Regional employment growth and the business cycle.
Rissman, Ellen R.
Introduction and summary
The purpose of this article is to study the sources of regional
employment fluctuations in the U.S. and to shed light on the
interactions of these regional fluctuations with the aggregate economy.
Many studies of regional employment growth have analyzed the effect of
regional differences in a number of underlying factors, such as local
government expenditures and tax policy, while controlling for aggregate
economic activity. My analysis focuses alternatively on the role of
regional fluctuations in determining aggregate economic activity.
Macroeconomists have tended to concentrate on the impact of changes
in aggregate factors in determining the business cycle. [1] Such
aggregate factors have included, for example, fiscal and monetary
policy, the role of consumer confidence, aggregate supply and demand,
and productivity. Yet there is a growing literature that suggests that
aggregate disturbances are the result of a variety of influences. [2] In
the work introduced here, I explicitly consider the role of regional
employment fluctuations in determining the business cycle. I do not
specifically identify the sources of such regional shocks. They could be
the result of changing federal governmental policies, for example,
immigration or defense spending, that impinge upon certain areas of the
country more than others. They could also reflect changes in local
welfare programs or shifts in local fiscal and tax policy.
The analysis is complicated by the fact that while regional
fluctuations may have aggregate repercussions, aggregate factors
influence regional growth as well. For example, general productivity
shocks are likely to have broad consequences across a variety of
industries and geographical areas that are reflected in regional
employment growth. Ascertaining what movements in employment growth are
common across regions and what are region-specific would be helpful for
policymakers. If, for example, regional employment growth is largely
unrelated to employment growth in other regions, a more regional policy
focus might be appropriate. Examples of more localized policy would
include differential taxation and spending programs that are coordinated
within a region or a more geographically targeted approach to federal
government spending. If, however, most regional employment growth is
common across regions, a more centralized policy process is warranted.
The business cycle has been conceptualized as "expansions
occurring at about the same time in many economic activities, followed
by similarly general recessions, contractions, and revivals which merge
into the expansion phase of the next cycle." [3] Thus, the business
cycle is characterized by comovements among a variety of economic
variables and is observable only indirectly. Only by monitoring the
behavior of many economic variables simultaneously can one quantify the
business cycle. For example, recessions are typically associated with
declining output and employment across broadly defined industries. It is
this notion of comovement that has supplied the foundation for measuring
cyclical activity. This is the practice behind the widely publicized National Bureau of Economic Research's (NBER) dating of business
cycles and Stock and Watson's (1988) index of coincident economic
indicators.
While most analyses of the business cycle focus on the notion of
comovement in employment or output across industries, a great deal of
comovement exists across geographical regions as well. Yet, until
recently this regional cyclicality has gone largely unexplored, with a
few notable exceptions such as Altonji and Ham (1990), Blanchard and
Katz (1992), Clark (1998), and Clark and Shin (1999). The reason for the
lack of interest in the regional cycle has largely been the belief that
whatever cyclicality a geographical region experiences is due in large
part to its industrial mix and to common aggregate shocks. In fact,
regional shocks are typically not considered in assessing the business
cycle.
Altonji and Ham (1990) investigate the effect of U.S., Canadian
national, and sectoral shocks on Canadian employment fluctuations at the
national, industrial, and provincial level. They find that sectoral
shocks account for only one-tenth of aggregate variation, with
two-thirds of the variation attributable to U.S. disturbances and
one-quarter to Canadian shocks. The relatively small importance of
sectoral fluctuations in describing aggregate variation in Canadian data
suggests that regional shocks have little effect on the business cycle.
The conclusion holds true for Canada but the study does not necessarily
apply to the U.S. economy, in which external shocks presumably play less
of a role.
In a model similar to Altonji and Ham (1990), Clark (1998) attempts
to quantify the roles of national, regional, and industry-specific
shocks on regional employment growth for U.S. data. Contrary to the
traditional view that regional fluctuations are unimportant in
determining the aggregate and the results of Altonji and Ham (1990) for
Canada, Clark finds that "roughly 40 percent of the variance of the
cyclical innovation in any region's employment growth rate is
particular to that region." [4] He goes on to show that these
regional shocks tend to propagate across regions. Clark's
conclusion is that heterogeneous regional fluctuations have possibly
important implications for business cycle study. Although valuable, the
methodology he employs does not permit the construction of actual
estimates of regional disturbances, which hampers his ability to clarify
the underlying causes of the regional shocks.
In this article, I develop and estimate a model of regional
employment growth aimed at understanding the role of the aggregate
economy. Each region's employment growth is assumed to depend upon
a common factor, thought of here as the business cycle. [5] This common
factor is not directly observable, but is inferred through the
comovements of employment growth across a number of regions
simultaneously. This does not mean that each region responds in the same
manner to cyclical fluctuations. Some regions will be more cyclically
sensitive while others are less. Accordingly, the methodology permits
the cycle to have a differential impact on regional employment growth.
The methodology I employ is similar to that in Rissman (1997) and
utilizes a statistical technique known as the Kalman filter. The
research here is akin to Clark's in that it is an attempt to
isolate the effects of the business cycle and regional disturbances on
regional employment growth. However, I expressly model the business
cycle as a common factor affecting all regions and some more than
others. A measure of the business cycle develops naturally from the
estimation of the model and is based solely upon the comovements in
employment growth across census regions. In addition, I estimate
regional employment shocks, which are useful for elucidating the reasons
behind regional differences in economic growth.
In summary, while aggregate fluctuations are an important force
behind regional employment growth, local disturbances contribute
significantly as well. The role of such local shocks is not uniform
across regions. My estimates indicate that almost 60 percent of the
steady state variance in employment growth in the West South Central
region is attributable to local fluctuations. This compares with only
about 10 percent in East South Central, where aggregate conditions are
the driving force.
My results suggest that regional employment growth can be described
remarkably well by a simple model in which a common business cycle has a
differential impact upon the various regions. Measures of the business
cycle from this approach are quite consistent across models and agree
quite well with more typical measures of the business cycle. The main
difference between this measure and other such measures is that this one
relies upon regional employment data alone, while other measures may
take into consideration a wide variety of other factors, such as
productivity.
Interestingly, errors made in forecasting employment growth in the
West South Central region appear to have some predictive content for
forecasting employment growth in most other regions. This suggests that
there is something unique about this region's economy that is not
currently captured by the model but that does have aggregate
repercussions. This might be due to the region's reliance on the
oil industry. My analysis implies that regional policies may be an
important tool in managing the economy. However, more research on the
nature of the spillovers across regions would be required to support
economic policy targeting specific regions.
