Health governance in the aftermath of traditional corporatism: one small step for the legislator, one giant leap for the subsystem?
Bandelow, Nils C.
1 Introduction (1)
Until the late 1980s outpatient care in Germany was an
"ideal-type" of sectoral corporatism (Rosenbrock/Gerlinger
2006: 280). Self-governance and the dominance of large provider
associations were the main characteristics of the German outpatient
health care governance (Lehmbruch 1988). Public corporations in
particular were able to insure privileges for their members by being
involved in every decision concerning the range of benefits and prices
of outpatient care.
This system has come under increasing political pressure since the
first oil crisis in the mid 1970s (Hegelich/Meyer 2008: 130-131).
Governments led by both the CDU/CSU and the SPD have argued for
sustainable solutions to contain the rising health costs. More than 20
attempts to introduce structural reforms have been undertaken, though
most of these only lead to incremental change. The German consensus
democracy, the patterns of semi-sovereignty and the powerful
associations worked as efficient veto points in preventing a significant
change in the German health system (Al-tenstetter/Busse 2005).
If the supporters of major reform policy look at the policy outcome
there will be little cause for optimism: The proportion of the GDP on
health expenditure has risen continuously. The most recent Statutory
Health Insurance (SHI) Competition Strengthening Act of 2007 (CSA,
GKV-Wettbe-werbsstarkungsgesetz), concurred with a further rise of
contributions to the SHI (Green/Paterson 2009). Considering the
financial and economic crisis that started in 2008 even larger problems
in the German health system can be expected.
But there is another side to the German health policy that is
revealed when investigating policy output instead of outcome: Despite
the failure of sustainable cost containment there have been some
considerable changes in the institutional structures. The first major
changes were introduced by the Health Structure Act (HAS,
Gesundheitsstrukturgesetz) of 1992. The HSA did not overcome the
self-governance of the SHI but changed the legal framework of the
negotiations significantly (Bandelow 1998: 206-208).
The subsequent attempts of both the former Kohl and Schroder
governments hardly continued the structural conversion started by the
HSA. So it was up to the grand coalition that came into power in 2005 to
take up the dissolution of the power of the associations and to change
traditional patterns of negotiations. Both the SPD and the CDU/CSU
shared at least the wording of their ideas to strengthen competition
within the system even though the parties have totally different views
of the problem, the future health system and even the definition of
competition (Bandelow/Schade 2009).
At present the structural changes introduced by the latest reform
are about to be implemented. There is much change happening within
outpatient care. Up to now we can only observe the output and impact of
the changes. One has to complete the analysis of the changes that have
occurred so far by looking at the long term perspective. What will be
the outcome of these changes? This article aims at answering this
question by combining the heuristics of the policy cycle with a
perspective centered on the protagonists. Referring to the
Actor-Centered Institutionalism (Scharpf 1997) it will argue that
changes of institutional rules will result in predictable decisions of
rational actors. Unlike most applications of the Actor-Centered
Institutional-ism this observation will not only be used to create
models that explain past policy results but to formulate scenarios of
future policies.
Part 2 will focus on the changes in the legal framework. Health
care policy has already led to major changes within the system of
organized interests, especially concerning physicians'
associations. These policy impacts will be presented in part 3.
Subsequently the manifold changes in German regions are analyzed to
develop ideal-typical scenarios of the possible future of hierarchy,
market, and cooperation in outpatient care governance.
2 Policy Output: Legal Changes of Outpatient Care Governance
Outpatient care governance underwent several changes during the
last decades. After World War II it took many years to re-establish the
major elements of the Bismarckian health system. Against some opposition
by the social democrats, the early Adenauer government not only
re-introduced the separate systems of sickness funds, but also
relaunched the corporatist institutions. The most important players
within the system of outpatient care became the Associations of
Statutory Health Insurance Physicians (ASHIP, Kassenarztliche
Vereinigungen) that were provided with the full responsibility to
guarantee the provision of outpatient services. The ASHIP negotiated
with the sickness funds on both the regional and the national levels. On
the national level the government refunded the National Committee of
SHI-Physicians and Sickness Funds in 1956. The National Committee has
increasingly gained authority and became the most important institution
within the German health system (Dohler 2002).
During the first decades the governments aimed at providing a
system that guaranteed solidarity within the limits of stratification
and subsidiarity. This means, that the range of benefits and the
proportion of public financed health services grew. Indeed, the
solidaristic system still excluded parts of society like civil servants
and high-income households. Furthermore, it relied on the separation of
societal groups to be insured in different subsystems of the health
insurance.
In the aftermath of the economic crisis of 1973, the ability to
finance the system became the major goal of German health policy. To
achieve this goal, the cost containment policy that started in the mid
1970s originally extended and deepened the system of self-governance and
corporatism. The Health Insurance Cost-Containment Act (HICCA,
GKV-Kostendampfungs-gesetz) of 1977 established the Concerted Action in
Health Care (CAHC). The CAHC intentionally used the name of the
tripartite economic Concerted Action that broke up in the same year
(1977). Unlike the National Committee, the Concerted Action never became
a central institution for outpatient governance. The Concerted Action
suffered from the problem of unanimity by having to include a large
diversity of interest groups. It never gained enough legitimacy to
implement major policy changes (Wiesenthal 1981).
So the cost containment policy originally established sectoral
committees of provider associations and sickness funds and strengthened
the competencies of these committees. The state supervised these
committees and used soft forms of governance to reach their own goals.
Negotiations have been the most important type of governance while the
governing capacity of the state was limited and there was almost no
competition within the system. This strategy was pursued until the end
of the 1980s.
Since 1992, there have been different and partly oppositional
strategies concerning change of the health policy governance. The Health
Structure Act occasionally pursued a strategy that aimed at weakening
the traditional negotiation structures. It used several legal
instruments of hierarchical steering like cost budgeting and limitation
of approved physicians. Additionally, the HSA was a first step to enable
competition by introducing an organizational reform of sickness funds.
