Assessing the jobless recovery.
Aaronson, Daniel ; Rissman, Ellen R. ; Sullivan, Daniel G. 等
Introduction and summary
By all measures, employment growth since the recession that ended
in November 2001 has been surprisingly weak. But exactly how weak and
why have been the subjects of much discussion. In this article, we
review the evidence on recent employment trends, provide some new
evidence on the role of self-employment, and offer some thoughts on the
strengths and weaknesses of several proposed explanations of the causes
of what many have called a jobless recovery.
Differing estimates of employment growth from the Bureau of Labor
Statistics' (BLS) two monthly surveys have led to some controversy
over exactly how weak the labor market has been over the last few years,
with the survey of households suggesting somewhat more upbeat labor
market conditions than the survey of business establishments. In order
to understand the differences in the estimates of employment growth, it
is helpful to first adjust for the fact that the two surveys differ in
the employment concept they are attempting to estimate. The biggest such
difference is that the household survey attempts to measure the number
of unincorporated self-employed workers, while the payroll survey does
not. Because self-employment has been growing in recent years, this
difference in coverage accounts for a portion of the difference in
employment growth estimates.
Some analysts have pointed to the growth of self-employment as a
hopeful sign of increased entrepreneurial activity. Undoubtedly, many of
the newly self-employed are entrepreneurs who will be significant
employers in the future. But, we suggest that for some, self-employment
is likely a temporary status, which they will quickly relinquish when
labor market conditions improve. This seems especially likely in the
case of those self-employed individuals who have not incorporated their
businesses.
To better understand the nature of the increase in self-employment,
we study its relationship with unemployment. Looking across states, as
well as over time, we find that higher unemployment rates tend to imply
higher rates of unincorporated self-employment. Moreover, when we use
our estimates to predict by how much self-employment should have risen
given trends in unemployment over the last few years, the results
explain a good part of the observed increase since the end of the last
expansion. Therefore, this share of the increase in self-employment is
likely a reflection of the weak labor market conditions of the last
three years.
Even after subtracting the number of unincorporated self-employed
workers and making other adjustments to align the household survey
estimate of employment with the employment concept of the payroll
survey, significant differences remain in recent employment growth
estimates. Much of this gap is due to a sizable difference in employment
counts that developed between 1998 and 2002 that has since receded.
Therefore, interpreting recent growth rates, say during the recovery,
depends very much on which survey we believe is more accurate. As we
discuss in detail below, each survey measure has some potential
weaknesses.
In the case of the payroll data, the most significant potential
source of error is likely in estimates of the difference between
employment in newly opened and newly closed establishments. For such
estimates, the BLS is forced to rely on a statistical model rather than
hard data. However, the BLS has benchmarked the payroll survey estimates
to a nearly full count of paid employment through March 2003. Thus, if
there is a pickup in employment that has been missed by the payroll
survey, it has occurred in the last year.
In the case of the household data, the biggest potential source of
error is likely in the estimates of the population by which the
survey's estimates of the employment-population ratio are
multiplied. Unmeasured flows of immigrants can seriously bias such
estimates of the population, and lead to corresponding biases in
estimates of total employment. As we discuss, this latter problem is
probably more serious. For this and other reasons discussed below, we
put greater faith in the payroll survey.
This article concludes by reviewing a list of explanations that
analysts have given for the jobless recovery. These include the
possibility of an increased need for sectoral labor reallocation, the
emergence of just-in-time hiring practices, the rising cost of health
care benefits, a fall in labor supply, and the failure of aggregate
demand to keep pace with more rapid productivity growth. The evidence in
support of the various theories is quite meager. We offer some highly
speculative thoughts on their strengths and weaknesses, arguing that
sectoral reallocation, health insurance costs, and falling labor supply
are unlikely to be major culprits, but that just-in-time hiring and
inadequate aggregate demand likely have played a larger role in the weak
hiring trends. Ultimately, however, we are forced to conclude that it is
not yet clear what forces have kept employment from growing more
robustly in the last two years.