Data
In formulating a model of regional employment growth, a necessary
first step is to observe the patterns in the data. The Bureau of Labor
Statistics (BLS) collects regional employment statistics from its
Employment Survey for the following nine census regions: New England,
Mid-Atlantic, East North Central, West North Central, South Atlantic,
East South Central, West South Central, Mountain, and Pacific. [6]
Figure 1 shows annualized quarterly employment growth for each of the
nine census regions from 1961:Q1 to 1998:Q2. (The construction is
explained in box 1.) It is clear from the figure that some regions
consistently exhibit high employment growth (for example, South
Atlantic, East South Central, West South Central, Mountain, and
Pacific), while other regions consistently exhibit below-average
employment growth (New England, Mid-Atlantic, East North Central, and
West North Central). [7]
In addition to differences in mean employment growth, regional
employment growth exhibits an apparent cyclical pattern. Typically,
employment growth declines during a recession (shaded areas in figure 1)
and increases in an expansion. [8] This cyclical pattern shows up quite
clearly in all regions but is less pronounced in some. Specifically, the
Pacific and Mountain states appear to be less affected by the business
cycle than a more typical Rust Belt region such as East North Central.
This is not to say that employment growth does not decline here as well,
but in these regions contractions are associated with smaller declines.
Closer inspection of figure 1 shows that regional employment growth
appears to have a random component in addition to a cyclical one. For
example, the West South Central region experienced a marked decline in
employment growth in the mid-1980s. This decline was echoed in a few
other regions, but was nowhere as pronounced as in West South Central.
In fact, regions such as the Mid-Atlantic, East North Central, South
Atlantic, and Pacific experienced relatively little negative impact at
that time.
In modeling the effect of the business cycle on regional employment
growth it is useful to know how the business cycle affects the regional
economy through other less-direct avenues. For example, the cycle may
affect the distribution of employment across regions. Figure 2 exhibits
regional employment growth net of aggregate employment growth. A
negative number for a region indicates that that region's
employment share of the aggregate is shrinking. Conversely, a positive
number shows that that region's employment is growing relative to
the aggregate. The figure shows that trends in employment growth seem to
persist for long periods. For example, the Rust Belt New England region
experienced below national average employment growth for most of the
earlier part of the data period. This decline was temporarily reversed
in the 1980s--the much-vaunted "Massachusetts miracle."
However, the New England recovery was short-lived, as shown by the
subsequent pronounced decline in New England's employment share.
The Mid- Atlantic states lost ground as well over most of the period. In
contrast, employment growth in the Mountain states was above the
national average, with the exception of a brief period in the mid-1960s
and again in the mid-1980s.
The employment shares in figure 2 do not appear, at least by casual
observation, to behave cyclically. It is not the case that a given
region's relative importance in the composition of aggregate
employment is affected systematically by the business cycle. This is in
direct contrast to the evidence on industries, where the composition of
total employment shifts away from goods-producing and toward
service-producing industries during contractions. Although regions show
periods of expansion and contraction, at first blush the timing of these
"regional cycles" is unlike the timing of the familiar
business cycle. If a business cycle is described by comovements in a
number of series, it is difficult to describe what these comovements
might be from looking at net regional employment growth alone.
At times, statistical relationships can be difficult to ascertain
by casual observation of the data at hand. To investigate a more complex
model of the cyclicality of net regional employment growth, I perform a
regression exercise in which net regional employment growth is assumed
to depend upon lags of net regional employment growth and whether the
economy is in a contraction as defined by the NBER. (The form of the
regression is shown in box 2.) Table 1 shows the results of these simple
ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions. A significant negative or
positive number in the CONTRACT column indicates that, even after
accounting for dynamics through lags of own-region net employment
growth, the state of the aggregate economy has an additional impact upon
net employment growth. In the case of a negative number, the
region's employment share shrinks during a contraction. Conversely,
a positive number suggests that the region's employment share
expands during a contraction.
From table 1, clearly business cycle contractions as defined by the
NBER are not particularly good at explaining regional net employment
growth after accounting for serial correlation in the dependent
variable. Most of the estimates are not significantly different from
zero. The exceptions are Mid-Atlantic, East North Central, and Mountain.
In the East North Central region, comprising Ohio, Indiana, Michigan,
Wisconsin, and Illinois, employment shares typically decline in a
recession. Furthermore, the estimated effect for East North Central is
quite large compared with the other regions. In the Mid-Atlantic and
Mountain regions, employment shares tend to rise during a contraction.
The [R.sup.2] statistic is a measure of the fit of the regression. The
closer this number is to unity, the better the data fit the estimated
equation. The high values of [R.sup.2] suggest that most of the
variation in net regional employment growth is accounted for by lags in
the dependent variable.
Industry effects
To summarize, the data on regional employment growth suggest that
the business cycle affects regional employment growth directly and to a
far lesser extent through its effect on the distribution of employment
across regions. It has long been observed that the business cycle
systematically affects the distribution of employment across industries.
[9] One possible explanation for the cyclicality of regional employment
growth is that certain regions are dominated by specific industries. To
the extent that this is true, then the regional cycles found in
employment growth merely mirror the effects of the business cycle on the
regional industry mix and, thus, there is relatively little role for
regional fluctuations or shocks to explain the patterns in the data. Box
3 shows how state industry employment data can be used to evaluate this
issue.
Changes in state employment are dominated by two effects. First,
there is the effect of shifting industry employment on employment within
the state, holding the contribution of the state in employment within
the industry constant. The second effect measures the importance of
shifting the state's contribution to each industry, holding
aggregate industry employment constant. The first effect can be thought
of as an industry effect while the second can be thought of as a state
effect. If state effects are not important, then an analysis of
employment growth by geographical region is unlikely to yield any
insight into business cycles. If, however, a significant portion of the
change in employment within a state is state-specific, a regional
analysis is likely to provide further information.
Table 2 shows the relative importance of each of these two factors
for all states except Hawaii. Specifically, the table shows the portion
of the normalized change between 1985:Q1 and 1998:Q2 in employment in
state s attributable to changing industry employment and changing
employment shares, respectively. [10] The industry categories are
mining, construction, manufacturing, trade, services, transportation and
public utilities, government, and finance, insurance, and real estate.
The goal is to analyze how important state and industry effects are in
explaining state employment changes. A full set of data on all states
with the exception of Hawaii is available from 1982:Q1 forward. To avoid
evaluating employment over two different phases of the business cycle, I
analyze changes in state employment between 1985:Ql and 1998:Q2.
The evidence provided in table 2 supports Clark's (1998)
contention that location-specific shocks are important. For example,
about 58 percent of the increase in employment in Arizona is
attributable to within-industry employment growth. However, the
remaining 42 percent of the increase is the result of a shifting
industrial mix within the state. Although the effect of changing
aggregate industrial employment dominates, the importance of the
changing industrial composition within the state is not insignificant in
most instances, most often leading to increases in state employment.
Some states, notably Alaska, California, Connecticut, Illinois,
Louisiana, Maryland, Massachusetts, New Jersey, New York, North Dakota,
Oklahoma, Pennsylvania, Rhode Island, Vermont, West Virginia, and
Wyoming, would have experienced an even larger increase in employment
between 1985:Q1 and 1998:Q2 except that employment shares shifted
adversely. New York appears to be somewhat of an outlier with employment
gains being offset to a large extent by shifts in employment shares:
Manufacturing employment as a share of total state employment fell
precipitously, while employment in finance, insurance, and real estate
grew quickly.
