CRA and fair lending regulations: resulting trends in mortgage lending.
Evanoff, Douglas D. ; Segal, Lewis M.
In response to concerns that banks were not adequately serving the
credit needs of their local communities and not treating all applicants
fairly, during the 1960s and 1970s Congress passed the fair lending laws
and the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA).(1) These laws, aimed at
eliminating discriminatory lending practices and encouraging lending to
low-income individuals and in low-income areas, have been controversial
since their inception. Community advocates argued that the acts were
either inadequate or inadequately enforced and that banks continued to
channel deposits away from local communities, resulting in inadequate
financing for the areas most in need. Bankers argued that they treated
applicants fairly and the acts smacked of credit allocation that could
adversely affect bank safety and soundness.
Although there continues to be significant disagreement regarding
these regulations, recently there has been a wave of positive reviews of
their effectiveness.(2) The regulations have been given credit for
encouraging banks to implement special loan programs aimed at
lower-income communities and for effectively channeling funds toward
previously underserved areas and minority groups. Community advocates
argue that significant progress has been made and continued enforcement
will reap additional benefits. Some bankers state that in responding to
the CRA they have discovered new, profitable, previously untapped
lending opportunities. These opportunities have come at a most
convenient time as the demand in traditional lending markets has slowed.
While the arguments for the fair lending laws and the CRA are
essentially ones of equity, there may also be economic arguments for
constraining private market behavior and channeling funds to underserved
areas. It may be that these credit flows produce positive externalities which, from a societal perspective, generate a total return greater than
that received by the providers of the credit.(3) That is, although
society reaps the full benefits of providing this credit, the service
provider (a bank in this case) may not. While this provides economic
justification for channeling credit to particular markets, it does not
necessarily warrant doing so through the banking system.
In this article, we examine the evolution of the fair lending
regulations and the CRA. We then summarize the economic literature that
pertains to these regulations. Finally, we evaluate the effectiveness of
the fair lending laws and the CRA by analyzing recent trends in mortgage
lending activity and discussing whether these trends are in line with
the intent of the regulations. We ask whether the trends can be
attributed to the regulations and whether the data suggest that the
regulations have been successful.
Evolution of the CRA and the fair lending laws
Although it is common to group together the Fair Housing Act, the
Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA), and the CRA, they are more
accurately classified into two groups: the fair lending laws and the
CRA. The fair lending laws are aimed at eliminating lending
discrimination based on the inherent attributes of the borrower, such as
race or gender. The CRA primarily addresses geographic discrimination,
that is, failing to serve the credit needs of the local community in
which the bank was chartered. The Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA)
provides information on lending to individuals and locations, supporting
the enforcement of both the fair lending laws and the CRA.
Fair lending laws
The Fair Housing Act was approved by Congress in 1968 as part of the
Civil Rights Act of that year. It prohibits discrimination in
residential real estate transactions based on race or color, religion,
national origin, gender, handicap, or family status.(4) The ECOA
encompasses a broader array of transactions. Passed in 1974, it
prohibits discrimination with regard to any aspect of a credit
transaction (consumer, commercial, or real estate loan) based on race or
color, religion, ethnic origin, gender, marital status, age, and receipt
of public assistance.(5)
It has been argued that fair lending enforcement prior to the 1990s
was generally unaggressive.(6) The techniques employed to detect
discrimination (reviewing whether internal policies were followed and
performed uniformly across the protected factors) typically detected
only the most blatant cases of discrimination. Since that time, in
response to growing public concern about lending discrimination and
well-publicized research that reported evidence of discrimination,
regulatory agencies and the U.S. Department of Justice have stepped up
their enforcement efforts. For example, a 1988 study of mortgage
discrimination in Atlanta led the Justice Department to initiate an
investigation into fair lending practices by depositories in that
market.(7) The investigation resulted in the first major lawsuit filed
by the department against an institution for violating fair lending
laws.(8) This is in sharp contrast to the number of suits filed for
civil rights violations in other areas, for example, housing and
employment. Congress also responded to repeated claims of lending
discrimination by amending the Fair Housing Act in 1988 to allow private
parties to originate mortgage discrimination lawsuits more easily. The
ECOA was amended in 1991 to require bank regulators to refer cases to
the Department of Justice instead of handling them independently,
sending a signal that the department was going to be more aggressive in
the prosecution of such cases. Perhaps most significantly, the 1975 HMDA
was amended in 1988, 1989, and 1991 to develop a database that would
provide regulators and the public with data to analyze depository
institution lending patterns.
As originally enacted, HMDA required depository institutions and
their subsidiaries to provide the total number and dollar value of
mortgages originated and purchased in the local market, typically
segmented by census tract. The 1989 amendment required lenders to report
information at the loan application level regarding race, gender, and
income, along with details on the disposition of the application
(deny/accept/withdraw, reason for denial, etc.).(9) Banks were required
to make the data publicly available. These expanded data have enabled
regulators to complement their manual reviews of loan files with
systematic statistical analysis.(10) The additional data also allow the
public to more closely scrutinize lending patterns of depository
institutions.
There have also been recent efforts by bank regulators to help
depository institutions comply with fair lending regulation by
clarifying the compliance requirements. While the purpose of fair
lending laws and regulations is relatively straightforward, there have
been problems in implementation, and disagreements have arisen between
regulatory agencies and lenders as to interpretations of the law. To
provide guidance, a 1994 interagency task force representing the federal
depository regulators released guidelines as to what could constitute
discriminatory lending practices.(11) Under these fair lending
guidelines, a lender may not, because of a prohibited factor:
* Fail to provide information or services or provide different
information or services regarding any aspect of the lending process,
including credit availability, application procedures, or lending
standards;
* Discourage or selectively encourage applicants with respect to
inquiries about or applications for credit;
* Refuse to extend credit or use different standards in determining
whether to extend credit;
* Vary the terms of credit offered, including the amount, interest
rate, duration, or type of loan;
* Use different standards to evaluate collateral;
* Treat a borrower differently in servicing a loan or invoking
default remedies;
* Use different standards for pooling or packaging a loan in the
secondary market;
* Express, orally or in writing, a preference based on these
prohibited factors, or indicate that it will treat applicants
differently based on these factors; or
* Discriminate because of the characteristics of a person
associated with a credit applicant or the prospective occupants of the
area where property to be financed is located.(12)
While blatant discrimination may be obvious to most parties, there
are times when sound business practices may result in an unintended
discriminatory practice against a protected group. To emphasize to
lenders the need to avoid unintended effects in setting underwriting criteria, the interagency task force also listed the forms of
discrimination that the courts had previously recognized as illegal.
These include: overt discrimination - the lender openly discriminates;
disparate treatment - the lender treats applicants differently based on
one of the prohibited factors (whether or not it is motivated by
prejudice or intent to discriminate); and disparate impact - the lender
applies a practice uniformly to all applicants, but the practice has a
discriminatory effect and cannot be justified by business necessity.
As a result of the increased scrutiny of lending practices by
regulators, there has been a significant increase in the number of ECOA
violations referred to the Department of Justice by the regulatory
agencies and in the number of suits filed by the department for
violation of the fair lending laws. Most of the suits have been settled
through well-publicized consent agreements, which relayed the message of
stringent enforcement of the fair lending laws. In evaluating the effect
of the fair lending laws on mortgage activity, therefore, one would
expect to see more of an impact on lending patterns in the 1990s, as
institutions respond to increased regulatory pressure.(13)
The CRA
The major impetus for the 1977 passage of the CRA was concern by
community groups that banks and thrifts were not responding adequately
to the credit needs of local communities. Depository institutions were
accused of discriminating against individuals based on the
characteristics of their neighborhood, that is, redlining. This was seen
as having a particularly adverse impact on minority groups and
contributing to the deterioration of inner-city neighborhoods. However,
the emphasis of the act was on adequately preserving communities and not
on channeling credit based on race. Community groups argued that it was
common for banks to reinvest a relatively small portion of deposits
generated from local communities back into those markets.(14)
The initial community reinvestment bill was much more intrusive to
banks than the final act. The initial proposal argued that banks were
chartered institutions with access to a government safety net and, as
such, had a formal responsibility to perform social functions in
addition to pursuing the objectives of a private enterprise. The
proposal defined the bank's relevant local market from which it
received deposits and required it to focus on satisfying credit demands
in this market prior to exporting funds to other areas. Banks argued
that such behavior would run counter to existing safety and soundness
regulation and constituted overt credit allocation without regard to the
credit quality of applicants in different geographic areas.
The final act omitted the explicit credit allocation criteria. It
required financial institutions to serve the convenience and needs of
the communities in which they were chartered without mandating how this
was to be accomplished. Additionally, it emphasized the need for bank
management to be conscious of community credit needs and stressed that
this was to be done without sacrificing safety and soundness.
The mandate of the CRA, to have institutions serve the needs of the
community in which they are chartered, was actually already in place.