After the HSA had been enacted by an informal Grand Coalition, the
Kohl government returned to the strategy of strengthening
self-governance. The SHI Reorganization Acts of 1997
(GKV-Neuordnungsgesetze) were communicated using the motto "right
of way for self-governance" (Bande-low 1998: 219).
Nevertheless the second Reorganization Act already allowed
decentralized competition (SVR Gesundheit 2005: 35). By introducing the
possibility of pilot projects (article 63 of Social Code Book V) and
structure contracts (article 63a of Social Code Book V) a test phase of
new supply forms was initiated. Model plans served the development of
organization and payment to increase quality and economic efficiency.
Sickness funds got the chance to conclude contracts with individual
doctors, doctor's teams or associations of Statutory Health
Insurance Physicians. The act used financial incentives to stimulate
competition within the medical profession.
The actual effect of the pilot programs has been limited by hurdles
that came into force during the implementation phase. In particular the
high start-up expenses proved to be an obstacle. Savings could only be
reached in the medium term and were often only small and did not
immediately go back to the model plan. At the same time the sickness
funds aimed at limiting their expenses instead of increasing the quality
of services. Therefore most actors would not consider the competitive
elements of the 1997 reform as successful (Rosenbrock/Gerlinger 2006:
257).
In spite of these failures the red-green government continued the
strategy of the Reorganization Acts. It introduced further contract
options in 2000. In contrast to the Kohl government, the green health
minister Andrea Fischer not only wanted to increase financeability but
also to ensure better quality by changing the governance patterns. The
government therefore focused on the idea of integrated care to combine
primary with specialist and inpatient services (articles 140a-d of
Social Code Book V). Although the implementation still relied on the
negotiations between the different types of providers. In the end the
results were not very satisfying. The reform enabled some networks of
SHI practices but did not overcome the border between inpatient and
outpatient care. It thereby demonstrated again the difficulty of
introducing considerable changes by relying on the bodies of
self-governance and corporatism.
After the replacement of Andrea Fischer with the social democrat
Ulla Schmidt, the strategy of the ministry changed. Schmidt increased
the pressure to strengthen the state, to enable competition and to
overcome traditional patterns of self-governance and corporatism. She
first used a policy window in the aftermath of chancellor
Schroder's agenda 2003 speech to mirror the Health Structure Act of
1992: In 2004 she agreed with the oppositional CDU/CSU to introduce the
SHI Modernization Act (GKV-Modernisierungsgesetz). The reform has become
a perfect example of poor reform communication. Schmidt gave way to the
CDU/CSU to introduce a quarterly flat-rate charge of SHI patients for
ambulatory treatment. This treatment fee of 10 Euros is very unpopular
and gave the provider groups the chance to attack the reform altogether.
The modernization act also was a significant step in changing
health care governance. It extended the legal basis of integrated care
and increased the monetary incentives. Additionally, medical care units
(Medizinische Ver-sorgungszentren) were allowed (paragraph 95 Social
Code Book V) and the threshold between inpatient and outpatient care was
lowered (paragraphs 73c and 116b Social Code Book V). So the negotiation
system of the Associations of Statutory Health Insurance Physicians not
only lost their monopoly but had to face real alternatives. Since 2004,
1,088 medical care units have been established. Most of these units are
located in large cities and are under the aegis of office-based
physicians (Arzte Zeitung 30th October 2008).
At the end of 2008, there were about 6,000 contracts in the field
of integrated care, although most of these contracts only covered a
small amount of money (altogether about 800 million Euros). In contrast
to other patterns of single contracts, the future of integrated care
still remains unsolved. In 2008 the start-up funding for integrated care
ended and experts expected about half of the contracts to be phased out
(Arzte Zeitung 12th November 2008).
The displacement of the traditional corporatist actors and
institutions was supplemented with a centralization of decisions
relating to the general framework for contracts. The reform of 2004
merged the numerous National Committees of providers and sickness funds
to become a Federal Joint Committee (FJC, Gemeinsamer Bundesausschuss).
The FJC defines the range of benefits and also decides upon the approval
of new sorts of treatment using a cost benefit analysis.
The Federal Joint Committee still is an arena of self-governance
and could even be interpreted as a new form of corporatism (Gerlinger
2008). The centralization enabled much more direct control of the health
ministry though. In contrast to the situation in the former National
Committees, no provider is able to dominate the negotiations within the
FJC. The Associations of Statutory Health Insurance Physicians in
particular lost influence within the new system. Officially, the
ministry is only a legal supervisor, but it takes this supervision quite
seriously and is suspected by the members of the FJC of
(mis)interpreting its role to become a functional supervisor (according
to interviews with representatives of associations that are members
within the FJC).
Ulla Schmidt survived as health minister when the red green
government was replaced by the second formal Grand Coalition in 2005.
She still followed the strategy of weakening the actors and institutions
of the traditional corporatist system. On the federal level, the Grand
Coalition continued to strengthen state control. The changes on the
regional level are much more difficult to evaluate, as the latest reform
eliminated old structures without determining the new system.
In January 2007, the Amendment to the Law Governing the
Professional Activities of Physicians in General Practice
(Vertragsarztrechtsande-rungsgesetz) enabled new forms of contracts. It
became much easier for physicians to work at multiple places and to
employ other physicians.
The main health reform act of the Grand Coalition was the
Competition Strengthening Act (CSA), enacted in April 2007. Like the
Modernization Act, the CSA was a disaster in public communication. The
public only was aware of the financial reform. The parties have bound
themselves to the apparently incompatible concepts of citizens'
insurance (SPD) and health premium (CDU). Bargaining between the party
leadership of both partners led to the health care fund
(Gesundheitsfonds, Richter 2005), which looked like a sell-out that did
not serve either of the goals of both parties.