The state industry employment data suggest that employment growth
is only partly explained by industry effects and that a good portion of
state employment changes results from location-specific factors. It
follows that changes in local employment do not simply reflect the local
industrial mix, but also have a significant location-specific component.
This adds another dimension to our understanding of regional employment
growth.
The model
The evidence above indicates that regional employment growth is
driven in large part by a common business cycle. Furthermore, regional
shocks are important even after accounting for changing aggregate
industrial composition. Let annual employment growth in region i,
[y.sub.it], have the following specification:
[y.sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.i] + [[[beta].sup.i].sub.0][C.sub.t] +
[[[beta].sup.i].sub.1][C.sub.t-1] + [[[beta].sup.i].sub.2][C.sub.t-2] +
[[gamma].sub.i][y.sub.it-1] + [[epsilon].sub.it],
where [[alpha].sub.i] is a constant, [C.sub.t] is a variable meant
to capture the business cycle, [[[beta].sup.i].sub.0],
[[[beta].sup.i].sub.1], [[[beta].sup.i].sub.2] are coefficients
measuring the effect on [y.sub.it] of current and lagged values of the
business cycle (that is, [[beta].sup.i](L)[C.sub.t] =
[[[beta].sup.i].sub.0][C.sub.t] + [[[beta].sup.i].sub.1][C.sub.t-1] +
... + [[[beta].sup.i].sub.p][C.sub.t-p], where p=2), [[gamma].sub.i] is
a coefficient on lagged own-region employment growth, and
[[epsilon].sub.it] is an independent and identically distributed random
variable with mean 0 and variance [[[sigma].sup.2].sub.i], i = 1, ...,
I.
The business cycle is assumed to affect each region differently in
terms of both timing and magnitude. This differing effect is captured
parsimoniously by the coefficients [[[beta].sup.i].sub.0],
[[[beta].sup.i].sub.1], [[[beta].sup.i].sub.2]. Those regions that are
less cyclical have values of the [[[beta].sup.i].sub.j] parameters that
are closer to 0. Those regions that lag the cycle have estimates of
[[[beta].sup.i].sub.j] that are insignificantly different from 0 for
small j.
Finally, I assume that one cannot observe the business cycle
directly, but instead must infer it through its effects on regional
employment growth across all regions simultaneously. [11] I assume that
the cycle follows an AR(2) specification so that:
[C.sub.t] = [[phi].sub.1][C.sub.t-1] + [[phi].sub.2][C.sub.t-2] +
[u.sub.t].
The error term [u.sub.t] is assumed to be serially independent and
identically distributed with mean 0 and variance of
[[[sigma].sup.2].sub.u]. The imposition of an AR(2) process for the
business cycle provides a succinct way of allowing for a business cycle
that is characterized by recessions followed by expansions.
To completely specify the model, it is necessary to assume
something about the two types of shocks, [u.sub.t] and
[[epsilon].sub.it], where [u.sub.t] can be thought of as a business
cycle shock and [[epsilon].sub.it] is a regional disturbance.
Specifically, I assume that the cyclical shock and the regional
disturbances are mean 0, serially uncorrelated, and uncorrelated with
each other. Box 4 provides a detailed discussion of the estimation.
Results
As currently specified, the model is not identified without
additional restrictions. [12] Neither the scale nor sign of the business
cycle is defined. To see this, suppose that the common cycle [C.sub.t]
is rescaled by multiplying it by some constant b, and define
[[C.sup.*].sub.t] = [bC.sub.t]. Then [[C.sup.*].sub.t] =
[[phi].sub.1][[C.sup.*].sub.t] + [[phi].sub.2][[C.sup.*].sub.t] +
[[u.sup.*].sub.t], where [[u.sup.*].sub.t] = [bu.sub.t] and
var([[u.sup.*].sub.t]) = [b.sup.2][[[sigma].sup.2].sub.u]. I fix the
scale by setting [[[sigma].sup.2].sub.u] to 1 and choose the sign so
that [[beta].sub.0] is positive in the East North Central region. In
fact, the parameter [[beta].sub.0] turns out to be positive in all
regions. This is the natural normalization because we define a boom to
be a state when economic activity is high.
Additional assumptions are required to pin down the timing of the
cycle. Following Stock and Watson (1989), I normalize by restricting the
business cycle to enter only contemporaneously in at least one region j,
that is, [[[beta].sup.j].sub.1] = [[[beta].sup.j].sub.2] = 0. This
region has been set arbitrarily as East North Central. [13]
The results reported in table 3 are for the model described above,
in which two lags of [C.sub.t] are included (that is, [[beta].sup.i](L)
is second order). The estimation uses quarterly data from 1961:Q2 to
1998:Q3 for the nine census regions. [14]
According to the model, movements in the regional employment growth
rate reflect macroeconomic conditions, local dynamics, and idiosyncratic fluctuations that are specific to the region. What kind of growth rates should the regions experience over the long term in the absence of
cyclical fluctuations and regional shocks? The expected long-term
regional growth rate depends upon both the constant [[alpha].sub.i] and
the coefficient on the lagged dependent variable [[gamma].sub.i].
Specifically,
E([y.sub.i]) = [[alpha].sub.i]/(1-[[gamma].sub.i]
From this computation, the West South Central, South Atlantic, and
Mountain regions have had the highest growth rates on average, with mean
growth over this period of 3.05 percent, 3.09 percent, and 3.74 percent,
respectively. The Rust Belt regions of New England, Mid-Atlantic, and
East North Central have had the lowest employment growth, recording
annual percentage increases of 1.51 percent, 1.01 percent, and 1.98
percent, respectively.
The parameter [[[beta].sup.i].sub.0] reflects the contemporaneous effect of the business cycle on region i's employment growth. These
estimated coefficients (reported in column 2 of table 3) are positive
and significant for all regions. The East North Central and East South
Central regions are the most cyclically sensitive, exhibiting the
largest estimated values for [[beta].sub.0]. The West South Central
region is by far the least cyclically sensitive contemporaneously with
an estimated [[beta].sub.0] of only 0.8406, so that an increase in
[C.sub.t] of one unit is associated with a less than 1 percent increase
in regional employment growth contemporaneously.
Technically, the Kalman filter and maximum likelihood estimation
provide a way to obtain estimates of the business cycle, [C.sub.t],
conditional on information prior to time t. I apply a Kalman smoothing
technique that uses all available information through the end of the
sample period to generate smoothed estimates of [C.sub.t]. These
estimates of the cycle are also referred to as two-sided estimates since
they reflect both past and future data. [15]
The process generating the business cycle is estimated as
[C.sub.t] = 0.6036[C.sub.t-1] (0.1029) + 0.0123[C.sub.t-2] (0.0822)
+ [u.sub.t]
and is shown in figure 3 for the smoothed estimates. The estimated
employment cycle roughly corresponds to the timing of the NBER business
cycle in the sense that contractions occur at approximately the same
time as the NBER recessions. Interestingly, business cycle peaks as
measured here typically precede the NBER-dated peaks and recoveries tend
to precede the NBER-dated recoveries. This is particularly notable in
light of the fact that the measure of cyclical activity constructed here
is based upon employment data alone. It is a well-known empirical
regularity that employment lags the business cycle. This can be seen
from carefully comparing real gross domestic product (GDP) growth and
aggregate employment growth in figure 4. So cyclical measures
constructed from employment data alone might be reasonably expected to
lag as well. As figure 3 shows, however, this hypothesis is not
supported by the data.