The 1935 Banking Act required banks to meet the convenience and needs of
their communities, as did the 1956 Bank Holding Company Act and the bank
charter itself. The fair lending laws, while not explicitly outlawing
redlining, addressed similar concerns. Finally, while HMDA provided no
mechanism for imposing sanctions on depository institutions, the data
were being collected precisely for the purpose of monitoring lending
patterns and detecting neighborhood redlining. The real thrust of the
CRA was to reemphasize the need for good lending practices, to shift the
emphasis on reinvestment away from the liability side of the balance
sheet (deposit gathering) to the asset side (credit generation), and to
put the onus squarely upon regulators to monitor the lending patterns of
financial institutions and encourage investment in local communities.
In the early years of the CRA, regulatory agencies required banks to
specify their local community; develop a public statement, including the
local community definition and listing the type of credit instruments
the bank intended to provide; post a list of consumer rights under the
CRA; and maintain a file of public comments for public inspection. These
procedural requirements were relatively straightforward. In addition,
regulators performed an evaluation to "assess the
institution's record of meeting the credit needs of the entire
community, including low- and moderate-income neighborhoods, consistent
with the safe and sound operation of each institution" (Regulation
BB).
To assess the institution's performance in satisfying this
requirement, the regulators developed 12 assessment factors grouped into
five performance categories:(15)
Category A: Ascertainment of community credit needs
1. Communication with members of the community to ascertain credit
needs; and
2. Extent of involvement by the board of directors in the CRA
activities.
Category B: Marketing and types of credit offered and extended
3. Marketing efforts to make the types of credit offered known in the
community;
4. The extent of loans originated in the community; and
5. The extent of participation in government loan programs.
Category C: Geographic distribution and record of opening and closing
offices
6. The geographic distribution of credit applications, approvals, and
denials; and
7. The record of office openings and closings and extent of service
provided at the offices.
Category D: Discrimination and other illegal credit practices
8. Practices to discourage credit applications; and
9. Discriminatory or other illegal practices.
Category E: Community development
10. Participation in community development projects or programs;
11. The institution's ability to meet community credit needs;
and
12. Other relevant factors which could bear upon the extent to which
the institution is helping to meet the credit needs of the community.
For each of the assessment factors, the examiner was to assign a
grade of 1 (exceptional) to 5 (significantly inferior), similar to the
CAMEL rating given for safety and soundness evaluation. Later, to avoid
confusion with safety and soundness ratings, the CRA rating was changed
to a four scale grading system: outstanding, satisfactory, needs to
improve, or substantial noncompliance.
The regulations did not impose explicit sanctions on institutions
found not to have adequately served the needs of their communities.
Instead, the regulator was to consider the CRA rating along with other
factors, such as safety and soundness, when ruling on an application for
a geographic expansion of facilities through a merger or acquisition,
the introduction of new branches, an office change, etc. However, there
are additional costs from having a poor CRA rating or being accused of
poor CRA performance, even if the application is ultimately approved.
For example, the application process can be significantly lengthened and
complicated if community groups protest the application. In a period in
which banks were aggressively expanding geographically, the potential
for lost deals, delays in expansion, and negative public relations could
be quite burdensome.
Following passage of the act, bankers frequently complained about the
vagueness of the requirements, including the lack of a specific ranking
or weighting scheme for the assessment factors to guide the allocation
of resources. Regulatory agencies would periodically issue policy
statements providing guidance to institutions as to how the assessment
criteria were scored and discussing elements of effective CRA programs.
Most of these statements emphasized effort, and the documentation of
such effort, instead of performance. In the late 1980s, Congress amended
the act to have the assessments made public and increased public
scrutiny of banks and regulators.
As with the fair lending laws, enforcement of the CRA intensified in
the early 1990s. Denials of merger or acquisition applications based on
poor CRA performance became more common. Although the ratings were not
made public prior to 1990, evidence suggests that regulators have
tightened enforcement and have been more strict in assigning CRA
ratings.(16) To stress the commitment to low-income financing, Congress
passed the Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and Soundness
Act in 1991. This act put the Federal National Mortgage Association and
the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation under an affirmative
obligation to facilitate financing of low- and moderate-income housing.
It also established mortgage purchasing goals for these agencies
relating to low- and moderate-income families for affordable housing and
for the central city. Bankers continued to complain about the vagueness
of CRA requirements and the resulting regulatory burden. Community
groups continued to complain that banks were inadequately serving the
credit needs of their local communities and that regulators were
inadequately enforcing the act.
TABLE 1
CRA test ratings
Component test ratings are assigned to reflect the bank's lending,
investment, and services.
Component
test ratings Lending Investment Service
Outstanding 12 6 6
High satisfactory 9 4 4
Low satisfactory 6 3 3
Needs to improve 3 1 1
Substantial
noncompliance 0 0 0
Preliminary composite rating is assigned by summing the three
component test ratings and referring to the chart below.
Points Composite assigned rating
20 + Outstanding
11-19 Satisfactory
5-10 Needs to improve
0-4 Substantial noncompliance
Note: Adjustments to preliminary composite rating - no bank may
receive a composite assigned rating of satisfactory or higher
unless it receives at least low satisfactory on the lending test.
After much public and congressional debate, new CRA regulations were
issued in 1995 for implementation over the following two years. The new
regulations stressed performance over effort in meeting CRA requirements
and introduced a new evaluation system, replacing the previous 12
assessment factors with three new tests: lending, investment, and
service. For each test a bank is assigned one of five grades from
outstanding to substantial noncompliance. There is also an overall
composite rating for CRA compliance.(17)
The lending test evaluates whether a bank has a record of meeting the
credit needs of its local community. The regulator evaluates the number,
amount, and distribution across income groups and geographic areas of
mortgage, small business, small farm, and consumer loans in the
assessment area(s) or communities.(18) The regulator also considers the
innovativeness of the bank in addressing the credit needs of low- or
moderate-income individuals or areas and in generating community
development loans. As illustrated in table 1, the lending test carries a
disproportional weight in determining the composite rating. A bank
cannot receive a composite rating of satisfactory or better unless it
receives a minimum of low satisfactory on the lending test.(19)
The investment test evaluates how well a bank satisfies the credit
needs of its local neighborhoods through qualified community investments
that benefit the assessment area. Again, the bank's innovativeness
in responding to community development needs is also taken into account.
Finally, the service test evaluates how well the credit needs of the
community are met by the bank's retail service delivery systems.
This includes the distribution of branches across areas serving low- to
moderate-income individuals and geographies, as well as alternative
delivery systems, such as ATM, telephone, computer, and mail. The
delivery systems and services should be directed at meeting the needs of
the local community, for example, low-balance checking accounts and
extended lobby hours. Again, the innovativeness of the bank in using
these alternative delivery systems to serve the low- and moderate-income
individuals and neighborhoods within the community is taken into
consideration.
Although it is too early to determine the effectiveness of the
revisions to the CRA, a recent Government Accounting Office review of
the new guidelines argued that regulators may face significant
challenges in implementing the reforms.(20) The potential problems are
similar to those which existed before the reforms, namely:
* A continued need for excessive documentation of effort and
process;
* Inconsistency in ratings and uncertainty about the performance
criteria;
* Incomplete consideration of all relevant material in determining
the performance of the institution; and
* Dissatisfaction with regulatory enforcement (depending on
one's perspective, too stringent or too lax).
To minimize potential problems, the report recommended that
significant efforts be made to provide improved examiner training,
improve the quality of the data used in evaluating performance, and
increase the use of public disclosure of the ratings.
Evidence of discrimination in mortgage lending
The CRA was introduced because redlining was believed to be a common
practice by banks. The fair lending laws were passed because there was a
perception that certain borrowing groups were not being treated
equitably. However, there continues to be significant disagreement as to
the extent of these problems.
Housing and mortgage discrimination has been a topical issue since
the 1960s, when community groups argued that neighborhoods were
deteriorating as a result of practices by mortgage originators. The
originators were accused of using noneconomic criteria to limit funding
to non-white applicants and/or nonwhite neighborhoods. Research in this
area has intensified in recent years as amendments to HMDA reporting
requirements have increased the availability of data used to compare
lending patterns across race and ethnic groups, income groups, and
geographic areas. However the data exclude many of the more relevant
variables used in the credit evaluation process.(21) The most meaningful
studies of the role of race and neighborhood effects in mortgage lending
incorporate information beyond HMDA data and evaluate discrimination
based either on the neighborhood of the applicant or the characteristics
of the individual applicant. These studies are divided into four
classes: neighborhood redlining studies, application accept/reject
studies, studies of default rates, and performance of institutions
specializing in loans to low-income individuals or in low-income
neighborhoods. Below, we summarize the studies to emphasize the ongoing
controversies in this area of research.
Redlining studies
Redlining is the practice of having the loan decision based on, or
significantly influenced by, the location of the property without
appropriate regard for the qualifications of the applicant or the value
of the property. As a result, the neighborhood's financial needs
are not adequately served and the region is unable to develop
economically. Redlining studies typically take the neighborhood as the
unit of observation, evaluating whether the aggregate supply of funds
made available is related to the racial composition of the area.
Early analysis of differences in loan originations across markets
found significant differences based on the racial composition of the
neighborhood. However, these studies attributed all market differences
to the race variable.(22) The findings from a number of recent studies,
which either directly or indirectly addressed the redlining issue and
attempted to explicitly account for market differences, are summarized
in box A.