Even though it did not receive much public attention, civil
servants used the public controversy concerning financial issues to
introduce major changes of health care governance (Bandelow/Schade
2008). While the act of January 2007 strengthened regional pluralism,
the CSA--despite its name--did not directly enable competition but
continued the centralization of the system. The FJC especially has
become professionalized and now includes professionals appointed by the
Ministry of Health. The number of other members was reduced and the
former corporate bodies of the health insurances were downgraded to
become private associations. Their competencies were mainly given to a
new SHI umbrella association of all sickness funds.
The health care fund also contributes to the centralization. While
up to the end of 2008 each sickness fund could decide on its respective
contribution rate, there will be a single rate valid for all sickness
funds. The rate is actually set by the ministry. The sickness funds are
allowed to raise an additional contribution or to pay a refund to those
insured dependent on their respective balances. In contrast to the
different contribution rates, the additional contribution is quite
visible for those insured (who have to bear it on their own, while the
employers are released from paying more than 7.3 percent of the base
rate salary). So the health fund might increase the pressure on the
sickness funds to achieve financeability in the long run.
In total, there are changes towards both more competition and more
state. The results are appropriately described as a 'regulated
health market' by Bockmann (2007). Similar developments also can be
found at other Bis-marckian health insurance systems as in France and
the Netherlands (Has-senteufel/Palier 2007). At the federal level, the
health ministry became the central actor with an advanced legal
supervision and enlarged intervention authority. At the regional level
single health insurances play a significant role to implement the
federal measures.
At present, there are still different possible paths for the future
of German health governance. Although the changes of the legal framework
and the increasing pressure of financeability already caused significant
changes in physicians' associations that will be evaluated in the
next chapter.
3 Policy Impact: Actors and Goals in the new German Outpatient Care
Policy
As shown above, legal changes enabled new patterns of contracts
between suppliers and sickness funds at the regional level. The regional
Associations of Statutory Health Insurance Physicians lost their
monopolies. The new legal framework intended to give sickness funds a
stronger position for negotiations with the physicians. They can now
close contract with single suppliers or supplier groups. The physicians
reacted to these changes by reorganizing their interests within new
associations and cooperatives. At the same time, the traditional
associations have to redefine their role within the new framework. As a
consequence, one can observe several exciting developments in the
intermediation of physicians' interest.
The best known and by now most successful new cooperative is the
MEDI group which was founded by former officials of a southern ASHIP as
a parallel organization to the corporate bodies. The more than 12,000
physicians and psychotherapists that are organized within MEDI are
companions of the MEDI GmbH. Starting with Baden-Wuerttemberg the MEDI
cooperatives have succeeded in founding new organizations in several
federal states and at least partly reach high organizational degrees. By
now, MEDI groups exist in Bavaria, Berlin, Brandenburg, Hesse,
Mecklenburg-West Pomerania and Rhineland-Palatinate, associated are
practise networks in North Rhine-Westphalia.
MEDI belongs to the most radical associations within the new
system. The cooperatives aim at completely replacing the system of the
corporative bodies at the regional level. For that purpose they use the
paragraphs 72a and 95b of the Social Code Book V. These articles specify
the chances for competitors to take over the responsibility for
guaranteeing provision of services from a regional ASHIP. If more than
70 percent of the physicians within a medical specialty, a region or a
federal state deliberately resign from their approval as ASHIP members,
the responsibility for the services passes on to the sickness funds.
The self-image of MEDI is to be a multidisciplinary, democratically
legitimized community of office-based physicians that follows espousing
conservative values and structure-conservative beliefs. The cooperation
strives for both a political and economic mandate to negotiate the
interests of its members. It supplies and organizes individual contracts
with sickness funds by using the legal framework of regional competition
(Rubsam-Simon 2005).
MEDI follows the core belief that only practice networks will be
able to protect office-based physicians against the dominant demand
power of the sickness funds. The practice networks need stable internal
contracts to guarantee high income for their members in spite of the
legal attempts to weaken physicians' negotiation position.
While MEDI is quite successful in southern Germany, other
physicians' cooperatives have been founded that have more influence
in northern federal states. Especially in Lower Saxony and
Schleswig-Holstein these "Arzte-genossenschaften" have already
reached sufficient membership to negotiate for individual contracts with
sickness funds (Arzte Zeitung 22nd September 2008). In 2008, the federal
association of these Arztegenossenschaften claimed that they have nearly
15,000 members in total.
Beside the corporative bodies and the newly emerged cooperatives
there are several established and new associations that organize the
interest of German physicians. The largest of these associations within
outpatient care is the traditional Hartmannbund. The Hartmannbund is the
oldest German physicians' association. Its predecessor Leipziger
Verband was founded in 1900. It organizes physicians of all sectors but
concentrates on office-based physicians. About two thirds of its nearly
40,000 members work in outpatient care. The Hartmannbund is a very
traditional lobbying group and still defends core features of the old
system. In contrast to MEDI, it has for a long time avoided taking part
in single negotiations with health care funds.
The Hartmannbund is mirrored in several ways by the
NAV-Virchow-bund that was founded by a fusion of a physicians'
association from the old federal republic with a strong partner from
eastern Germany. The NAV-Virchowbund has about 20,000 members. Its
opposition toward the new contractual system is not as radical as the
position of the Hartmannbund. In contrast to the Hartmannbund, the
NAV-Virchowbund agreed upon a general cooperation with MEDI and the
Arztegenossenschaften at the federal level to prepare joint contracts on
the basis of articles 73b and 73c (Arzte Zei-tung 1st July 2008).
Both the Hartmannbund and the NAV-Virchowbund are facing rising
competition of associations that organize specific groups of physicians.