Employment trends
Figure 1 plots the level of payroll employment since 1960. The
shaded bars identify recession periods as defined by the National Bureau
of Economic Research (NBER). For example, the NBER believes the most
recent recession began (the peak) in March 2001 and ended (the trough)
in November 2001. (1) For the vast majority of these 43 years, payroll
employment is a coincident indicator of economic activity, falling when
the economy is contracting (shaded areas) and rising when the economy is
expanding (nonshaded areas).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
To show this cyclical feature more clearly, figure 2 charts
employment during the 12 months before and the 28 months after cyclical
troughs. The T refers to the month of the cycle trough. Months prior to
the end of the recession (including the recession itself) are
represented by the negative numbers to the left of the T, and months
after the end of the recession ("the recovery") are
represented by the positive numbers to the right of the T. For example,
month 12 is the twelfth month into the recovery whereas month -12 is the
twelfth month before the end of the recession. Employment levels are
given relative to the value at the trough.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The light orange line in figure 2 gives the average path of
employment during the five recessions and recoveries of the 1960s,
1970s, and 1980s. Contrary to recent experience, employment began
growing almost immediately after the end of these recessions. (2)
Twenty-six months into the recovery, where we stand as of this writing,
employment was, on average, 5.4 percent higher than the trough month and
3.6 percent higher than the previous expansion's employment peak.
However, following the 1990-91 recession (represented by the dark
orange line), employment continued to fall. It was 14 months into the
recovery before employment returned to the level of the trough and an
additional nine months before it exceeded the previous expansion's
employment peak. As of January 2004, 26 months into this recovery (the
black line in figure 2), the economy has yet to reach the employment
level of the November 2001 trough and is almost 2 percent or 2.4 million
jobs below the March 2001 employment peak.
An even gloomier picture emerges for total hours worked. The
average workweek, at least for the 80 percent of the work force that the
BLS labels production or nonsupervisory workers, has been slow to
recover relative to previous recoveries. (3) The index of total
production worker hours is 1.7 percent below the level reached at the
cycle trough and 4.9 percent below the previous expansion's
production-hours peak. By comparison, in the cycles during the 1960s,
1970s, and 1980s, after 26 months, production worker hours averaged a
gain of 6.0 percent relative to the cycle trough and 0.8 percent
relative to the previous expansion's peak.
Over the last year, a number of analysts have questioned whether
the recent employment performance has actually been as bad as is
indicated in figure 2. (4) The employment numbers in that figure are
from the Current Employment Statistics data (often referred to as the
establishment or payroll survey), a large, nationally representative
monthly survey of roughly 160,000 businesses and government agencies
covering 400,000 establishments. Two important and related measurement
issues in the payroll survey may be of particular importance around
economic turning points.
First, the survey may be slow picking up job growth due to unusual
levels of firm entry and exit. This is not to say that the BLS ignores
firm births and deaths. However, at least until final data revisions are
complete, the BLS uses a statistical model to estimate net job changes
due to firm entry and exit. It is certainly possible that these
statistical relationships are inaccurate over short periods,
particularly when births or deaths deviate from historical averages.
Second, because the survey only counts paid employees, it does not count
unpaid workers, unpaid family workers, and proprietors who own
unincorporated businesses. We discuss this measurement issue in much
more detail below. For now, we note that so long as this is a problem,
the payroll survey could understate employment growth during recoveries
by missing the acceleration of business openings, particularly
unincorporated concerns, as business conditions improve.
Those skeptical of the accuracy of the payroll survey note that
there is an alternative data source: the monthly survey of households
(the household or Current Population Survey), a nationally
representative sample of 60,000 households that is the basis for the
monthly unemployment rate. The household survey may be more timely in
accounting for business births and deaths because it simply asks
household members whether they are employed in a given month. There is
no need to find and measure new employers. Furthermore, since the
household survey counts all non-institutionalized persons, there is less
concern that it will miss subgroups of workers that are not considered
paid employees.