Although improvements have been made in redlining studies, inherent
methodological problems remain. First, in a number of redlining studies
the unit of observation may be too large. To the extent redlining
occurs, it could be for a relatively small area, such as two or three
city blocks. In larger areas, such as metropolitan statistical areas
(MSA), redlining may not be detectable in the aggregate data.
Additionally, assuming some lenders redline and others do not, if
borrowers eventually find the non-redlining lender, data at the broader
level will imply that no redlining has occurred. The unit of observation
should, therefore, be relatively small. There may also be a significant
omitted variable bias. Exclusion of variables correlated with race may
produce a significant coefficient for race even in the absence of
discrimination. A standard criticism of redlining studies is that they
inadequately account for demand factors. Thus, it is impossible to
attribute differences in mortgage activity across markets to an
inadequate supply of funding (redlining) or to a lower demand from
potential borrowers. The creditworthiness of the applicant pool is also
important since the riskiness of the loan will obviously be a
determining factor in the underwriting decision. Additional variables to
account for differences in borrower credit demand and creditworthiness
that have been included in the recent studies are neighborhood average
income, percent of owner-occupied houses, changes in property values,
poverty and welfare rates, percent of housing units vacant, crime rates,
wealth measures, mobility rates, average age of population and housing
stock, total housing units, duration of residency, and the stock of
conventional mortgages.
Typically, studies that have accounted for these market
characteristics more comprehensively have reported a less significant
impact of racial composition than that found in earlier studies. For
example, when Holmes and Horvitz (1994) excluded measures of risk in
their analysis of the Houston market, they found that the flow of
mortgage credit was negatively associated with minority status,
consistent with redlining. When the risk measure was included, minority
status was not found to influence the flow of credit.(23) Studies which
employ a single-equation model to explain the amount of credit made
available in a neighborhood will be mixing elements of both supply and
demand for credit. Redlining will affect the supply loans. However, with
the single-equation approach the supply and demand effects cannot be
separated (Yezer, Phillips, and Trost, 1994), Arguing that the race
variable represents discrimination requires that there be no demand-side
effects. As mentioned above, a number of studies have shown this to be
incorrect. Finally, model specification has been shown to drive some
results (Home, 1997). Concern with model specification argues that one
should use a relatively flexible financial form which has the more
commonly used alternative forms nested within it.
Some researchers have argued that the problems associated with the
above credit flow type of redlining studies are too large to overcome
and, as a result, these studies cannot adequately identify the role of
racial composition of the neighborhood in loan decisions. An alternative
approach, which addresses the problem of individuals eventually finding
the non-redlining lender, is to directly survey individuals who were
active in the mortgage market. Benston and Horsky (1992, 1979) surveyed
home sellers and buyers to gather information on credit difficulties
encountered in attempting to sell or purchase homes in several U.S.
cities. Instead of viewing only the mortgages approved, the survey
gathered information on individuals who requested credit but were unable
to obtain it (for reasons such as redlining), in areas in which charges
of redlining had been made and in control areas. If obtaining credit was
a problem, additional information as to the reason for the problem was
obtained - for example, unemployment, inadequate down payment, or
location of the house. The survey explicitly asked home buyers if either
a lending institution or real estate agent had stated or implied that
obtaining a mortgage might be difficult because of the neighborhood in
which the home was located. In both studies, the authors were unable to
detect evidence of discrimination or unmet demand. The bottom line
appears to be that there is little convincing evidence to suggest that
redlining explains lending patterns in low-income neighborhoods.
Accept/Reject studies
Given the above criticisms of credit flow studies, the availability
of more detailed HMDA data since 1990, and a desire to more directly
address the discrimination issue, recent research has taken a more
microeconomic approach. Accept/reject studies take individual
application data and evaluate the determinants of the lender's
decision. They estimate a probability of rejection function based on
various risk factors and include a race variable to account for
discrimination.(24) While these studies can also be used to test for
redlining, their focus is on discrimination with respect to individual
applicants. (For a sample of these studies, see box B.)
Prior to the availability of HMDA data, Black et al. (1978) used
special survey data to determine the economic variables important to the
lending decision and whether personal variables such as race played a
role. After accounting for economic variables and terms of the loans,
they found that, although the personal characteristics did not
significantly add to the power of their model in explaining the
accept/denial decision, race was significant. Black applicants had a
higher probability of denial at the 90 percent significance level.
In a well-publicized accept/reject study, Munnell et al. (1992) used
HMDA data augmented with survey information about the creditworthiness
of borrowers to analyze lending behavior in Boston. A variable to
account for the racial composition of the market was not found to affect
the lender's accept/reject decision, but applicant race was found
to be statistically related to the decision. Minorities were rejected 56
percent more often than equally qualified whites.
The Boston study has been criticized for a number of reasons.(25)
First, as with the credit flow studies, there is the potential for
omitted variable bias. If omitted variables are associated with the race
variable, the coefficient on race will account for the true effect of
race plus that of the omitted variable(s). The Boston study included
several variables to account for borrower risk. However, not all risk
factors could be captured, and some researchers argue that the race
coefficient is actually capturing the riskiness of the applicant. Race
would appear significant in an analysis which fails to account for
wealth if, as has been shown elsewhere, minorities have lower levels of
wealth. There was also little consideration of the characteristics of
the property and credit history of the applicant. Second, the study has
been criticized for data errors. These potential data errors include
monthly incomes that are inconsistent with annual levels, negative
interest rates, loan to value ratios exceeding one, loan to income
ratios outside reasonable ranges, the inclusion of black applicant
denials because of over-qualification for special lending programs, and
a number of extreme outliers. Brown and Tootell (1995) and Munnell et
al. (1996) contend that even after accounting for the data concerns, the
fundamental result remains - minorities are more likely to be denied
mortgages than similarly qualified whites.
Other follow-up studies have shown mixed results. Using data from
Munnell et al. (1992), Zandi (1993) found no race effect, while Carr and
Megbolugbe (1993) found the effect remains after "cleaning the
data," as did Glennon and Stengel (1994). Using a model similar to
that in Munnell et al. to evaluate the Boston and Philadelphia markets,
Schill and Wachter (1993) found evidence consistent with redlining and
discrimination. When variables are included to proxy for neighborhood
risk, the neighborhood racial composition became insignificant, although
racial status still significantly decreased the probability of
acceptance. Stengel and Glennon (1995) also found that it is important
to use bank-specific guidelines in the analysis to capture unique, but
economically based, underwriting criteria. Using a more generic market
model, for example, secondary market criteria, can lead to misleading
results.(26) Using cleansed data from Munnell et al. (1992), Hunter and
Walker (1996) did not find evidence of discrimination via higher
underwriting standards for all minorities. They contend that race
matters only in the case of marginally qualified applications. Needless
to say, there is little uniformity of view.
Yezer (1995) and Rosenblatt (1997) argue that fundamental problems in
the use of accept/reject models to evaluate discrimination result from
the informal prescreening of applicants. Both applicants and lenders
only want to proceed with applications that appear likely to qualify for
a loan because denials are costly for both parties. Thus, during the
initial lender-borrower contact, the lender and borrower decide whether
the application warrants pursuing. Then, the formal application takes
place, and denials occur only in those cases in which information not
available in the initial contact affects the decision (for example, bad
credit history). Therefore, denial may be as closely related to
communication skills and cultural background as to economic variables.
Sophisticated underqualified potential applicants will not reach the
formal application process because they realize they will not be
accepted, while unsophisticated candidates will follow through only to
be denied. Thus, there is a significant selection bias problem in the
formal application stage which may explain the race differentials. To
support this view, Rosenblatt (1997) cites evidence that education
levels are strongly predictive of credit approvals. The argument,
therefore, is that the information in denial rate data may not be what
researchers perceive it to be.
Default rate studies
An alternative means of evaluating lender discrimination is to
examine the default rates of borrowers thought to be discriminated
against relative to other borrowers. Researchers have compared default
rates across groups based on the theory that if minorities are overtly discriminated against, the average minority borrower should be of higher
credit quality than the average nonminority borrower.(27) This should be
reflected in mortgage default rates and resulting loss rates; for
minority loans, both should be lower. However, studies have not found
evidence of lower default rates for minority holders of mortgages. In
critiquing the Boston study, Becker (1993) cited data indicating the
default rates were equal for white and minority sections of the Boston
market, which was not consistent with overt discrimination.(28) A more
recent study by Berkovec et al. (1996) also tests for discrimination
using default rates. Controlling for various loan, borrower, and
property related characteristics, the authors evaluated the default
rates and resulting losses for FHA-insured loans and found a higher
likelihood of default on the part of black borrowers and higher loss
rates. These results suggest that lenders, perhaps as a result of
regulatory pressure, may have over-extended credit to minorities.
However, this line of research has also been criticized. First, if
discrimination occurs, while the marginal minority borrower may be
better qualified than the marginal white applicant, inferences about the
average borrower cannot be made without making assumptions about the
distribution of creditworthiness across the two groups of potential
borrowers, for example, Ferguson and Peters (1995). The distributions
could be significantly different. Additionally, minorities may also be
treated differently once they are in default. Default studies typically
use data on foreclosures. Bank forbearance in defaults favoring one of
the two groups could bias the results.(29)
Performance studies
There are two general areas of research relating bank performance to
the CRA and fair lending regulations. The first deals with the
profitability associated with lending in low-income markets. If such
lending is not profitable, regulation requiring it should adversely
affect performance. The second area of research addresses the
implications of mortgage discrimination on bank performance. If some
banks are choosing to discriminate and forego profitable lending
opportunities, other banks that do not discriminate should be able to
exploit these opportunities.