The biggest of these associations are the German Association of General
Practitioners (GAGP, Deutscher Hausarzteverband) that has about 23,000
members and the Professional Association of German Internists (PAGI,
Berufs-verband Deutscher Internisten) with some 25,000 members. Both
associations contribute to the rising conflict between general
practitioners and specialists. The conflict is a continuing issue within
the corporate bodies and sometimes also reaches the new cooperatives.
Beside the PAGI there are several smaller associations of
specialists. Fifteen of these smaller associations have founded a
federal umbrella association of specialists (Spitzenverband Deutscher
Facharzte) in 2008 that competes with both the GAGP and the PAGI. In
contrast to the PAGI, the members of the new umbrella associations only
represent office-based physicians and do not want to include
hospital-based specialists (Arzte Zeitung 7th May 2008).
Generally the policy of cost containment has led to a fragmentation
of physicians' associations. Beside the general fragmentation of
interest one can observe a pluralization of actors and interests. There
are increasing differences between the regions. For example, MEDI and
the GAGP cooperate in some regions while they compete in others. In
Baden-Wuerttemberg, both associations have worked together and jointly
have won a major contract with the local sickness fund. The contract has
included 3,055 practitioners and more than 600,000 insured people up to
July 2009 (Arzte Zeitung 28th July 2009). A similar contract was signed
by MEDI, the GAGP and the Company Health Insurance Fund in
Baden-Wuerttemberg (Arzte Zeitung 23rd June 2009).
At the same time, MEDI face sharp criticism from other physicians.
Though they have not only been able to compete successfully against the
local ASHIP, they also dominate their competitor at the same time. At
the last elections of the assembly of SHI-physicians
(Vertreterversammlung) in Baden-Wurttemberg MEDI only missed very
narrowly a majority on its own. As MEDI cooperates with the GAGP it is
very difficult for their opponents to use the public corporation as a
real alternative against MEDI.
Competition between MEDI and the GAGP is based on different general
goals of both associations within the new system: While MEDI aims at
dismantling the traditional system, the GAGP wants to save and improve
the income of general practitioners. So they disagree when it comes to
the question whether the specialists should be integrated into the
selected contracts with single sickness funds. MEDI needs the support of
specialists to establish itself as a real alternative to the
Associations of Statutory Health Insurance Physicians. Therefore it
wants to use paragraph 73c of the Social Code Book V (special medical
outpatient care) to enlarge the basis of existing contracts that were
only negotiated for general practitioners on the basis of paragraph 73b
(Arzte Zeitung 28th July 2008).
In Bremen, in contrast, the GAGP is negotiating for a single
contract with the local sickness fund on the basis of paragraph 73b
without including any partner (Arzte Zeitung 10th November 2008). The
Berlin GAGP cooperates with several local physicians' associations
(excluding MEDI) and has just agreed upon a 73b-contract (Artze Zeitung
3rd August 2009).
Aside from Baden-Wurttemberg, Bavaria and Rhineland Palatinate are
the main strongholds of the development to build alternatives to the
corporations. In Bavaria, both MEDI and the GAGP have organized a
"Korbmo-dell" to return the approval to the SHI. It turned out
that it was quite difficult to reach the required proportion of 70 per
cent of all doctors of a federal state, a region or a specialist group
(Arzte Zeitung 23rd June 2008). Only if this proportion is achieved can
the supervisory authority decide that the provision of services is no
longer guaranteed by the ASHIP and can transfer the responsibility to
the sickness funds. Obviously, it is very difficult for competitors of
the corporations to win enough direct support even in southern Germany.
Therefore other associations work together with the ASHIP in
Bavaria. In 2008, a special Bavarian coalition was built of the ASHIP,
the Hartmann-bund, the PAGI and some local physicians' networks to
win a contract with the local sickness fund under paragraph 73b (Arzte
Zeitung 24th September 2008).
While in Baden-Wurttemberg MEDI opposes the ASHIP-system, it
cooperates with the ASHIP in Rhineland-Palatinate. As in
Baden-Wurttemberg, MEDI is involved in the guidance of the corporation.
In contrast to the southern neighbors, MEDI in Rhineland-Palatinate only
organizes about 1000 physicians and therefore still lacks the basis for
a confrontation against the ASHIP. Indeed, even in Rhineland-Palatinate
MEDI discusses ways to oppose the ASHIP-system (Arzte-Zeitung of 6th
February 2008).
In the other federal states varying alliances can be observed. In
Hessen the conflict between general practitioners and specialists
dominates the assembly of the ASHIP. At the same time, the assembly
tries to avoid separate contracts of its members with single sickness
funds.
In Lower Saxony, Hartmannbund, the Net Alliance Southern Lower
Saxony (Netzallianz Sudniedersachsen) and the Arztegenossenschaft have
agreed upon joint negotiations with the sickness funds. Even though the
ASHIP is not a member of this group yet, the associations are much more
open to include the corporation into single contracts than in southern
Germany.
Most of the northern and eastern federal states have changing
confederations of associations that usually include the regional ASHIP.
On the federal level, MEDI, the federal association of the
Arztegenossenschaften and the NAV-Virchowbund have built an alliance for
negotiating outpatient care. The National Association of Statutory
Health Insurance Physicians (Kas-senarztliche Bundesvereinigung, NASHIP)
has been hampered by the conflict between general practitioners and
specialists for a long time.
In addition to corporations, old associations and new cooperatives,
the hospitals are about to emerge as players in outpatient care in some
regions. The legal status of hospitals' outpatient care is a very
controversial topic. Some large hospitals refuse participation in single
contracts, while others already have applied for them. So it is quite
difficult to find a general pattern of the new actor constellation in
outpatient care. But the new institutional rules and the rational
interest of the major corporatist actors allow us to formulate
ideal-typical scenarios and to predict their respective policy outcome.
4 Future scenarios of outpatient-governance and their consequences
Originally, the introduction and strengthening of competition in
outpatient care aimed at increasing financeability. Competition was
believed to be an instrument to improve efficiency and thereby contain
health costs. During the process of formulating the SHI-CSI the
financeability and competition have been discussed in separate arenas.