However, these two surveys are fundamentally different instruments
and consequently many survey concepts, including the very definitions of
who and what are being counted, differ. The household survey is a more
inclusive count of employment, including a number of categories of
workers--agricultural, private household workers, owners of
unincorporated businesses, unpaid family business employees, or those on
unpaid leave of absence (for example, maternity leave)--that are
excluded from the payroll counts. (5) Furthermore, what is actually
being tallied differs. The household survey counts the number of people
employed, while the payroll survey counts the number of jobs occupied.
Thus, in the payroll survey, multiple jobholders are counted for each
job they hold.
The quantitative importance of these distinctions is shown in
figure 3, which plots the level of employment reported by the household
(dark orange line) and payroll survey (black line). (6) The reported
level of employment in the surveys has deviated from 4.5 million to 10.5
million over the last ten years, with the gap varying to some degree
over the business cycle.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Fortunately, it is relatively straightforward to adjust for the
majority of the surveys' conceptual differences. The light orange
line in figure 3 is one such attempt by the BLS. (7) This series adjusts
the household survey count to be consistent with the coverage and
concepts (jobs rather than people at work) in the payroll survey. Once
such adjustments are made, the surveys match quite closely from 1994 to
1998, at which point the payroll survey began to grow substantially
faster than the household survey. This process reversed around 2002 to
the point where, as of January 2004, the adjusted household
survey's jobs count is higher, albeit by less than half a million
workers or 0.4 percent of total employment.
Figure 4 shows the growth in jobs recorded by the two surveys since
the NBER trough in November 2001. At that time, a fairly substantial gap
of roughly 1.9 million jobs, favoring the payroll survey, was already in
place. Since then, the adjusted household survey has made up all of this
ground and more, recording almost 2.4 million or 1.8 percent more jobs
than the payroll survey through January 2004. Household employment,
unadjusted for payroll survey coverage and concepts, surpassed the
November 2001 NBER trough level within six months; the adjusted series
reached this goal even quicker. Accordingly, some have argued that the
worst of the labor market news is a figment of the payroll data.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
That is not to say that growth in the household survey has been
especially strong either. Through January 2004, household employment had
grown 1.6 percent (unadjusted, 1.3 percent) during this recovery, well
below the typically robust growth rates of the 1960-80s recoveries.
Indeed, it is even below the substandard performance recorded in the
early 1990s jobless recovery, when the payroll and unadjusted household
surveys recorded roughly 1.8 percent and 2.5 percent gains,
respectively, through an equivalent period.
Although both surveys are useful indicators of current labor market
conditions, there are reasons to de-emphasize, although not completely
discount, the household survey estimate of employment. The payroll
survey is much larger, (8) covers a far higher fraction of employment,
and is benchmarked to a universe count of jobs from the unemployment
insurance (UI) records once a year, albeit with a lag. (9) This
benchmarking implies that the payroll survey represents a full
population of paid employees. The last such benchmarking, reported in
January 2004 and covering data through March 2003, showed little
adjustment to the jobs picture was necessary, suggesting that the
BLS's statistical model of firm births and deaths was fairly
accurate.
Furthermore, the household survey has its own measurement issues.
In particular, as detailed in Nardone et al. (2003), household
employment growth may have been overstated during the early 2000s.
Aggregate household employment growth is derived from two
statistics--the fraction of people employed (the employment-population
ratio) and the population level. The former is estimated directly from
the household survey. Population is enumerated only every ten years in
the U.S. population census and, therefore, must be estimated in
intervening years. These estimates can be subject to substantial
measurement error. Moreover, the importance of the population estimates
is particularly acute for a discussion of recent survey accuracy because
the household employment-population ratio has been falling since 2001.
Therefore, the entire increase in the household survey's employment
count is due to estimated population growth.