During the debate prior to the enactment of the CRA, critics argued
that economics was driving lending patterns and the CRA might either
have no impact, but be costly to implement, or actually generate bad
loans. From the banks' perspective it would be a tax and, if
lending patterns did not change, it would be without benefits. If
increased lending in the low-income market did occur, but was not as
profitable as that in alternative markets, then the CRA would act as a
tax and a credit redistribution mechanism. The argument in favor of the
CRA was that banks were foregoing profitable opportunities because of
discriminatory behavior or market failure, and performance could be
enhanced if they became more actively involved in this market (although
performance could be adversely affected in the short run as start-up
costs were incurred).
There have been a limited number of studies evaluating the effect on
performance of lending in the low-income market. Canner and Passmore
(1996) offered a number of testable hypotheses concerning the potential
impact on profitability and the relationship between the extent of the
bank's activity in this market and performance. They found no
evidence of lower profitability at banks specializing in the low-income
market, consistent with the view that, once start-up cost are incurred,
lending in this market can be just as profitable as in other
markets.(30) Beshouri and Glennon (1996) evaluated the relative
performance of credit unions that specialize in the low-income market
and found that while these specialized firms have greater return
volatility, higher delinquency rates, charge-off rates, and operating
costs, they are compensated for these differences and generate similar
rates of return. Similarly, in analyzing the performance of low-income
and minority lending, Malmquist, Phillips-Patrick, and Rossi (1997)
found that while low-income lending was more costly, lenders were
compensated with higher revenues, making profits similar for both low-
and high-income lending. Finally, Esty (1995) evaluated the performance
of Chicago's South Shore Bank, which has been held up as the model
community development bank with the dual objectives of making a profit
and aiding in the development of the local community. Esty's
analysis found the economic return of the bank to be substandard.
Shareholders, however, appeared to be willing to trade off the lower
return for the social return received from community improvement. That
is, the shareholders' objectives were apparently aligned with the
dual objectives of the bank.(31) In interviews with shareholders and
employees, Lash and Mote (1994) found similar evidence of a willingness
to trade off economic profit to emphasize the development objective.
While the behavior of South Shore's management and shareholders may
be admirable, if Esty's analysis is correct, it is not obvious that
this model can be implemented across the entire industry.
The second performance-related area of research deals with the profit
implications of discrimination. If an institution overtly discriminates,
it will deliberately forego profitable lending opportunities. This
implies that lenders that do not discriminate will be the beneficiaries
of this behavior. Assuming that minority-owned banks do not discriminate
against minorities, one might expect them to outperform the
discriminating-banks. Calomiris, Kahn, and Longhofer (1994) developed a
model of cultural affinity to explain differences in minority denial
rates. Their basic argument is that because of a general lack of
familiarity with the culture of minority applicants, the typical white
loan officer may not be as accommodating with these applicants as he
would with a white applicant. For the minority applicant, the loan
officer will rely more heavily on low-cost, objective information
instead of making the extra effort, as with the white applicant, to
obtain additional information to improve the chances of approval. There
is some empirical support for this argument (see Hunter and Walker,
1996). Again, this implies that minority-owned banks should benefit,
since they will not lack a cultural affinity with minority
applicants.(32)
If discriminatory banks forego profitable opportunities, ceterus
paribus, minority-owned banks should have superior profitability, lower
minority denial rates, and lower bad loans. However, the empirical
evidence does not support this. A number of studies have found that
minority-owned banks have lower profits (Bates and Bradford, 1980,
Boorman and Kwast, 1974, and Brimmet, 1971). There is also evidence of
higher loan losses at minority-owned banks (Kwast, 1981). Additionally,
there is evidence that bank ownership shifts from white to black control
result in fewer loans being generated (Dahl, 1996). Generally, there is
evidence that minority-owned banks do not have particularly good
performance or lending records and have relatively poor CRA ratings
(Kwast and Black, 1983, Clair, 1988, and Black, Collins, and Cyree,
1997). This evidence is not consistent with overt discrimination.
In summary, the findings for the various forms of discrimination are
quite mixed. While some studies have found race to be a factor in loan
decisions, the evidence is far from conclusive. Additionally,
methodological problems bring into question the validity of many
studies. Parties on either side of the issue frequently draw
uncritically on the studies that align with their own position.
Additional research is needed before we can draw meaningful conclusions
about race and the credit decision.
Recent trends in mortgage activity: The effect of regulation
How successful has the recent enforcement of the CRA and the fair
lending laws been? Headlines proclaiming surges in credit to minority
groups suggest that the stricter enforcement of the CRA and fair lending
laws during the 1990s has been successful. Most of these claims are
based on recent trends in lending to low-income individuals or in
low-income neighborhoods, such as those presented in figure 1.(33)
Between 1990 and 1995 the annual number of mortgage originations to low-
and moderate-income households, in low- and moderate-income census
tracts, and to minorities almost doubled. New loans in census tracts
where minorities accounted for at least half the population also grew
significantly. As figure 1 shows, there was a considerable increase in
the number of loans to individuals targeted by fair lending and CRA
regulations. Some bankers argue that the regulatory mandate to increase
lending in low-income neighborhoods and to low-income individuals has
actually been a blessing in disguise as it has opened up new, lucrative,
previously untapped markets. Others continue to criticize the
regulations.(34)
A full assessment of the success of the CRA and the fair lending
programs would require a comprehensive cost-benefit analysis. Accurately
quantifying the cost is difficult.(35) It is also difficult to quantify the success of these programs because of the vagueness of the
legislation and the regulations enforcing it. The mandate to banks was
to use the proper criteria in making loan decisions and to reach out to
the local community, including low- and moderate-income neighborhoods
and individuals. Based on this mandate, success may not require any
change in lending patterns. Another problem with associating recent
lending patterns with regulation is the lack of a control group. The
issue is not whether lending to the targeted groups increased, but
whether it increased as a result of the regulations,
There are, however, a number of credit flow measures often associated
with the CRA and fair lending laws. Concerning redlining, one would want
to analyze changes in the volume and dollar value of loans flowing into
low-income or minority neighborhoods. The number of applications in
these areas could also be considered if redlining resulted in
applications not being accepted from these areas. Some argue that the
purpose of the regulations was to increase the flow of credit to
specific groups of borrowers (based either on income or race),
therefore, credit flows to those particular groups could be analyzed. It
has also been argued that the elimination of differences in denial rates
may be desirable.(36) Concerning fair lending, one would want to analyze
changes in lending to minority individuals and/or denial rates.
Although data limitations hamper the degree to which rigorous
analysis of the regulatory impact can be undertaken, we can evaluate
lending patterns and check for trends consistent with what are typically
perceived to be desired changes. We use three different control group
specifications. First, we compare lending patterns pre- and post- the
recent regulatory changes. Second, we compare the degree of lending to
targeted groups (minority and low-income individuals and neighborhoods)
with lending to nontargeted groups. Last, we compare the lending
behavior of more heavily regulated depository institutions with that of
less regulated mortgage companies.
Below, we present evidence on these credit flows and discuss how they
align with the goals of the legislation. We would expect the CRA and
fair lending reforms of the late 1980s and early 1990s to have increased
lending to minority and low-income individuals and low-income
neighborhoods. We would also expect that most of the impact would be
concentrated in recent years as regulatory, legal, and public scrutiny
intensified and the cost of failing to satisfy the requirements
increased. We analyze two potential effects. If the regulations were
successful in getting lenders to expand their business into new markets,
this might influence the overall level of mortgage activity.
Alternatively, we may see distributional effects as lenders allocated a
larger share of the credit pool toward the new markets.
To analyze the effect on the aggregate level of mortgage activity, we
used a nominal dollar measure of all mortgage activity for 1970 through
1995, combining originations and refinances, from the Survey of Mortgage
Lending Activity issued by the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban
Development (HUD) [ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 2 OMITTED]. Figure 2 suggests
considerable growth in mortgage originations over the 1990s, in
particular 1993-94. Can the high rate of growth in the 1990s be
attributed to regulatory-induced changes in lending behavior or to other
factors related to the aggregate demand for housing credit? Three pieces
of evidence suggest that the latter hypothesis may be more accurate.