Given the high real GDP growth rates of recent quarters, as shown
in figure 4, we might expect the business cycle to be abnormally high
over this period. Instead, the estimated cycle suggests business
conditions are currently hovering around neutral. The reason for the
apparent disparity is quite simple. The business cycle as constructed
here depends solely upon comovements in regional employment growth.
However, employment growth has recently been close to its long-term
average, as is also apparent in figure 4. The employment-based measure
of the business cycle constructed here reflects this trend employment
growth as implying neutral economic conditions.
GDP has exhibited such strong growth in recent quarters because of
the increase in productivity of the economy and not because of any
substantive increase in employment growth. High productivity growth will
tend to increase output without a concomittant rise in employment. This
is what appears to have happened in the latter part of the sample.
Conversely, when productivity growth is low and employment growth
remains stable, output-based measures of the cycle are likely to show
deeper recessions than employment-based measures.
What happens to regional employment growth when the economy
experiences an aggregate onetime shock, that is, a change in the common
shock [u.sub.i]? A positive cyclical shock of one standard deviation in
magnitude increases the cycle by a unit of 1 at the time it occurs.
This, in turn, affects regional employment growth contemporaneously. The
following quarter the shock disappears but its effects linger and are
felt in two ways. First, the shock has an evolving effect on the
business cycle through its autoregressive structure. [16] This effect
translates into movements in regional employment growth that also evolve
over time. Second, the shock affects regional employment growth through
the lag of regional employment growth (feedback).
Figure 5 traces the effect of a one standard deviation one-time
aggregate business cycle shock on the cycle and also on regional
employment growth. The effect of the aggregate disturbance on the
business cycle itself dissipates smoothly over time. The regions'
responses show more complicated dynamics, with the largest impact being
felt at the same time the disturbance occurs and one quarter thereafter.
The effect then fades over time. (In the West South Central region, the
shock's initial effect is smaller but the effect lingers slightly
longer than in other regions.)
In East North Central, for example, the cyclical shock
contemporaneously increases employment growth by 1.75 percent per annum relative to its long-term average. The following quarter as these other
feedbacks influence regional employment growth, the effect remains about
the same at 1.71 percent, despite the value of the shock returning to 0.
However, as time progresses, the cyclical shock's effect fades so
by the seventh quarter following the shock, employment growth in the
East North Central region is only 0.14 percent higher per annum than it
would have been in the absence of the disturbance.
Recall that the variance of the cyclical shock has been scaled to
equal
unity. Because the current state of the economy depends upon past
realizations of the business cycle as well as the aggregate shock, its
variance will reflect these dynamics. The variance of [C.sub.t] is
computed as
var([C.sub.t]) = (1 - [[phi].sub.2])/(1 + [[phi].sub.2]) [[(1 -
[[phi].sub.2]).sup.2] - [[[phi].sup.2].sub.1]] = 1.596.
Consequently, a one unit increase in u corresponds approximately to
a one standard deviation shift in the cycle of [(1.596).sup.1/2] =
1.263.
Table 4 illuminates the relative importance of the business cycle
and the regional idiosyncratic shocks in explaining the variance of each
region's employment growth. (The calculations are shown in box 5.)
Clearly, regional shocks are more important in some regions than in
others. In West South Central, for example, the regional shock accounts
for almost 60 percent of the variance in the region's employment
growth rate. Regional idiosyncratic shocks account for a somewhat
smaller but still sizable proportion of the total variance in New
England, Mid-Atlantic, Mountain, and Pacific. This compares with East
South Central, where almost 90 percent of the region's total
variance is attributable to variance in the aggregate shock. The East
North Central, West North Central, and South Atlantic regions appear to
be influenced in large part by the aggregate shock.
The model has been estimated under the assumption that the regional
disturbances are uncorrelated with each other for all leads and lags and
are serially uncorrelated. This is a strong assumption and a test is
useful to assess the validity of the estimated model. According to the
model estimated above, all comovement is ascribed to the common cyclical
shock. If the model is true, then errors made in forecasting regional
employment growth in one region should not be useful for predicting
regional employment growth in another region. One can construct a simple
diagnostic test in which the estimated one-step-ahead forecast errors in
a region's employment growth are regressed against lags of the
one-step-ahead forecast errors in other regions. [17] If the model
describes the data well, lags of another region's forecast errors
should not be significantly different from 0 in these regressions. In
other words, errors made in forecasting another region's employment
growth should not significantly aid in the predicti on of a given
region's employment growth.
In table 5, p-values are reported for the regressions described
above, testing for the significance of forecast error lags. If the model
fits the data well, the p-values should be large. Small p-values
indicate that the independent variable has some predictive content for
the dependent variable. Because of natural variation, we would expect
about 10 percent of the regressions (that is, eight or nine) to have
p-values of less than 0.100 even if the hypothesis was true. Table 5
shows that, in fact, ten of the regressions show significantly low
p-values. More significantly, most of these low p-values are in
regressions involving the predictive content of forecast errors in the
West South Central region.
One obvious reason why the West South Central region may wield such
influence in regional employment growth stems from the industrial
composition of the area. The West South Central states are heavily
dependent on oil and gas production. Disturbances to these industries,
in turn, have repercussions for other industries and regions of the
country. My results imply that, in addition to the common cyclical
factor affecting all regions, there might be another factor involved in
explaining regional employment growth patterns. This factor is likely
related to oil price shocks. Further research is necessary to test this
hypothesis.
The main advantage of estimating a Kalman filter model of the sort
presented here is its ability to obtain estimates of the underlying
cyclical and regional disturbances, as shown in figure 6. The analysis
suggests that New England experienced some positive shocks in the late
1970s and early 1980s, coinciding roughly with well-documented growth in
technology and business services at that time. However, some time in the
late 1980s, the region experienced a series of large negative shocks.
These shocks correspond to the timing of the S&L crisis and the
credit crunch. At about this time, computers were making the transition
from mainframe to desktop and some larger New England employers were
cutting back their labor force in large numbers. Employment growth in
New England has recovered to some extent and is approximately in line
with what is predicted by the model. [18]
The Mid-Atlantic region is heavily influenced by New York. Regional
employment growth has held fairly steady, with the stock bust of 1987
causing lower employment growth. The East North Central region
experienced a large negative disturbance during the period surrounding
the first oil price shock and smaller negative ones in 1978 and in 1980.
For much of the 1980s through mid-1990s, employment growth shocks in
this area were small and tended to be positive. This likely reflects the
bottoming out of the farm crisis in 1986 and strong export growth. The
farm crisis also appears to have had an effect on employment growth in
the West North Central region. The West South Central region appears to
have more volatility, and experienced a large negative disturbance in
the mid-1980s. This shock is most likely the result of the oil price
bust, followed by a recovery in the industry. Finally, the Pacific
region was hit by a series of negative shocks in the early 1990s due to
cutbacks in defense spending. [19] The Pacif ic region seems to have
recovered to a large extent.