While financeability became a topic of the party leadership, the
strengthening of competition has been negotiated by specialists and
civil servants. In contrast to the party leadership, the specialists
have not primary followed the goal of financeability but are interested
in guaranteeing the quality of health services much more. At the same
time, the specialists of both large parties have agreed that the power
of interest groups has to be reduced. This should apply both for the
power of sickness funds and of health service providers like physicians
(Bandelow/Schade 2008).
The policy outcome of the new system depends crucially on recent
and further decisions by both politics and subsystem actors. Up to now,
there are still a huge number of partly inconsistent patterns in
different regions (Jacobs 2007: 335). Idealtypically, one can
distinguish four possible developments. First the traditional system
with a strong position of regional Associations of Statutory Health
Insurance Physicians could continue to exist. Much more likely is
another development that will lead to a replacement of the old
monopolies of corporations by new monopolies of single associations in
each region. The "third way" is the official goal of plural
competition with several providers working for a better quality of
services. Fourthly, it is possible that the sickness funds focus on
different groups of insured people.
Continuing Dominance of the ASHIP System
There is some evidence that the Associations of Statutory Health
Insurance Physicians will be able to maintain their dominance in spite
of the formal increase of competition: The contract competition still is
restrained by the problem to get uniform guidelines for the payment of
standard benefits in inpatient and outpatient care (Hess 2007: 987). The
legislator admits selective contracts only if exhaustive services are
guaranteed. The ASHIP could remain in some regions as the only suppliers
who can give this guarantee in their contracts. The introduction of
disease management programs (paragraph 137f of Social Code Book V)
strengthened the position of the ASHIP as they used to be the only
competitor to be able to realize an exhaustive registration of patients
(SVR Gesundheit 2005: 34). Besides, it is difficult to persuade
physicians to abandon the ASHIP interest. As discussed above, the
attempt to win enough support against the ASHIP within the general
practitioners in Bavaria has failed up to now.
This first scenario is consistent with a traditional self
conception of the sickness funds. Within this way, the sickness funds
only use single contracts to supplement the supply of the ASHIP. They
would not compete with each other for special services but would avoid
any strategy that restricts the free choice of doctors. So not only the
ASHIP but also the sickness funds would resist significant changes.
New Monopolies
The latest policy decisions in particular have increased the
probability of a general change of actors within the system without a
real change of basic structures. The SHI has already given patients a
general right to register for a primary physician gatekeeper model. So
every sickness fund is forced to find partners for primary physician
contracts. The payment of these contracts is cut from the overall
remuneration for medical services.
The replacement of the monopoly of the ASHIP will not necessarily
enable real competition. There is still the chance that a situation
emerges with only one large association or group of allied associations
that are able to provide exhaustive services in a region.
In an extreme case, the new monopolies would lead to a situation
that strengthened the power of service suppliers ever further than
within the old system. Previously the ASHIP was faced with only a few
associations of sickness funds that were able to cooperate. So the
monopoly on the supply side could have been balanced by the powerful
demand side. The new structures will strengthen the competition between
single sickness funds. The new monopolies could use this situation to
negotiate different services with different sickness funds. They thereby
might negotiate increases of physicians' benefits that have never
been intended by the legislator. If one looks at the latest development
of physicians' income, one can already find some evidence for the
thesis of stronger instead of weaker physicians' associations. They
were able to negotiate an increase of payments for outpatient care in
different regions between 2.5 per cent and 8.6 per cent in 2009. Indeed,
there is no relation between the respective organizational structure of
physicians' associations and the amount of regional increases in
benefits visible so far (Arzte Zeitung 27th October 2008).
Nonetheless, the legislator itself has already paved the way for
the new monopolies. Under pressure from the Bavarian state government,
paragraph 73b of Social Code Book V was changed in 2008. The governing
Bavarian party, the CSU, has followed the pressure of the German
Association of General Practitioners in the run-up to the state
elections to include a new requirement for any association that is
allowed to apply for single contracts under this article. The new
regulation is part of the Act to Develop the Or ganizational Structures
of Sickness Funds (ADOSSF,
GKV-Organisationsstruktur-Weiterentwicklungsgesetz) that passed
Bundestag and Bundesrat in October and November 2008, respectively. So
the artificial monopoly of the GAGP has been backed not only by the CSU
but also by the SPD even though critics belong to nearly all major
parties (Arzte Zeitung 7th July 2009). Up to 30th June 2009, every
sickness fund had to agree on a contract with an association that meets
the requirement. As a requirement, the association has to represent 50
per cent of the general practitioners in the region. Neither
pediatricians nor internists have been included in the definition of
general practitioners. Therefore competitors of the GAGP will have
little chance to participate in this sort of contract.
Within this scenario the sickness funds also face changes. In
contrast to the ASHIP, free associations like the GAGP do not have the
responsibility for guaranteeing provision of services. So the sickness
funds will gain this responsibility. This will increase the pressure on
small sickness funds to merge with larger partners. It is also possible
that regional monopolies of associations develop in partnership with the
local sickness funds. So even within pluralist competition we will have
less than the currently 186 sickness funds in future (Arzte Zeitung 13rd
August 2009)
Pluralist Competition
The third scenario describes the actual policy goal of the
legislator: the establishment of a pluralistic competition around the
highest-quality supply. Health specialists of both large parties still
believe that they could approach this goal by the recent measures.
Public Health experts have a lot of objections against this idea
though. First of all, there is doubt if competition really could lead to
quality. Competition would only produce incentives towards better
quality if the demand side of the market was able to distinguish
different levels of quality (Wille 1999: 131; Hajen/Paetow/Schumacher
2000: 52-53; Lungen/Lauterbach 2007: 292). As patients usually are not
able to evaluate the medical quality of services, competition could
produce opposite incentives. Service suppliers might try to reduce
costs, as this is the only thing everybody could easily overlook
(Rosenbrock/Gerlinger 2006: 243).