First, there is considerable growth throughout the entire period, even
in real terms as indicated by the colored line depicting the dollar
value of mortgage originations deflated by the Consumer Price Index for
Urban Workers. The colored line also highlights the procyclical and
seasonal nature of mortgage originations. Second, there is a substantial
decline in the number of mortgage originations after the 1993 peak,
which might be due to a curtailment of refinance activity.(37) Clearly,
there is no regulatory explanation for this decline. There are probably
a number of factors beyond regulation that affect the number of
originations and increase the difficulty of graphically detecting a
structural break. To address this, we use a regression model of the
quarterly growth rate of originations, controlling for the growth rate
of gross domestic product (GDP), the change in mortgage rates, and the
growth rate of the consumer price index.(38) Quarterly indicators are
included to absorb the seasonality in the dependent variable. Table 2
displays the regression results. In column 1, over 50 percent of the
variation in the growth of originations is explained by the
right-hand-side variables. The coefficients suggest that an increase in
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 2 OMITTED] mortgage rates corresponds to a
decrease in the growth of mortgage originations, while an increase in
the growth rate of GDP corresponds to an increase in the level of
originations. The controls for seasonality, the quarterly indicator
variables, suggest faster growth in mortgage originations in the second
and third quarters than in the first and fourth. Column 2 of the table
presents the regression model with the addition of a binary variable to
capture a structural shift in the post-1990 period. The coefficient of
the post-1990 indicator variable is actually negative, but is
significant at only the 74 percent confidence level. Therefore, the
regression model is unable to support the hypothesis that mortgage
originations were stronger in the period following the recent regulatory
changes. Tests for structural breaks for post-1992 and post-1993,
columns 3 and 4, produced similar results.
Although we find the recent growth in mortgage lending is consistent
with earlier patterns, the regulations may have resulted in
distributional changes in lending patterns.(39) That is, there may be a
shift in lending emphasis away from traditional markets toward low- or
moderate-income groups and individuals. To evaluate this, we assembled
HMDA data for depository institutions and their affiliates over the
1982-95 period and decomposed the data by income groups and, when
possible, racial groups.(40)
To the extent that regulations influence lending patterns, we have
argued above that the effect would be most evident in recent years,
because of increased scrutiny, and most pronounced among low-income and
minority borrowers and neighborhoods. We therefore divided total lending
activity into four income categories and evaluated growth trends in the
number of mortgage applicants, originations, and dollar value of
originations for the 1990s. We also developed data for the number and
dollar value of originations for the 1980s by neighborhood income
levels.(41) Table 3 shows the 1990 levels and relative shares of
mortgage activity on which our analysis is based. The targeted groups
received a relatively small portion of the applications, originations,
and dollars. Low- and moderate-income tracts account for approximately
10 percent of the applications and loans and slightly less of the
dollars lent. Low- and moderate-income individuals, as opposed to home
purchases in low- and moderate-income tracts, represent nearly 20
percent of applications and originations, but still less than 10 percent
of the dollars lent. Roughly 80 percent of mortgage activity
(applicants, originations, and dollars) involved white applicants. These
figures demonstrate that the targeted populations are a relatively small
share of the aggregate, which may explain why increases may not be
observable in the aggregate data.
TABLE 3
Base mortgage lending data, 1990
Applications Acceptances Dollars
(000s) (000s) (billion)
Total Applications 1,491.35 1,276.16 127.72
Tract income/MSA
income shares
Low income 0.01 0.01 0.01
Moderate income 0.10 0.09 0.08
Medium income 0.57 0.57 0.49
High income 0.31 0.33 0.43
Applicant income/MSA
income shares
Low income 0.05 0.04 0.01
Moderate income 0.17 0.16 0.08
Medium income 0.27 0.28 0.20
High income 0.50 0.53 0.71
Race shares
White 0.82 0.84 0.82
Black 0.06 0.05 0.04
Other minority 0.11 0.11 0.13
Source: HMDA data, see footnotes 33 and 40.
The year-over-year growth rates for the number of loans originated by
neighborhood income groups for the 1980s and 1990s are presented in
figures 3 and 4, respectively. For the 1980s, growth in the low- and
moderate-income groups lagged that in other areas. For four of the years
in the 1980s, the low-income tracts showed the slowest growth and the
moderate-income tracts also showed relatively slow growth. In these
years, growth in the overall market was quite robust. Thus, for the
1980s overall, growth in loan volume was not particularly concentrated
in the low- and moderate-income groups. Originations to the low- and
moderate-income groups grew more than 40 percent between 1985 and 1986,
exceeding growth for these groups for any single year throughout the
1990s. However, the 1986 growth of mortgage originations in middle- and
upper-income tracts still exceeded that of the low- and moderate-income
groups.
Things changed in the 1990s. After 1991, growth was relatively fast
in the two lowest income groups, particularly in the years when overall
market growth was greatest. This finding suggests that banks have
responded to the CRA and have made significantly more loans in the low-
and moderate-income markets. The change is overwhelmingly statistically
significant based on a test of whether the share of loans in each income
category is constant throughout the 1990s. We conclude that the growth
in mortgage originations has not been uniform throughout the 1990s,
consistent with the 1992 through 1994 growth spurt in lending to low-
and moderate-income groups.
Figure 5 presents data for recent mortgage applications.(42) After
1991, low- and moderate-income neighborhoods saw significantly stronger
growth than occurred in other areas. Growth in the middle-income group,
where the majority of mortgage activity is occurring (see table 3), saw
the slowest increase over this period. These trends are consistent with
the view that banks have been making a significant effort to encourage
applications from lower-income neighborhoods and with statements by
community groups that progress is being made in less affluent
neighborhoods. The test of differences across categories is again highly
statistically significant.(43)
Figures 6 and 7 analyze mortgage activity by the income level of the
borrower instead of the neighborhood in which the property is located.
While not quite as pronounced as the neighborhood data, figure 6 shows
growth in mortgage activity to low- and moderate-income individuals,
particularly for the years in which overall growth was greatest. The
mortgage application data in figure 7 tell a similar story. Overall, the
data suggest an increase in the growth of loan applications and loans
approved for low- and moderate-income individuals, with much of the
growth coming after 1992. However, the differences are only significant
at the 46 percent and 54 percent confidence levels, respectively, for
originations and applications. Thus, based on this test, lending to low-
and moderate-income individuals was uniform throughout the 1990s. Data
on applicant income were not collected for the 1980s so we cannot
compare the two periods.
Figures 8 and 9 show loan activity by applicant race. While neither
the CRA nor the fair lending laws explicitly require lenders to change
underwriting criteria and affirmatively pursue additional minority
mortgage business, lenders may believe that doing so will help them
avoid charges of discrimination and be looked upon more favorably during
their regulatory assessment. The growth in minority applications and
originations during the 1990s has been high relative to that for
nonminorities. The increase in applications and originations among
blacks is even more significant.(44) Figures 10 and 11 present a similar
analysis based on the minority proportion of the census tract as opposed
to the minority status of the applicant. Since 1991, growth appears to
have been relatively similar across the groups.
Several of the results in figures 3-11 are consistent with efforts by
banks to target low- and moderate-income individuals and neighborhoods
in their mortgage business. This observation is based not on the level
of loans made but on the fact that the growth in lending to the targeted
groups exceeded that to the nontargeted groups. One could argue,
however, that the improvements are somewhat diminished, being from such
a small base (see table 3). Lending in low- and moderate-income
neighborhoods constitutes approximately 10 percent of total originations
and even less of the dollar value of loans originated. Based on income
alone, we would expect the demand for mortgages in these neighborhoods
to be relatively low. Mortgage activity among low-income individuals
constitutes approximately 20 percent of the market. However, the 31
percent growth in mortgage originations in low- and moderate-income
tracts from 1993 to 1994 corresponds to nearly 35,000 loans and
approximately $2.7 billion. If all of this change is attributed to the
regulations, it translates to just over 100 loans and $8 million per
MSA.
In addition to the number of loans and applications, we evaluated
denial rates for ethnic groups. Minorities have typically been shown to
have higher denial rates than other applicants. One of the common
debates in the literature and popular press is whether the differences
across racial groups can be explained by economic characteristics.(45)
We present two measures of differences in denial rates. The first is a
standard odds ratio: Based on the loan decision, we calculate the odds
of a minority applicant being denied a loan relative to the odds of a
nonminority applicant being denied.(46) An odds ratio of 1 corresponds
to equality of the denial odds for white and minority applicants; values
above I correspond to more minority denials. If minority status is
associated with lower creditworthiness, we would expect the odds ratio
to be higher because of the differences in qualifications. To partially
account for this, we also calculated an odds ratio conditioned on income
and loan value.(47) The odds ratios are presented in table 4.(48)
Interpretation of the odds ratios as evidence of discrimination is
difficult due to the small number of variables collected in the HMDA
data. Instead, we focus on the changes in the ratio over time. Under the
assumption of constant quality of the applicant pools, changes in the
ratios may be attributed to changes in lender behavior. Cyclical economic changes, however, are likely to affect the creditworthiness of
the applicant pool. To account for this, we also calculated the two odds
ratio measures for a sample of independent mortgage companies. These are
typically thought to be less stringently regulated with respect to the
CRA, but they still report for HMDA purposes through HUD. Thus, we use
these as a control group that we can contrast with the regulated banks
to distinguish the effect of regulation.
As table 4 indicates, for depository institutions the unconditioned odds ratio is relatively stable during the 1990s.(49) The odds of a
minority applicant being denied a mortgage request are approximately
twice those of a nonminority applicant. The odds ratio and trend
estimates are statistically different from 0 at the 99 percent
confidence level. Differences between years are typically statistically
significant at conventional levels. The conditioned ratio for banks is
somewhat similar to the unconditioned measure, but declines throughout
the period. The additional information embedded in the conditioned
measure does explain part of the difference between the two borrowing
groups; however, it leaves much unexplained. Additional information on
the creditworthiness of the applicant and any discriminatory effects
would be needed to explain the remainder. The declining trend in the
odds ratio, after conditioning on a flexible specification of loan
amount and applicant income, suggests a change in the treatment of
minority applicants relative to nonminority applicants over the 1990-95
period. Essentially, lenders became more accommodating to minorities.