Conclusion
The business cycle is not observable directly. Instead, it must be
inferred from observing many data series simultaneously. Casual
observation suggests that all regions experience some cyclicality in
employment growth, despite the fact that some regions show above-average
employment growth over long periods and other regions consistently
report below-average employment growth. The fact that these regions move
more or less in tandem over time provides a way to construct a measure
of the business cycle.
In this article, I define the business cycle as co-movements in
regional employment growth. I estimate the cycle using the Kalman filter
and maximum likelihood techniques. The estimates of the cycle obtained
from the model are quite consistent and conform with more traditional
measures of the business cycle, for example, GDP growth or the
unemployment rate.
Because employment growth is distinct from productivity growth, the
estimates of the cycle do not exhibit the large expansion in the most
recent period that output-based measures do. In fact, current estimates
of the business cycle show that the economy is well balanced, in the
sense that there are no cyclical shocks that seem to be expanding or
contracting regional employment growth above or below long-term
averages. If employment growth contributes to inflation, this balance in
the economy seems to imply that, despite high output growth, inflation
is under control.
Sectoral disturbances appear to be an important determinant of
regional employment growth--at least in some regions. This is
particularly true for the West South Central, Mountain, Pacific, New
England, and Mid-Atlantic states. Regional shocks play a far less
important role in explaining regional employment growth in the East
North Central, West North Central, South Atlantic, and East South
Central regions, where most of the movements are related to aggregate
fluctuations.
There are obviously many ways one could define the business cycle.
The tack taken here is to define it relative to regional employment
growth patterns. This is not to say that all other information should be
excluded from the analysis. However, the focus on an employment-based
measure helps shed light on regional issues. Furthermore, a comparison
of an employment-based cyclical measure versus an output-based measure
may aid in our understanding of productivity.
Finally, the methodology employed permits the recovery of a series
of regional employment shocks. The timing of such disturbances may be
helpful for assessing what factors may explain regional declines or
expansions that are not anticipated by long-term patterns or cyclical
influences. Although speculative, it appears that oil shocks and defense
contracts might help explain the origin of regional shocks. The model
estimated here is somewhat simplistic, in that it does not allow for
regional spillovers that are not accounted for by the aggregate shock.
By examining the regional disturbances that the model estimates and
formulating a better notion of the underlying economics behind these
regional shocks, one could develop a richer understanding of regional
dynamics.
Ellen R. Rissman is an economist in the Economic Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The author would like
to thank Ken Housinger for his research assistance. She is particularly
indebted to Ken Kuttner for his insight and for providing the basic
statistical programs. Dan Sullivan, David Marshall, Joe Altonji, and
Bill Testa provided many thoughtful comments. The author would also like
to thank the seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
for their patience and suggestions.
NOTES
(1.) A comprehensive list is outside the scope of this article. A
few references include Barro (1977, 1978), Mishkin (1983), Gordon and
Veitch (1986), and Litterman and Weiss (1985).
(2.) Blanchard and Watson (1986).
(3.) Mitchell (1927).
(4.) Clark (1998), p. 202.
(5.) A more appropriate nomenclature might be the "employment
cycle" since it is constructed by filtering out the common
movements in employment across regions. In contrast, the
"business" cycle is typically modeled as comovements in less
narrowly focused series. For example, Stock and Watson (1989) construct
their Coincident Economic Index with reference to industrial production,
total personal income less transfer payments in 1982 dollars, total
manufacturing and trade sales in 1982 dollars, and employees on
nonagricultural payrolls.
(6.) The New England states are Maine, New Hampshire, Vermont,
Massachusetts, Connecticut, and Rhode Island. Mid-Atlantic contains New
York, Pennsylvania, and New Jersey. East North Central comprises
Wisconsin, Michigan, Illinois, Indiana, and Ohio. South Atlantic
contains Maryland, Delaware, Virginia, West Virginia, North Carolina,
South Carolina, Georgia, and Florida. East South Central states are
Kentucky, Tennessee, Alabama, and Mississippi. West South Central
contains Oklahoma, Arkansas, Louisiana, and Texas. The East North
Central states are Minnesota, Iowa, Nebraska, Kansas, North Dakota,
South Dakota, and Missouri. The Mountain states are Montana, Idaho,
Wyoming, Nevada, Utah, Colorado, Arizona, and New Mexico. Pacific
contains Alaska, Hawaii, Washington, Oregon, and California.
(7.) These trends have been noted by previous researchers,
including Blanchard and Katz (1992).
(8.) The timing of the cyclical upturns and downturns in regional
employment growth is somewhat different from that proposed by the NBER
dating. It is well known that employment reacts with a small lag to
cyclical events so, for example, the trough of the recessions is
typically a short time after the NBER dating of the trough.
(9.) This observation was made by Mitchell (1927).
(10.) Seasonally unadjusted data are reported monthly by the BLS
and are available on the BLS Labstat website. Calculations were carried
out using quarterly data that have been seasonally adjusted using the
PROC X11 procedure. Hawaii has been omitted from the calculations due to
a lack of data for mining.
(11.) A richer model might incorporate other cyclical series as
well, such as gross domestic product (GDP) or industry employment.
However, because the objective is to describe regional employment
patterns, the business cycle is constructed by looking at comovements in
regional employment patterns alone.
(12.) The discussion here follows Harvey's (1989) analysis of
common trends.
(13.) A more subtle point is raised in Stock and Watson (1989).
Given three data series that are serially uncorrelated but are
correlated with each other, it is always possible to restructure the
model with a single index. This common factor captures the covariance of
the three series. Over-identification occurs when there are more than
three observable variables (there are nine here) or when the variables
are serially correlated.
(14.) The BFGS algorithm was used in maximizing the likelihood
function. In practice, numerical difficulties arose in which the Hessian
matrix failed to invert when the model was estimated with the sole
restriction that lags of the cycle do not enter into the East North
Central Region. The problem was resolved by restricting the South
Atlantic region to depend solely upon the contemporaneous cycle as well.
(15.) Details of this procedure can be found in chapter 4 of Harvey
(1989).
(16.) The evolution of the business cycle following a temporary one
standard deviation shock is found in the first panel of figure 5.
(17.) The one-step-ahead forecast error is simply defined as:
[e.sub.it] [congruent to] [y.sub.it] - [y.sub.it/t-1],
where the forecast error [e.sub.u] is calculated as the difference
between the actual regional employment growth rate at time t and the
model's prediction of regional employment growth based upon
information up to time t - 1.
(18.) Bradbury (1993) examines employment over the 1990-91
recession and the recovery in New England.
(19.) See Gabriel et al. (1995) for a discussion of migration
trends in California.
REFERENCES
Altonji, Joseph G., and John C. Ham, 1990, "Variation in
employment growth in Canada: The role of external, national, regional,
and industrial factors," Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 8, No. 1,
Part 2, January, pp. S198-S236.