Furthermore, there are general problems of competition within the
health sector like the uno actu principle (Herder-Dorneich 1979: 119).
So it is not only unclear if there will be any competition within future
outpatient care but also to which outcome competition might lead.
The role of the traditional corporate bodies within this scenario
remains unclear. It is still legally contested whether the ASHIP is
allowed to apply for contracts on the basis of paragraph 73b in all
regions (Arzte Zeitung 2nd October 2008). Additionally, not all ASHIP
actually want to take part in the new competitive game. While in some
regions--for example in Bavaria--the ASHIP joined a coalition that
applied for a contract, the ASHIP in other regions--like Schleswig
Holstein and North Rhine--even warned that the disadvantages may
actually outweigh the benefits for those who take part in selected
contracts (Arzte Zeitung 22nd August 2008; KVNO 2008). Furthermore there
is an internal problem. The ASHIP being made up of corporate bodies, are
not able to work as independent competitors. They are much more an arena
for the conflict between the different groups than an actor themselves.
Each competitor has the chance not only to compete for better services
than the ASHIP but also to dominate the ASHIP assembly. So if an
association or a group of associations wins a dominant position within a
region it will usually also be able to win a majority of seats within
the ASHIP.
The strategy of the sickness funds will be a customer-oriented one
in which the insured can be persuaded that they will gain a better
service, prices and/or quality by single contracts. Up to now, single
contracts still lack quality gains as aimed by the legislator. Pluralist
competition will only be successful if sickness funds find strategies to
win new policy holders by promising better quality because of single
contracts. For example they could promise shorter waiting periods or
offer special checkups for their members. Single funds have already
promised to follow this strategy (Arzte Zeitung 28th July 2009).
Like the others scenarios, pluralist competition will be
accompanied by a further reduction of sickness funds. But there will be
several funds with different quality strategies in each region. The risk
remains that we will face the development of more expensive funds
offering better quality on the one hand (competing with the private
health insurance). On the other hand there might be insurance funds for
people who cannot offer additional contributions and get worse treatment
than today.
Fragmentation by Specialization of Sickness Funds
The fourth ideal typical scenario is based on a possible
development of the strategies of the sickness funds. Opposite to the
other scenarios, it does not start with a possible development within
the organizational structure of physicians' associations. On the
contrary, it looks at the demand side of outpatient care.
The new system could lead to incentives for sickness funds to
specialize on specific groups of insured people and patients. This would
have significant effects on the whole system. The sickness funds could
develop political strategies instead of economic strategies to improve
their respective competitiveness. The framework for this sort of
strategies is provided by the new morbidity related risk adjustment
scheme (morbiditatsorientierter Risiko strukturausgleich). Sickness
funds that have a high proportion of insured members with a specific
illness would profit if this illness is factored in the compensation
scheme. So they might use political influence instead of strategies to
improve quality.
There has already been such a strategy of sickness funds when the
list of 80 diseases to be listed in the scheme was decided. The local
sickness funds were able to formulate a coalition with the Barmer
Ersatzkasse which is the largest substitute fund. The Barmer mirrors the
insured structure of the local sickness funds with a delay of about
three years. Therefore they have similar interest structures and have
been successful in changing the original approach of the scientific
advisory council of the federal insurance office (interview federal peak
association of sickness funds).
For the supply side, this scenario is a special case of pluralist
competition. Specialists' associations might cooperate with special
sickness funds, but they will not have a monopoly as they lack the legal
protection that has been described in the second scenario.
Evaluation
The different scenarios have been introduced as ideal types and the
future development will be characterised by elements of several or all
types at the same time. In addition regional differences are also
possible. The legislator will have decisive influence which of these
types will gain most weight (Schmidt 2009: 32). Legislation can decide
on the overall remuneration for medical services, on hurdles to join the
market for private providers and on the risk adjustment scheme and
thereby frame the competition.
All scenarios have waived the special relationship between the SHI
and the private insurance companies. The grand coalition left this
problem for its successors. Private insurance companies could actually
influence the future of the SHI if they were completely or at least
partly integrated into the system.
5. Outlook
The traditional corporatist system of German outpatient care was
characterized by the sectoral negotiations of corporate bodies and the
dominance of office-based physicians over the bargaining power of
sickness funds. Until the cap of the remuneration for medical services
in 1993, the corporate bodies had the control over services and payment
for the whole outpatient care. Quality was only assured by hierarchical
governance that was not directly included in the most powerful arenas of
the system. The latest reforms and in particular the SHI-CSI contribute
to a general change of this system.
Originally, the political measures were motivated by the aim to
improve financeability and to cut expenses. The employers'
contributions in particular should have been limited to improve
international competitiveness of the German industry. Since the late
1990s this goal has been supplemented with rising efforts to ensure
quality of health services.
Both the idea of financeability and the aim to guarantee quality
should be reached by increasing competition within the system. Even
though, the political decisions have not been able to guarantee
competition yet. While the grand coalition was not able to agree upon
major changes toward a sustainable financial system the small changes of
structural rules have already lead to major changes of actors and
constellations and are about to create one giant leap for the policy
outcome.
There are different developments of governance patterns and actor
constellations within the regions. On the basis of the present
developments four ideal typical scenarios have been distinguished to
describe the possible future of outpatient health governance.
Up to now the beneficiaries of the reform are actors that belonged
to the weakest groups of the traditional systems: local sickness funds,
general practitioners and their largest association (GAGP), health
service providers in eastern Germany and even some consumer groups
profited from the reforms introduced by the social democratic health
minister Ulla Schmidt. The traditional physicians' associations
were originally completely opposed to the political measures. The
previous system of regional collective negotiations guaranteed a
formally free choice of doctors within the SHI system. This freedom of
choice was one of the most important demands of physicians'
associations (Naschold 1967). The latest reforms depart from the idea of
freedom of patient choice. Officially it is aimed at replacing it with
more freedom for those insured and associations' contract choice
(Le Grand 2003), but up to now it is unclear who will have more choices
in the future.