The effect is more apparent in the last two columns of the table, where
we repeat the analysis using black/white odds ratios. These results are
consistent with more stringent regulations producing a change in lender
behavior, assuming that the unobserved characteristics of the applicant
pool remain constant over time.
The odds ratios for the independent mortgage companies are also
presented in table 4. The ratios for these less regulated companies are
much more erratic, but display a similar downward trend. Disparities
between minority and nonminority applicants and between black and white
applicants decline over time for both sets of institutions, suggesting
that the change may not be the result of the regulations.(50)
Another way to assess the extent to which the supply of mortgage
credit to minorities increased in the mid 1990s is to examine home
ownership rates over time. The relaxation of binding credit constraints
should cause minority originations and home ownership rates to increase.
Figure 12 displays home ownership rates from 1970 to 1994 for white,
black, and other minority households. Recent home ownership rates are
still well below the rates observed in the early to mid-1980s. Recall
that blacks experienced the strongest growth in mortgage originations in
1993 and 1994, yet there was little effect on home ownership. Within our
sample, mortgage originations to blacks increased by 23,000 loans from
1992 to 1993 and another 4,000 from 1993 to 1994. In 1994 there were
roughly 11.3 million black households in the U.S., implying that 113,000
new loans would be necessary to move the home ownership rate a single
percentage point. Viewed this way, the 1993-94 changes appear small.
Summary and conclusions
In this article, we have provided background on the evolution of the
CRA and fair lending regulations, summarized the economic literature
which pertains to this type of regulation, and presented evidence on the
effectiveness [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 4 OMITTED] of these regulations by
analyzing recent trends in mortgage lending activity. The literature
review indicated mixed results. Although early studies appear to find
evidence of redlining, more recent studies do not support this finding.
Concerning disparate treatment based on the race of the applicant, some
studies have found differences in the probability of a loan application
being denied that are not explained by economic characteristics.
However, these studies have been criticized as having methodological and
data problems.
Our major purpose, however, is to provide the reader with a review of
the literature and not to take a position on the merits of the various
positions concerning whether there is a need for the CRA and fair
lending regulations. Regardless of one's position, the regulations
do exist and are being enforced. We evaluated how the regulations may
alter lending behavior, using a variety of measures of changes in
lending patterns. We found that over the 1990-95 period (particularly
1993-94), loan applications and originations increased significantly to
groups targeted by the CRA and fair lending legislation. Additionally,
it appears there may have been a compositional shift toward blacks and a
minor shift toward low-income groups. These changes appear large in
terms of growth rates, but they started from a very small base. The
changes appear smaller when measured in dollars rather than the number
of loans or applications.
It is difficult to attribute the increase solely to the strengthening
of the regulations. We assessed the regulatory impact in three ways.
First, we used historical trends as a control group. After accounting
for economic conditions, we found that aggregate lending in recent years
has not been unusually strong. Second, we considered changes in the
composition of mortgage activity by examining year-to-year growth rates
of applications and mortgage originations. We used the nontargeted
groups as controls. The analyses presented some evidence of a change
toward increased lending to minority and low-income individuals and
neighborhoods. Last, we compared recent trends in denial disparity measures, black/white and minority/nonminority odds ratios over time
between depository institutions and mortgage companies. Typically
thought to be less stringently regulated, mortgage companies might
depict the market result in the absence of additional regulation. Our
analysis shows a decline in the odds ratio for both depository and
non-depository institutions, suggesting that the effect may not be the
result of increased regulatory scrutiny.
Overall, our results are mixed. There is some evidence of changes in
lending patterns, and some of the evidence is consistent with changes
related to the new regulatory environment. However, the growth rates are
not unprecedented and, if entirely attributed to the regulations,
translate to approximately 100 loans and $8 million per MSA. We would
emphasize that we have not addressed the cost of implementing the
regulations relative to the benefits. In addition, we have not addressed
the question of whether these credit market regulations are the most
effective way of changing the fundamental economic status of the
targeted groups. As the regulation of credit markets continues to
evolve, it remains important to continually revisit these issues.
NOTES
1 Throughout we use the term bank in a generic sense to encompass all
depository institutions.
2 See, for example, Coplan (1996), Lindsey (1996), Seiberg (1996a,
1996b), or Wilke (1996).
3 For a discussion of potential information externalities, see
Nakamura (1993) and Calem (1996).
4 Gender was added as a protected category through 1974 amendments,
and handicap and family status were added by amendment in 1988.
5 A number of these protected categories were added by amendments in
1976.
6 See Hula (1991) and GAO (1996).
7 See Dedman (1988).
8 For a discussion and examples of increased scrutiny by regulators
in more recent years, see Garwood and Smith (1993) and Macey and Miller
(1993).
9 The reporting requirement now extends beyond depository
institutions to, generally, all lending institutions with assets of more
than $10 million with an office in a metropolitan statistical area (MSA)
(for depositories) or loan activity in MSAs (for nondepositories).
10 For a description of the process by which the Federal Reserve
Banks use statistical models to test for disparate treatment of
applicants, see Bauer and Cromwell (1994) and Avery, Beeson, and Calem
(1997 forthcoming). For discussion of the use of statistics in detecting
mortgage discrimination, see Yezer (1995).
11 See Interagency Regulatory Task Force (1994). Represented in the
interagency group were the Department of Housing and urban Development,
Department of Justice, Comptroller of the Currency, Office of Thrift
Supervision, Federal Reserve System, Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation, Federal Housing Finance Board, Federal Trade Commission,
and National Credit Union Administration.
12 Again, although the fair lending laws and the CRA are different,
there is significant overlap as evidenced in the last of these items.
This is very close to an anti-redlining statement - the very reason for
the passage of the CRA.
13 For examples of enforcement activities by the Department of
Justice and bank regulatory agencies, see Macey and Miller (1993) and
GAO (1996). For a discussion of alternative strategic responses by banks
to the increased regulatory pressure from fair lending and CRA
regulations, see Evanoff and Segal (1997 forthcoming).
14 This argument was also being made at the time to contest the
liberalization of bank branching laws. The concern was that banks would
export deposits through their branch network to other, more lucrative,
markets.
15 Regulation BB of the Code of Federal Regulations describes the
requirements of the community reinvestment regulation.
16 See Macey and Miller (1993) and U.S. Congress (1989).
17 There are alternative tests for wholesale or limited purpose
banks, still another streamlined test for small banks, and another for
banks choosing to develop and be held accountable for a strategic plan
which details how the banks intend to satisfy CRA requirements.
18 Consumer loans will be considered if the bank collects data on
this activity and requests that they be considered in the evaluation, or
if regulators determine that this activity constitutes a substantial
portion of the institution's business.
19 The explicit weight assigned for each test and grade addresses a
criticism of the earlier rating system under which bankers frequently
complained about the uncertainty as to how they should allocate
resources to improve their CRA rating. Emphasizing the lending test also
addresses criticisms of the earlier grading scheme by being less
process-oriented and more results-oriented.
20 See GAO (1995).
21 For example, HMDA data does not contain information on credit
history, wealth, and employment stability of the applicant, or the value
or purchase price of the property. Adverse credit history is the most
common reason given in the HMDA data for denying loans. For discussions
of lending trends in HMDA data, see Canner and Passmore (1994, 1995a,
1995b).
22 A review of much of the early literature can be found in Benston
(1981) and Canner (1982).
23 Canner, Gabriel, and Woolley (1991) reported similar findings
after controlling for market characteristics. The inclusion of variables
to capture risk factors, however, may not resolve the endogeneity
problem since their values may be supply induced.
24 Some studies have addressed whether minority groups are
"discriminated" against in that they are more likely to
receive a particular type of loan which may have less favorable terms.
For example, Canner, Gabriel, and Woolley (1991) found minorities are
more likely to obtain an FHA loan than are nonminorities.
25 See Horne (1994, 1997 forthcoming), Liebowitz (1993), and Day and
Liebowitz (1996).
26 The authors find considerable differences in underwriting
standards across banks concerning threshold values for debt ratios,
loan-to-value ratios, etc. The authors realize that unlike the more
generic market model, regressions with an emphasis on bank-specific
underwriting standards will not allow for a direct test of disparate
impact.
27 Becker (1971) is typically cited as the source of this argument.
28 Although Becker actually used data from the Boston study, it is
questionable if the data are appropriate for critiquing the Boston study
based on default rates. The data were for loans originated prior to the
period discussed in the Boston study and the analysis was a comparison
of default rates across geographic areas based on racial composition.
From the data, one cannot conclude how racial default rates compare.
29 For a discussion of these concerns see Tootell (1993) and Ross
(1996).
30 The authors, however, emphasize the limitations of their analysis.
For example, information on the profitability of low-income lending is
not available. Thus, the authors are comparing overall profit levels
across banks with different levels of low-income lending although this
lending is typically a relatively small portion of the overall
portfolio. There have also been concerns expressed recently about the
growing number of special lending programs to accommodate the targeted
groups and the resulting high default rates, see Seiberg (1996b).