Barro, Robert, 1978, "Unanticipated money, output, and the
price level in the United States," Journal of Political Economy,
Vol. 86, August, pp. 549-580.
__________, 1977, "Unanticipated money growth and unemployment
in the United States," American Economic Review, Vol. 67, March,
pp. 101-115.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Lawrence F. Katz, 1992, "Regional
evolutions," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1,
Washington: Brookings Institution, pp. 1-61.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Mark Watson, 1986, "Are business
cycles all alike?," in The American Business Cycle, Robert Gordon (ed.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 123-156.
Bradbury, Katharine L., 1993, "Shifting patterns of regional
employment and unemployment: A note," New England Economic Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, September/October, pp. 3-12.
Burns, Arthur F., and Wesley C. Mitchell, 1946, Measuring Business
Cycles, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Clark, Todd E., 1998, "Employment fluctuations in U.S. regions
and industries: The roles of national, region-specific, and
industry-specific shocks," Journal of Labor Economics, January, pp.
202-229.
Clark, Todd E., and Kwanho Shin, 1999, "The sources of
fluctuations within and across countries," in Intranational Macroeconomics, Gregory D. Hess and Eric van Wincoop (eds.), Cambridge,
New York, and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press, chapter 9.
Gabriel, Stuart A., Joe P. Mattey, and William L. Wascher, 1995,
"The demise of California reconsidered: Interstate migration over
the economic cycle," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, No. 2, pp. 30-45.
Gordon, Robert J., and John Veitch, 1986, "Fixed investment in
the American business cycle, 1919-83," in The American Business
Cycle, Robert J. Gordon (ed.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp.
267-335.
Hamilton, James D., 1994, Time Series Analysis, Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Harvey, Andrew C., 1989, Forecasting Structural Time Series Models
and the Kalman Filter, Cambridge, New York, and Melbourne: Cambridge
University Press.
Litterman, Robert, and Lawrence Weiss, 1985, "Money, real
interest rates and output: A reinterpretation of postwar U.S.
data," Econometrica, Vol. 53, January, pp. 129-156.
Mishkin, Fredrick, 1983, A Rational Expectation Approach to
Macroeconomics: Testing Policy Ineffectiveness and Efficient Market
Models, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Mitchell, Wesley, C., 1927, Business Cycles: The Problem and Its
Setting, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Rissman, Ellen R., 1997, "Measuring labor market turbulence," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, Vol. 21, No. 3, May/June, pp. 2-14.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson, 1989, "New indexes of
coincident and leading economic indicators," in NBER Macroeconomics
Annual 1989, Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press,
pp. 351-394.
__________, 1988, "A probability model of the coincident
economic indicators," National Bureau of Economic Research, working
paper, No. 2772.
Effect of timing of NBER contractions on
regional employment growth less aggregate
employment growth, OLS
Region CONTRACT [R.sup.2]
New England 0.1170 0.9281
Mid-Atlantic 0.1345 [**] 0.8851
East North Central -0.3581 [***] 0.8541
West North Central 0.0272 0.8207
South Atlantic 0.0540 0.8686
East South Central -0.0458 0.8393
West South Central 0.1444 0.9394
Mountain 0.1561 [*] 0.9267
Pacific -0.0308 0.8436
Notes: The regression equation estimated by OLS is:
[n.sub.it] = c + a(L)[n.sub.it-1] + [b.sup.*]CONTRACT +
[[epsilon].sub.it],
where CONTRACT takes on the value of 1 during an NBER contraction
and is 0 otherwise; a(L) is a polynomial in the lag operator with a
maximum lag length of four. (***.)indicates significance at the 1
percent level; (**.)indicates significance at the 5 percent level; and
(*.)indicates significance at the 10 percent level.
Source: Author's calculations based on data from the U.S.
Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, database at
ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/time.series and the National Bureau of Economic
Research database available on the Internet at www.nber.org.
Changes in employment in state s, 1985:Q1-98:Q2
Industry effect State effect
Alabama 0.80 0.20
Alaska 1.20 -0.20
Arizona 0.58 0.42
Arkansas 0.63 0.37
California 1.20 -0.20
Colorado 0.76 0.24
Connecticut 7.74 -6.74
Delaware 0.74 0.26
Florida 0.73 0.27
Georgia 0.65 0.35
Hawaii n.a. n.a.
Idaho 0.57 0.43
Illinois 1.31 -0.31
Indiana 0.76 0.24
Iowa 0.84 0.16
Kansas 0.82 0.18
Kentucky 0.67 0.33
Louisiana 1.78 -0.78
Maine 1.07 -0.07
Maryland 1.48 -0.48
Massachusetts 3.85 -2.85
Michigan 0.91 0.09
Minnesota 0.80 0.20
Mississippi 0.73 0.27
Missouri 0.99 0.01
Montana 0.91 0.09
Nebraska 0.89 0.11
Nevada 0.48 0.52
New Hampshire 1.06 -0.06
New Jersey 2.54 -1.54
New Mexico 0.81 0.19
New York 36.32 -35.33
North Carolina 0.63 0.36
North Dakota 1.15 -0.15
Ohio 1.03 -0.03
Oklahoma 1.34 -0.34
Oregon 0.60 0.40
Pennsylvania 1.87 -0.87
Rhode Island 4.89 -3.89
South Carolina 0.67 0.33
South Dakota 0.70 0.30
Tennessee 0.67 0.33
Texas 0.89 0.11
Utah 0.53 0.47
Vermont 1.15 -0.15
Virginia 0.82 0.18
Washington 0.61 0.39
West Virginia 1.11 -0.11
Wisconsin 0.73 0.27
Wyoming 1.76 -0.75
Notes: See box 3 for the exact calculations.
n.a. indicates not available.
Source: Author's calculations based on data from the
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, database at ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/time.series.