Nonetheless, some new cooperatives and even traditional
physicians' associations have already taken part in the new
governance strategy. They have discovered the new system as a way to
ensure higher income for the participating groups. Up to now, especially
actors with close links to governing parties can use the new system for
their own interests. For example the local sickness funds used their
traditional partnership with the SPD, while the general practitioners in
Bavaria have been successful in exploiting their relations with the CSU
for their own interests.
Even though the latest act, the ADOSSF of 2008, already entails
some major decisions, some elements concerning the future still remain
open. Paragraph 73b of Social Code Book V in particular has been
criticized by many interest groups and academic observers. In contrast
to paragraph 73c, it might have privileged single associations in a way
that is not legitimized by the goals of financeability and quality
(Cassel 2008). As both major articles seem to follow different beliefs
one has to expect that the legislator will at least change one of them
again soon. It is even possible that changes will be forced by a legal
judgment as the association of internists (PAGI) has already decided to
sue for a change in the paragraph 73b (Arzte Zeitung 3rd November 2008).
However future party politics decide these questions, the most
interesting lesson is that minor reform compromises are about to lead to
major changes of the subsystem. The causation between the belief systems
of legislators and the final policy outcome can not only be indirect but
also different from any impression gained by focusing only on policy
output. Policy analysts therefore should differentiate their theoretical
lenses by clarifying whether they aim to explain output, impact, or
outcome.
References
Altenstetter, Christa/Busse, Reinhard, 2005: Health Care Reform in
Germany: Patchwork Change within Established Governance Structures, in:
Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 30/1-2, 121-142.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 6th February 2008: Geteiltes Echo
auf BKK-Hausarztevertrag.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 7th May 2008: Neuer Dachverband soll
Facharzte besser vertreten.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 23rd June 2008: Hausarztverein
Nurnberg halt Korbmodell fur passe.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 1st July 2008: Neuer Verband soll
Vertrage nach 73b aushandeln.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 28th July 2008: Facharzte drangen
auf Son-dervertrage nach [section] 73 c.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 22nd August 2008: Kollateralschaden
durch Hausarztvertrag?
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 22nd September 2008: Arztegenossen
setzen auf Vertrage mit den Kassen.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 24th September 2008:
Anbieterkoalition fur AOK-Hausarztvertrag.
Arzte Zeitung (online verions) 2nd October 2008: Bayerns
Hausarztever-band bestreitet der KV die Vertragskompetenz fur [section]
73b.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 27th October 2008: Aufatmen in
Nordrhein, Zahneknirschen im Sudwesten.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 30th October 2008: Immer mehr
medizini-sche Versorgungszentren.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 3rd November 2008: BDI-Spitze: Gang
vor den Kadi beschlossene Sache.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 10th November 2008: Bremer Hausarzte
streben AOK-Vertrag an.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 12th November 2008: Fur IV-Vertrage
schlagt die Stunde der Wahrheit.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 23rd June 2009: Hausarztvertrag mit
Be-triebskrankenkassen im Sudwesten ist unter Dach und Fach.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 7th July 2009: Monopol des
Hausarztever-bandes missfallt Gesundheitspolitikern.
Arzte Zeitung (only version) 28th July 2009: Selektivvertrage als
Motor der Versorgung.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 28th July 2009: Sudwest-AOK setzt
auf vita-len Hausarzte-Vertrag.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 3rd August 2009: Bei Berliner
Hausarzten steht der Sudwesten Pate.
Arzte Zeitung (online version) 13rd August 2009: Da waren es nur
noch 186--Kassen im Fusionsfieber.
Bandelow, Nils C., 1998: Gesundheitspolitik: Der Staat in der Hand
einzel-ner Interessengruppen? Opladen: Leske + Budrich.
Bandelow, Nils C./Schade, Mathieu 2008: Die Gesundheitsreform der
Gro-ben Koalition: Strategische Erfolge im Schatten des Scheiterns, in:
Fischer, Thomas/Kiebling, Andreas/Novy, Leonard (Hrsg.): Politische
Reformprozesse in der Analyse: Untersuchungssystematik und
Fallbei-spiele. Gutersloh: Bertelsmann, 85-144.
Bandelow, Nils C./Schade, Mathieu 2009: Konsens im Dissens?
Parteipoli-tische Konflikte in der Gesundheitsreform der Groben
Koalition, in: Paquet, Robert/Schroder, Wolfgang (Hrsg.):
Gesundheitsreform 2007: Nach der Reform ist vor der Reform. Wiesbaden:
VS Verlag fur Sozi-alwissenschaften, 58-76.
Bockmann, Roman, 2007: Von der Selbstverwaltung zum regulierten
Gesundheitsmarkt. PoliThesis. Diskussionspapiere des Instituts fur
Po-litikwissenschaft und der Graduate School of Politics (GraSP).
Muns-ter: Westfalische Wilhelms-Universitat.
Cassel, Dieter et al., 2008: Vertragswettbewerb in der GKV.
Moglichkeiten und Grenzen vor und nach der Gesundheitsreform der Groben
Koaliti-on. Bonn: BdO.
Dohler, Marian, 2003: Gesundheitspolitik in der
Verhandlungsdemokratie, in: Gellner, Winand/Schon, Markus (Hrsg.):
Paradigmenwechsel in der Gesundheitspolitik?. Baden-Baden: Nomos. 25-40.
Gerlinger, 2008: Health Care Reform in Germany, in: German Policy
Studies. Special Issue ?From Bismarck to Conservative Universalism? The
Politics, Problems, and Prospects of the German Welfare State" (to
be published).
