibliography
Hall, Peter A., and Rosemary C. R. Taylor (1996). "Political
Science and the Three New Institutionalisms", Political Studies
XLIV(5): 936-957.
March, James G., und Johan P. Olsen (1989). Rediscovering
Institutions. The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: Free
Press.
Scharpf, Fritz W. (1994). "Games Real Actors Could Play.
Positive and Negative Coordination in Embedded Negotiations",
Journal of Theoretical Politics 6(1): 27-53.
Scharpf, Fritz W. (1997). Games Real Actors Play. Boulder, CO.:
Westview.
Fritz Sager
Buero Vatter, Policy Research and Consulting Bern
Vincent Kaufmann
Universite de Cergy Pontoise and Laboratoire de Sociologie urbaine
(LASUR)--Swiss Federal Institute of Technology, Lausanne