31 Esty also evaluated the impact South Shore had on the local
community and argued that there was no evidence of any unique positive
relative impact on the local community.
32 One could make the argument that banks with a significant number
of minority loan officers could also benefit from a cultural affinity.
We do not have data to directly test for this.
33 Low-income neighborhoods are defined as census tracts where the
median income is less than 50 percent of the MSA median income. The
moderate-income category corresponds to greater than or equal to 50 and
less than 80 percent, the middle-income category corresponds to greater
than or equal to 80 percent and less than 120 percent, and the
upper-income category corresponds to at least 120 percent of the MSA
median income. Similar break points define the categories for applicant
income relative to MSA income. Tracts are also classified by minority
composition into low (less than 25 percent minority), moderate (25
percent to 50 percent), middle (50 percent to 75 percent) and high (75
percent to 100 percent).
34 See, for example, Wilke (1996), Seiberg (1996), or Lindsey (1996).
35 Barefoot et al. (1993) attempt to quantify the compliance cost
associated with consumer protection regulations including the CRA. They
note that bankers find the CRA to be one of the most onerous regulations
faced by banks.
36 A narrowing of denial rate differentials is frequently cited in
the popular press as a measure of progress in fair lending, for example,
Coplan (1996). Lawmakers have also argued that although some
differential may be warranted based on credit quality, the current
differences are too great and imply some discrimination is being
undertaken: for example, in U.S. Congress (1989), see Illinois Senator
Dixon's opening comments during hearings on the CRA.
37 Refinancing and new originations cannot be separated in the HUD
data.
38 Changes in mortgage rates measure the contract rate on 30-year
fixed rate conventional mortgage commitments reported by the Federal
Home Loan Mortgage Corporation.
39 For critiques of the CRA as a means of accomplishing this
redistribution, see Lacker (1995), Macey and Miller (1993), and White
(1993).
40 It is important to emphasize that our sample may differ from HMDA
data reported elsewhere because, unless noted, we are viewing lending
activity only for depository institutions or their affiliates, and we
are screening out observations that cannot be classified into income and
racial subgroups which we expect to be affected by the regulation. By
analyzing this group of institutions, we have a homogenous group through
time. Certain mortgage originators were only added to the HMDA in recent
years. Our sample consists of loan applications for one-to-four family,
owner-occupied properties where the mortgage is valued between $1,000
and $1 million, the applicant's income is less than $1 million, and
the loan-to-income ratio is less than five. For the 1980s these
requirements were imposed on market (census tract) averages since
individual loan data were not available on HMDA until 1990. We only
consider mortgages for properties in MSAs, and we require complete data
on the location of the property - state, county, MSA, and census tract -
to allow us to combine HMDA data with census information concerning
neighborhood income and composition. Reporting institutions must report
on applications for property located in an MSA where they have an
office. If the property is outside of an MSA or in an MSA in which the
institution does not have an office, it has the option of reporting the
MSA information. Thus, some loans made in MSAs will be omitted from our
sample because the bank chose not to include the information. The MSA
information is necessary to merge the data with census information.
Finally, the data must pass the validity checks (Board of Governors
1995).
41 The data are not precisely comparable to that for the 1990s
because mortgage originations for purchase and refinancing were not
separated during this earlier period. However, the role played by
"refis" in the 1980s is not expected to be nearly as erratic
as in the 1990s. All analysis of the 1990s excludes refinances.
42 Application data are not available for the 1980s.
43 We reject the hypothesis that shares by income categories are
constant over the 1990-95 period based on a chi-square test statistic of
53 with 15 degrees of freedom.
44 The increase in mortgage activity for blacks was also spread
across all income levels. The 1990-95 growth rates for blacks in low-,
moderate-, middle-, and upper-income neighborhoods were 157 percent, 129
percent, 99 percent, and 101 percent, respectively. In their evaluation
of redlining Holmes and Horvitz (1994) found that, after accounting for
neighborhood characteristics including risk, more credit was being made
available in certain minority neighborhoods. They found a systematic
preference on the part of insured lenders (the FHA) toward lending in
areas of high or growing minority populations. They attribute this to
the pressures created by the CRA and community groups to increase
lending in these areas. Similarly, Malmquist, Phillips-Patrick, and
Rossi (1997 forthcoming) found that while low-income lending was more
expensive, lenders were also compensated with higher revenues making
profits similar for both low- and higher-income loans. However, the
authors found that profits were inversely related to the share of
mortgages originated to blacks. They suggest this is a result of firms
"bending over backwards" to yield to regulatory pressures to
make more minority loans.
45 Minorities are defined as non-whites. Asians are an exception and
typically do not have high denial rates.
46 Odds are defined as the ratio of the probability of denial to the
probability of acceptance.
47 We calculate this based on a logit regression which includes, in a
flexible functional form, applicant income, loan size, and race.
48 The denial rates may be related to other factors, for example,
geographic differences. In our analysis, we emphasize changes through
time and assume the effects from other factors are constant across time.
49 The mortgage company data should be interpreted cautiously, since
these institutions do not go through the same rigorous editing process
and resubmission of revised data as the depository institutions.
50 Alternatively, these "nonregulated" firms can be
prosecuted by the U.S. Department of Justice for fair lending
violations, so they may not be immune to this regulation.
REFERENCES
Ahlbrandt, Jr., Robert S., "Exploratory research on the
redlining phenomenon," AREUEA Journal, Vol. 5, 1977, pp. 473-481.
Art, Robert C., "Social responsibility in bank credit decisions:
The Community Reinvestment Act one decade later," Pacific Law
Journal, Vol. 18, July 1987, pp. 1071-1139.
Avery, Robert B., Patricia E. Beeson, and Paul S. Calem, "Using
HMDA data as a regulatory screen for fair lending compliance,"
Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol. 11, 1997 forthcoming.
Avery, Robert B., Patricia E. Beeson, and Mark S. Sniderman,
"Underserved mortgage markets: Evidence from HMDA data,"
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, working paper, No. 94-16, 1994.
Avery, Robert B., and Thomas M. Buynak, "Mortgage redlining:
Some new evidence," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, Summer 1981, pp. 18-32.
Barefoot, Marrianan & Associates, Inc., A.V. Thakor, and J. C.
Beltz, "Common ground: Increasing consumer benefits and reducing
regulatory costs in banking," Herbert V. Prochnow Educational
Foundation, monograph, 1993.
Bates, T., and W, Bradford, "An analysis of the portfolio
behavior of black-owned banks" Journal of Finance, Vol. 35, 1980,
pp. 753-768.
Bauer, Paul W., and Brian A. Cromwell, "A Monte Carlo examination of bias tests in mortgage lending," Economic Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Quarter 3 1994, pp. 27-44.
Becker, Gary S., The Economics of Discrimination, Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1971.
-----, "The evidence against banks doesn't prove
bias," Business Week, April 19, 1993.
Benston, George J., "Mortgage redlining research," Journal
of Bank Research, Vol. 12, Spring 1981, pp. 8-23.
Benston, George J., and Dan Horsky, "Redlining and the demand
for mortgages in the central city and suburbs," Journal of Bank
Research, Vol. 10, Summer 1979, pp. 72-87.
-----, "The relationship between the demand and supply of home
financing and neighborhood characteristics: An empirical study of
mortgage redlining," Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol.
5, 1992, pp. 235-260.
Berkovec, James A., Glenn B. Canner, Stuart A. Gabriel, and Timothy
H. Hannan, "Mortgage discrimination and FHA loan performance,"
Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago:
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, May 1995, pp. 218-237.
-----, "Mortgage discrimination and FHA loan performance,"
Cityscape, Vol. 2, February 1996, pp. 9-24.
Beshouri, Christopher P., and Dennis C. Glennon, "CRA as
'market development' or 'tax': An analysis of
lending decisions and economic development," Proceedings of a
Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago: Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, 1996 forthcoming, pp. 556-585.
Black, Harold, M. Cary Collins, and Ken B. Cyree, "Do
black-owned banks discriminate against black borrowers?" Journal of
Financial Services Research, Vol. 11, 1997 forthcoming.
Black, Harold, Robert L. Schweitzer, and Lewis Mandell,
"Discrimination in mortgage lending," American Economic
Review, Vol. 68, May 1978, pp. 186-191.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "Regulation
BB, community reinvestment," Federal Reserve Regulatory. Services
Handbook, Vol 3, 1995, section 228.
-----, "Processing procedures for Home Mortgage Disclosure
Act," technical memo, No. 96, 1995.
Boorman, J. T., and Myron L. Kwast, "The startup experience of
minority-owned commercial banks: A comparative analysis," Journal
of Finance, Vol. 29, 1974, pp. 1123-1142.
Bradbury, Katherine, Karl E. Case, and Constance R. Dunham,
"Geographic patterns of mortgage lending in Boston, 1982-87,"
New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston,
September/October 1989, pp. 3-30.
Brimmer, A.I., "The black banks: An assessment of performance
and prospects," Journal of Finance, Vol. 26, 1971, pp. 379-405.
Browne, Lynn Elaine, and Geoffrey M. B. Tootell, "Mortgage
lending in Boston - A response to the critics," New England
Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, September/October 1995,
pp. 53-78.