Regional employment growth model with lagged dependent variable
Cycle Cycle
Current 1 quarter 2 quarters
Region Constant cycle ago ago
New England 0.3711 [**] 1.1428 [***] -0.1332 -0.5495 [***]
(0.1605) (0.1207) (0.1650) (0.1218)
Mid-Atlantic 0.3520 [**] 1.1286 [***] -0.4275 [***] -0.0985
(0.1668) (0.1092) (0.1528) (0.0980)
East North Central 1.2952 [***] 1.8330 [***] 0.0000 0.0000
(0.4102) (0.1450) -- --
West North Central 1.8999 [***] 1.0579 [***] 0.5853 [***] 0.0050
(0.4076) (0.1025) (0.1570) (0.0632)
South Atlantic 1.8717 [***] 1.2708 [***] 0.0000 0.0000
(0.3251) (0.1157) -- --
East South Central 2.2168 [***] 1.7102 [***] 0.4925 [**] -0.2914 [**]
(0.5117) (0.1359) (0.2760) (0.1401)
West South Central 0.7077 [***] 0.8406 [***] -0.2395 [*] -0.1880 [*]
(0.2087) (0.1207) (0.1544) (0.1204)
Mountain 1.3379 [***] 1.0218 [***] -0.1161 -0.3058 [***]
(0.2923) (0.1271) (0.1715) (0.1246)
Pacific 1.1861 [***] 1.0751 [***] -0.2514 [*] -0.0295
(0.2921) (0.1327) (0.1720) (0.1366)
Lagged Standard
regional deviation of
employment regional
Region growth shock
New England 0.7535 [***] 1.1183 [***]
(0.0559) (0.0710)
Mid-Atlantic 0.6529 [***] 0.9122 [***]
(0.0719) (0.0633)
East North Central 0.3457 [***] 1.1718 [***]
(0.0822) (0.0869)
West North Central 0.1164 0.8563 [***]
(0.0948) (0.0614)
South Atlantic 0.3939 [***] 0.9549 [***]
(0.0514) (0.0696)
East South Central 0.1411 0.9026 [***]
(0.1198) (0.0757)
West South Central 0.7683 [***] 1.2456 [***]
(0.0526) (0.0750)
Mountain 0.6418 [***] 1.2519 [***]
(0.0642) (0.0766)
Pacific 0.5606 [***] 1.3016 [***]
(0.0721) (0.0809)
Notes: The dependent variable is measured as annualized quarterly
regional employment growth rates. Regional employment growth is assumed
to depend upon a constant, the current and two lags of the state of the
economy, and a single lag of own-region employment growth. Maximum
likelihood estimates are reported. Standard errors are in parentheses.
(***.)indicates marginal significance below 1 percent; (**.)indicates
marginal significance below 5 percent; and (*.)indicates marginal
significance below 10 percent. The mean log-likelihood is 6.48760 at the
maximum.
Steady state regional employment growth variance
due to cycle and shock, 1961:Q2-98:Q3
Steady state Percent Percent
employment of variance of variance
growth from cyclical from regional
Region variance shock shock
New England 7.3284 60.5 39.5
Mid-Atlantic 4.6298 64.8 31.3
East North Central 10.7283 85.5 14.5
West North Central 4.9939 85.1 14.9
South Atlantic 5.9623 81.9 18.1
East South Central 8.0531 89.7 10.3
West South Central 6.3430 40.3 59.7
Mountain 5.9528 55.2 44.8
Pacific 5.7963 57.4 42.6
Significance of lagged regional employment growth forecast errors
East West
New Mid- North North South
J[down arrow] I[right arrow] England Atlantic Central Central Atlantic
New England 0.083 0.288 0.652 0.650 0.381
Mid-Atlantic 0.423 0.063 0.699 0.450 0.551
East North Central 0.294 0.863 0.161 0.304 0.074
West North Central 0.997 0.973 0.769 0.834 0.273
South Atlantic 0.693 0.766 0.735 0.767 0.698
East South Central 0.934 0.612 0.410 0.209 0.931
West South Central 0.219 0.214 0.007 0.070 0.003
Mountain 0.706 0.380 0.538 0.942 0.713
Pacific 0.501 0.026 0.271 0.339 0.744
East West
South South
J[down arrow] I[right arrow] Central Central Mountain Pacific
New England 0.639 0.189 0.762 0.336
Mid-Atlantic 0.385 0.639 0.500 0.786
East North Central 0.438 0.316 0.200 0.678
West North Central 0.885 0.250 0.878 0.839
South Atlantic 0.987 0.860 0.854 0.330
East South Central 0.721 0.693 0.970 0.651
West South Central 0.008 0.749 0.031 0.048
Mountain 0.885 0.403 0.599 0.345
Pacific 0.692 0.190 0.480 0.382
Notes: The table reports p-values for OLS regressions of the form:
[e.sub.it] = c + [[beta].sub.1][e.sub.jt-1] +
[[beta].sub.2][e.sub.jt-2]+...+ [[beta].sub.6][e.sub.jt-6] + [v.sub.t],
where [e.sub.it] and [e.sub.jt] are the estimated one-step-ahead
forecast errors at time t for regional employment growth and i, j = 1,
..., 9. The p-values reported in the table are the significance levels
for the test of the null hypothesis that the [beta] coefficients are 0.
Low p-values indicate that the hypothesis is not consistent with the
data. Numbers in bold indicate a p-value less than 0.100.
Annual employment growth and net annual employment growth
Employment growth in region i at time t, [y.sub.it]' is
calculated as:
[y.sub.it] [congruent to] log([e.sub.it]/[e.sub.it-4]) x 100,
where [e.sub.it], is employment in region i at time t. Define net
employment growth [n.sub.it] as the difference between regional
employment growth and aggregate employment growth. Specifically,
[n.sub.it] [congruent to] [y.sub.it] - [y.sub.t]
[n.sub.it] = [log([e.sub.it]/[e.sub.it-4]) -
log([e.sub.t]/[e.sub.t-4])],
where [e.sub.t] is defined as aggregate employment at time t and
[y.sub.t] is aggregate employment growth.
OLS regression testing effect of contractions on net employment
growth
Let CONTRACT be a dummy variable taking on the value 1 during an
NBER contraction and 0 elsewhere. The OLS regression equation is of the
form:
[n.sub.it] = c + a(L)[n.sub.it-1] + [b.sup.*]CONTRACT +
[[epsilon].sub.it].
Four lags of the dependent variable have been included and are
generally enough to ensure that the error term is serially uncorrelated.
Effect of industry composition on state employment
Define [[e.sup.s].sub.i](t) as employment in industry i in state s
at time t. Define
[[k.sup.s].sub.i](t) [congruent to]
[[e.sup.s].sub.i](t)/[e.sub.i](t)
as the share of industry i's employment in state s. These
numbers sum to unity over all states. The larger the share in a given
state, the more important that state is in the employment of that
particular industry. Employment in state s at time t, [e.sup.s](t), can
be calculated as:
[e.sup.s](t) = [[sigma].sub.i][[k.sup.s].sub.i](t)[e.sub.i](t),
which says that total state employment is the sum of employment in
each industry within that state.
Now define the difference [[delta].sub.[tau]] as:
[[delta].sup.[tau]] x(t) [congruent to] x(t) - x(t-[tau]).
Applying the difference operator to the expression for state
employment yields:
[[delta].sup.[tau]][e.sup.s](t) =
[[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][e.sub.i](t)[[k.sup.s].sub.i](t) +
[[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][[k.sup.s].sub.i](t)[e.sub.i](t) -
[[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][[k.sup.s].sub.i](t)[[delta].sup.[t
au]][e.sub.i](t).
From this expression, the change in state employment between
periods t-[tau] and t can be separated into three different effects. The
first term to the right of the equal sign reflects the effect of
changing industry employment while keeping the share of industry
i's employment while keeping the share of industry I's
employment in state s constant. An example will help clarify this
construct. Suppose aggregate manufacturing employment declines, this
effect calculates the effect of declining aggregate manufacturing
employment on employment within a given state, holding the share of that
state's contribution to total manufacturing employment constant. No
secondary effects are permitted whereby the distribution of
manufacturing across states has been altered.