Green, Simon/Paterson, William E., 2009: Last Orders?
Semisovereignty and the Crisis of Cost Containment in the Grand
Coalition, in: Mi-skimmon, Alister/Paterson, William E./Sloam, James
(eds.): Germany's Gathering Crisis: The 2005 Federal Election and
the Grand Coalition. Basingstoke: Palgrave (to be published).
Hajen, Leonhard/Paetow, Holger/Schumacher, Harald 2000:
Gesund-heitsokonomie. Strukturen--Methoden--Praxisbeispiele.
Stutt-gart/Berlin/Koln: Verlag W. Kohlhammer.
Hassenteufel, Patrick/Palier, Bruno, 2007: Towards Neo-Bismarckian
Health Care States? Comparing Health Insurance Reforms in Bis-marckian
Welfare Systems, in: Social Policy & Administration, 41/6, 574-596.
Hegelich, Simon/Meyer, Hendrik, 2008: Konflikt, Verhandlung,
Sozialer Friede: Das deutsche Wohlfahrtssystem, in: Schubert,
Klaus/Hegelich, Simon/Bazant, Ursula (Hrsg.): Europaische
Wohlfahrtssysteme. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag, 127-148.
Herder-Dorneich, Philipp, 1979: Soziale Ordnungspolitik. Mit neuen
Stra-tegien gegen Steuerungsdefizite. Stuttgart: Verlag Bonn Aktuell.
Hess, Rainer, 2007: Der Stellenwert der gemeinsamen
Selbstverwaltung au Bundesebene nach dem GKV-WSG, in: Ulrich,
Volker/Ried, Walter (Hrsg.): Effizienz. Qualitat und Nachhaltigkeit im
Gesundheitswesen. Festschrift zum 65. Geburtstag von Eberhard Wille.
Baden-Baden: Nomos, 985-993.
Jacobs, Klaus, 2007: Alles blob Etikettenschwindel? Der kunftige
Kassen-wettbewerb nach der Gesundheitsreform der Groben Koalition, in:
Ulrich, Volker/Ried, Walter (Hrsg.): Effizienz. Qualitat und
Nachhaltig-keit im Gesundheitswesen. Festschrift zum 65. Geburtstag von
Eber-hard Wille. Baden-Baden: Nomos, 325-341.
KVNO 2008: Kassenarztliche Vereinigung Nordrhein: Selektiv-Vertrage
vereinzeln den Arzt und bedrohen das Arzt-Patienten-Verhaltnis, in: KVNO
aktuell online, Ausgabe April 2008.
Le Grand, Julian, 2003: Motivation, Agency, and Public Policy. Of
Knights and Knaves, Pawns and Queens. Oxford: Oxford UP.
Lehmbruch, Gerhard, 1988: Der Neokorporatismus der Bundesrepublik
im internationalen Vergleich und die ?Konzertierte Aktion im
Gesund-heitswesen", in: Gafgen, Gerard (Hrsg.): Neokorporatismus
und Gesundheitswesen. Baden-Baden: Nomos, 11-32.
Lungen, Markus/Lauterbach, Karl W., 2007: Wettbewerb im
Gesundheits-wesen, in: Ulrich, Volker/Ried, Walter (Hrsg.): Effizienz.
Qualitat und Nachhaltigkeit im Gesundheitswesen. Festschrift zum 65.
Geburtstag von Eberhard Wille. Baden-Baden: Nomos, 279-293.
Naschold, Frieder, 1967: Kassenarzte und
Krankenversicherungspflicht. Zu einer Theorie der Statuspolitik.
Freiburg: Rombach.
Richter, Wolfram R., 2005: Gesundheitspramie oder
Burgerversicherung? Ein Kompromissvorschlag, in: Wirtschaftsdienst
85/11, 693-697.
Rosenbrock, Rolf/Gerlinger, Thomas, 2006: Gesundheitspolitik. Eine
sys-tematische Einfuhrung. Bern: Verlag Hans Huber.
Rubsam-Simon, Ekkehard, 2005: "Es ist Krieg?. Der
gesundheitspolitische Kommentar.
www.buschtelefon.de/artikel/1132606918t65.pdf [visited 05.02.2008]
Sachverstandigenrat zur Begutachtung der Entwicklung im
Gesundheitswe-sen [SVR Gesundheit], 2005: Koordination und Qualitat im
Gesund-heitswesen. Jahresgutachten 2005. Bundestagsdrucksache 15/5670.
http://dip.bundestag.de/btd/15/056/1505670.pdf. [visited 05.02.2008]
Scharpf, Fritz W., 1997: Games real actors play: Actor-centered
institution-alism in policy research. Boulder: Westview.
Schmidt, Ulla, 2009: Gesundheitspolitik im Widerschein der
Interessen--Ein Ruck-und Ausblick, in: Bandelow, Nils C./Eckert,
Flo-rian/Rusenberg, Robin (eds.): Gesundheit 2030-Qualitatsorientierung
im Fokus von Politik, Wirtschaft, Selbstverwaltung und Wissenschaft.
Wiesbaden: VS Verlag fur Sozialwissenschaften, 29-33.
Wiesenthal, Helmut, 1981: Die Konzertierte Aktion im
Gesundheitswesen. Ein Beispiel fur Theorie und Politik des modernen
Korporatismus. Frankfrut a. M./New York: Campus.
Wille, Eberhard, 1999: Auswirkungen des Wettbewerbs auf die
gesetzliche Krankenversicherung, in: Wille, Eberhard (Hrsg.): Zur Rolle
des Wett-bewerbs in der gesetzlichen Rentenversicherung. Baden-Baden:
No-mos, 95-156.
(1) I am grateful to Markus Grunenberg, the special issue editors,
and the reviewers for helpful comments and suggestions.
Nils C. Bandelow University of Braunschweig (Germany)