Calomiris, Charles W., Charles M. Kahn, and Stanley D. Longhofer,
"Housing-finance intervention and private incentives: Helping
minorities and the poor," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking,
Vol. 26, August 1994, pp. 634-674.
Canner, Glenn B., "Redlining: Research and federal legislative
response," Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, staff
study, No. 121, 1982.
Canner, Glenn B., Stuart A. Gabriel, and J. M. Woolley, "Default
risk and mortgage redlining: A study of the FHA and conventional loan
markets," Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 58, July 1991, pp.
249-262.
Canner, Glenn B., and Wayne Passmore, "Residential lending to
low-income and minority families: Evidence from the 1992 HMDA
data," Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 80, February 1994, pp.
79-108.
-----, "Home purchase lending in low-income neighborhoods and to
low-income borrowers," Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 81, February
1995a, pp. 71-103.
-----, "Credit risk and the provision of mortgages to
lower-income and minority home buyers," Federal Reserve Bulletin,
Vol. 81, November 1995b, pp. 989-1016.
-----, "The relative profitability of commercial banks active in
lending in lower-income neighborhoods and to lower-income
borrowers," Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Structure and
Competition, Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1996 forthcoming,
pp. 531-555.
Carr, James H., and Isaac F. Megbolugbe, "The Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston study on mortgage lending revisited," Journal of
Housing Research, Vol. 4, 1993, pp. 277-314.
Clair, Robert, "The performance of black-owned banks in their
primary market areas," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas, 1988, pp. 11-20.
Coplan, Stephen, "HUD offers minority lending data on
Internet," American Banker, August 6, 1996, p. 11.
Dahl, Drew, "Ownership changes and lending at minority banks: A
note," Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 20, August 1996, pp.
1288-1301.
Day, Ted, and Stanley J, Liebowitz, "Mortgages, minorities, and
HMDA," University of Texas at Dallas, unpublished manuscript, March
18, 1996.
Dedman, William, "The color of money," Atlanta
Constitution, four-part series, May 1-4, 1988.
Esty, Benjamin C., "South Shore Bank: Is it the model of success
for community development banks?" Proceedings of a Conference on
Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, May 1995, pp. 192-217.
Evanoff, Douglas D., and Lewis M. Segal, "Strategic responses to
bank regulation: Evidence from HMDA data," Journal of Financial
Services Research, Vol. 11, 1997 forthcoming.
Ferguson, Michael F., and Stephen Peters, "What constitutes
evidence of discrimination?" Journal of Finance, Vol. 50, June
1995, pp. 739-748.
General Accounting Office, Community Reinvestment Act: Challenges
Remain to Successfully Implement CRA, Washington: Government Printing
Office, 1995.
-----, Fair Lending: Federal Oversight and Enforcement Improved but
Some Challenges Remain, Washington: Government Printing Office, 1996.
Garwood, Griffith L., and Dolores S. Smith, "The Community
Reinvestment Act: Evolution and current issues," Federal Reserve
Bulletin, Vol. 79, April 1993, pp. 251-267.
Glennon, Dennis, and Mitchell Stengel, "An evaluation of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston's study of racial discrimination in
mortgage lending," Comptroller of the Currency, working paper, No.
94-2, 1994.
Holmes, Andrew, and Paul Horvitz, "Mortgage redlining: Race,
risk, and demand," Journal of Finance, Vol. 49, March 1994, pp.
81-99.
Horne, David K., "Evaluating the role of race in mortgage
lending," FDIC Banking Review, Vol. 7, 1994, pp. 1-15.
-----, "Mortgage lending, race, and model specification,"
Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol. 11, 1997 forthcoming.
Hula, Richard C., "Neighborhood development and local credit
markets," Urban Affairs Quarterly, Vol. 27, 1991, pp. 249-267.
Hunter, William C., and Mary Beth Walker, "The cultural affinity
hypothesis and mortgage lending decisions," Journal of Real Estate
Finance and Economics, Vol. 13, 1996, pp. 57-70.
Hutchinson, Peter M., James R. Ostas, and J. David Reed, "A
survey and comparison of redlining influences in urban mortgage lending
markets," AREUEA Journal, Vol. 5, 1977, pp. 463-472.
Interagency Regulatory Task Force, "Policy statement on
discrimination in lending," Federal Register, April 15, 1994, pp.
18266-18274.
Kwast, Myron L., "New minority-owned commercial banks - A
statistical analysis," Journal of Bank Research, Vol. 12, 1981, pp.
37-45.
Kwast, Myron L., and Harold A. Black, "An analysis of the
behavior of mature black-owned commercial banks," Journal of
Economics and Business, Vol. 35, 1983, pp. 41-54.
Lacker, Jeffrey M., "Neighborhoods and banking," Economic
Quarterly, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Spring 1995, pp. 13-37.
Lash, Nicholas, and Larry R. Mote, "Early evidence on banking in
low- and moderate-income minority areas: A case study," paper
presented at the Western Economics Association, Vancouver British
Columbia, June 29, 1994.
Liebowitz, Stanley J., "A study that deserves no credit,"
Wall Street Journal, September 1, 1993.
Lindsey, Lawrence B., "Home ownership opportunities in a
deregulatory environment," Marketwise, Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond, No. 1, 1996, pp. 20-27.
Macey, Jonathan R., and Geoffrey P. Miller, "The Community
Reinvestment Act: Economic analysis," Virginia Law Review, Vol. 79,
March 1993, pp. 291-348.
Malmquist, David, Clifford Rossi, and Fred Phillips-Patrick,
"The economics of lending to low-income mortgages," Journal of
Financial Services Research, Vol. 11, 1997 forthcoming.
Megbolugbe, Isaac F., and Man Cho, "An empirical analysis of
metropolitan housing and mortgage markets," Journal of Housing
Research, Vol. 4, 1993, pp. 191-223.
Munnell, Alicia H., Geoffrey M. B. Tootell, Lynn E. Browne, and James
McEneaney, "Mortgage lending in Boston: Interpreting HMDA
data," Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, working paper, No. 92-7,
1992.
-----, "Mortgage lending in Boston: Interpreting HMDA
data," American Economic Review, Vol. 86, March 1996, pp. 25-54.
Perle, Eugene D., Kathryn Lynch, and Jeffrey Horner, "Model
specification and local mortgage market behavior," Journal of
Housing Research, Vol. 4, 1993, pp. 225-243.
Rosenblatt, Eric, "A reconsideration of discrimination in
mortgage underwriting with data from a national mortgage bank,"
Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol. 11, 1997 forthcoming.
Ross, Stephen L., "Flaws in the use of loan defaults to test for
mortgage discrimination and FHA loan performance," Cityscape, Vol.
2, February 1996, pp. 41-48.
Schill, Michael H., and Susan M. Wachter, "A tale of two cities:
Racial and ethnic geographic disparities in home mortgage lending in
Boston and Philadelphia," Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 4,
1993, pp. 245-275.
Seiberg, Jaret, "Efforts to halt mortgage bias seen finally
bearing fruit," American Banker, July 31, 1996a, p. 1.
-----, "HMDA: Five years later," American Banker, 4-part
series, September 16-20, 1996b.
Shlay, Anne B., "Not in that neighborhood: The effects of
population and housing on the distribution of mortgage finance within
the Chicago SMSA," Social Science Research, Vol. 17, 1988, pp.
137-163.
-----, "Financing community: Methods for assessing residential
credit disparities, market barriers, and institutional
reinvestment," Journal of Urban Affairs, Vol. 11, 1989, pp.
201-223.
Stengel, Mitchell, and Dennis Glennon, "Evaluating statistical
models of mortgage lending discrimination: A bank-specific
analysis," Comptroller of the Currency, working paper, No. 95-3,
1995.
Tootell, Geoffrey, "Defaults, denials, and discrimination in
mortgage lending," New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston, September/October 1993, pp. 45-51.
U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban
Affairs, "Discrimination in home mortgage lending," hearing
before the 101st Congress, first session, Washington: Government
Printing Office, October 24, 1989, p. 1.
White, Lawrence J., "The Community Reinvestment Act: Good
intentions headed in the wrong direction," Fordham Urban Law
Journal, Vol. 20, November 1993, pp. 281-292.
Wilke, John R., "Mortgage lending to minorities shows a sharp
1994 increase," American Banker, February 13, 1996, p. 1.
Yezer, Anthony M. J., Fair Lending Analysis: A Compendium of Essays
on the Use of Statistics, Washington: American Bankers Association,
1995.
Yezer, Anthony M.J., Robert F. Phillips, and Robert P. Trost,
"Bias in estimates of discrimination and default in mortgage
lending: The effects of simultaneity and self-selection," Journal
of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 9, November 1994, pp.
197-215.
Zandi, Mark, "Boston Fed's bias study was deeply
flawed," American Banker, August 19, 1993, p. 13.
Douglas D. Evanoff and Lewis M. Segal are economists at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago. They would like to thank John Bergstrom,
Raphael Bostic, Paul Calem, Glenn Canner, and Lorrie Woos for helpful
comments on earlier drafts, and Pat Dykes for her generous data support.
They also acknowledge the technical assistance of Jonathan Siegel.