The second term captures the effect of changing employment shares
in industry I in state s while keeping total industry employment
constant. Suppose that employment remains constant over time but that
the importance of a given state in its contribution to the total
changes. This second term calculates the effect of this shift on
employment within that state. Finally, the third term is an interaction
term that permits both state industry employment shares and industry
employment to vary together. Because it is calculated by multiplying
together two changes, it is smaller in magnitude than the first two
effects and will be dominated by the first two terms in the expression.
Rearranging terms,
[[delta].sup.[tau]][e.sup.s](t) +
[[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][[k.sup.s].sub.i](t)[[delta].sup.[t
au]][e.sub.i](t) = [[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][e.sub.i](t)[[k.sup.s].sub.i](t) + [[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][[k.sup.s].sub.i](t)[e.sub.i](t)
or
1 = [[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][e.sub.i](t)[[k.sup.s].sub.i](t) + [[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][[k.sup.s].sub.i](t)[e.sub.i](t)/[[ delta].sup.[tau]][e.sup.s](t) +
[[sigma].sub.i][[delta].sup.[tau]][[k.sup.s].sub.i](t)[[delta].sup.[t
au]][e.sub.i](t)
This expression says that the normalized sum of the two effects
should be unity.
Estimation details
The Kalman filter is a statistical technique that is useful in
estimating the parameters of the model specified above. These parameters
include [[alpha].sub.i], [[[beta].sup.i].sub.k], [[gamma].sub.i],
[[phi].sub.1], [[phi].sub.2], [[[sigma].sup.2].sub.u],
[[[sigma].sup.2].sub.i] & for i = 1, ..., I and for k = 1, ...,p. In
addition, the Kalman filter enables the estimation of the processes
[u.sub.t] and [[epsilon].sub.it] and the construction of the unobserved
cyclical variable [C.sub.t]. The Kalman filter requires a state equation
and a measurement equation. The state equation describes the evolution
of the possibly unobserved variable(s) of interest, [z.sub.t], while the
measurement equation relates observables [y.sub.t] to the state.
The vector [y.sub.t] is related to an m x 1 state vector,
[z.sub.t], via the measurement equation:
[y.sub.t] = [Cz.sub.t] + D[[epsilon].sub.t] + [Hw.sub.t],
where t = 1,..., T; C is an N x m matrix; [[epsilon].sub.t] is an N
x 1 vector of serially uncorrelated disturbances with mean zero and
covariance matrix [I.sub.N]; and [w.sub.t] is a vector of exogenous,
possibly predetermined variables with H and D being conformable
matrices.
In general, the elements of [z.sub.t] are not observable. In fact,
it is this very attribute that makes the Kalman filter so useful to
economists. Although the [z.sub.t] elements are unknown, they are
assumed to be generated by a first-order Markov process as follows:
[z.sub.t] = [Az.sub.t-1] + [Bu.sub.t] + [Gw.sub.t]
for t= 1,..., T, where A is an m x m matrix, B is an m x g matrix,
and [u.sub.t] is a g x 1 vector of serially uncorrelated disturbances
with mean zero and covariance matrix [I.sub.g]. This equation is
referred to as the transition equation.
The definition of the state vector [z.sub.t] for any particular
model is determined by construction. In fact, the same model can have
more than one state space representation. The elements of the state
vector may or may not have a substantive interpretation. Technically,
the aim of the state space formulation is to set up a vector [z.sub.t]
in such a way that it contains all the relevant information about the
system at time t and that it does do by having as small a number of
elements as possible. Furthermore, the state vector should be defined so
as to have zero correlation between the disturbances of the measurement
and transition equations, [u.sub.t] and [[epsilon].sub.t].
The Kalman filter refers to a two-step recursive algorithm for
optimally forecasting the state vector [z.sub.t] given information
available through time t-1, conditional on known matrices A, B, C, D, G
and H. The first step is the prediction step and involves forecasting
[z.sub.t] on the basis of [Z.sub.t-1]. The second step is the updating
step and involves updating the estimate of the unobserved state vector
[z.sub.t] on the basis of new information that becomes available in
period t. The results from the Kalman filtering algorithm can then be
used to obtain estimates of the parameters and the state vector
[z.sub.t] employing traditional maximum likelihood techniques. [1]
The model of regional employment growth proposed above can be put
into state space form defining the state vector [z.sub.t] = ([C.sub.i],
[C.sub.t-1], [C.sub.t-2])[minutes];[y.sub.t] =
([y.sub.1t],...,[y.sub.1t])[minutes]. The system matrices are given
below:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[[epsilon].sub.t] = ([[epsilon].sub.1t] [[epsilon].sub.2t]
[[epsilon].sub.9t])' [w.sub.t] = (1 [y.sub.1t-1] [y.sub.2t-1]
[y.sub.9t-1])'.
The Kalman filter technique is a way to optimally infer information
about the parameters of interest and, in particular, the state vector
[z.sub.t], which in this case is simply the unobserved cycle, [C.sub.t],
and its two lags. The cycle as constructed here represents that portion
of regional employment growth that is common across the various regions,
while allowing the cycle to differ in its impact on industry employment
growth in terms of timing and magnitude through the parameters of
[[beta].sub.i](L). The model is very much in the spirit of Burns and
Mitchell's (1946) idea of comovement but the estimation technique
permits the data to determine which movements are common and which are
idiosyncratic. [2]
(1.) The interested reader may obtain further details in Harvey
(1989) and Hamilton (1994).
(2.) Stock and Watson (1989) is a recent illustration of the Kalman
filtering technique for constructing the business cycle.
How important are regional shocks?
The steady state variance of regional employment growth reported in
table 4 is, in general, a complicated function depending upon the
variance of the idiosyncratic shock, the variance of the cyclical
disturbance, the cross-correlation structure between regions, and the
dynamics of the model. To construct a measure of the steady state
variance of regional employment growth, first rewrite the model in terms
of a vector AR(1) process. Specifically, let [z.sub.t] = ([y.sub.1t],
[y.sub.2t], ..., [y.sub.9t], [C.sub.t+1], [C.sub.t], [C.sub.t-1])'
and rewrite the model as:
[z.sub.t] = [pi][z.sub.t-1] + [v.sub.t],
where [v.sub.t] = ([[epsilon].sub.1t], [[epsilon].sub.2t], ...,
[[epsilon].sub.9t], [u.sub.t], 0, 0)' and the matrix [pi] is formed
as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where the matrix [gamma] has [[gamma].sub.1] ..., [[gamma].sub.9]
along the diagonal and 0 elsewhere, and A is defined in box 4. Let the
variance-covariance matrix of [v.sub.t] and [z.sub.t] equal [sigma] and
[omega], respectively. Then
[omega] = [pi][omega][pi]' + [sigma],
which has the following solution:
vec([omega]) = [[I - ([pi] x [pi])].sup.-1] vec([sigma]).
In this case the total steady state variance of a region's
employment growth is the sum of two terms, one reflecting the variance
of the idiosyncratic regional shock, and the other reflecting the
variance of the cyclical disturbance. Calculating the percentage
attributable to each of the two shocks follows easily.