So why might the population estimates be off? The methodology used
to produce population estimates for years between the decennial censuses
does not account for the state of the economy. However, it is likely
that when U.S. labor market conditions are weak (relative to conditions
in home countries), fewer immigrants will enter or remain in the
country. (10) Consequently, estimated population growth may be too high
when U.S. labor market conditions are tepid. This causes the household
survey's estimate of employment growth to be too high as well.
Furthermore, overestimation of the population may have been exacerbated
by the failure to account for reductions in immigration due to the
restrictions imposed after September 11, 2001. (11) In fact, as
displayed in figure 5, the January 2004 employment release reports a
downward adjustment to population of 348,000, by far the largest of its
kind in post World War II data, based on revised estimates of net
international migration. Until the next full census count in 2010, it is
hard to gauge whether the problem has been completely fixed.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Interestingly, the large spike in January 2000 represents the
opposite dynamic resulting from the strong economy in the late 1990s.
Then, low unemployment rates likely led to there being more workers in
the country than was expected based on population projections.
Consequently, household employment estimates grew significantly slower
than payroll, a bias that was only corrected by the full 2000 Census
population count. (12)
The recent increase in self-employment
The adjusted household series in figures 3 and 4 are computed in a
way that mimics the payroll survey's coverage. Consequently,
changes in self-employment are overlooked. However, self-employment, and
in particular its recent rise, is a feature of the household survey that
has received considerable attention recently. In particular, a growing
number of commentators have pointed to the spread of self-employment as
a sign of surging entrepreneurship and, consequently, an indication of a
healthy labor market and economy. (13)
Table 1 gives some indication of the size of this recent increase,
and figure 6 charts self-employment rates in a longer historical
context. As the recession began at the end the first quarter of 2001,
roughly 9.2 million people, or 6.8 percent of nonfarm workers, reported
themselves self-employed in nonfarm sector businesses. (4) This figure
fell to 8.9 million, or just under 6.7 percent of the nonfarm work
force, by the end of the recession and continued to fall to 8.7 million
or 6.5 percent of the nonfarm work force during the first quarter of
2002, before rising to 9.5 million, or roughly 7 percent of the nonfarm
work force, by the end of 2003. Since the beginning of the recession,
the increase in self-employment has been a rather modest one-quarter of
a million workers or 0.14 percentage points on the self-employment rate.
Measured from different points, however, the increase looks more
significant. For example, since the end of the recession, over one-half
million workers have, on net, become self-employed, increasing the
self-employment rate by 0.31 percentage points. And from its recent
quarterly low in early 2002, over 800,000 more workers have become
self-employed, raising the self-employment rate by about 0.49 percentage
points.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
To evaluate whether this increase is a sign of labor market
strength, we compare the actual increases with what might be predicted
based on a simple statistical model of past relationships between the
self-employment rate and a measure of labor market conditions. This
approach is described more formally in Rissman (2003). In that paper,
the decision to become self-employed is modeled when self-employment is
a low-paying alternative to wage work. Workers are either employed in
wage work, unemployed, or self-employed and looking for wage work.
Workers shift from unemployment into self-employment if the expected
return to job search from self-employment exceeds the expected return to
job search while unemployed. Rissman argues that self-employment is
countercyclical. During a cyclical downturn, the likelihood of being
laid off rises and the probability of generating a job offer falls. In
contrast, the return to searching from self-employment remains
relatively unaffected. Consequently, in evaluating the two alternatives
of 1) searching from unemployment, and 2) establishing a business while
continuing to search, the latter option of self-employment becomes
relatively more attractive when the economy is weak. Consistent with
this hypothesis, for males aged 21 years or older, Rissman finds that
increases in local unemployment rates are associated with increases in
self-employment.(15)
As we show below, the household survey itself shows a similar
general pattern. Historically, many of these businesses form during
weaker labor markets, when wage and salary jobs are scarce, and
subsequently disappear as labor market conditions improve. Therefore, if
this historical pattern plays out again, a good part of the recent rise
in self-employment could be reversed when labor market conditions
improve.
The cyclicality of self-employment
This section provides evidence on the extent to which
self-employment is cyclical. We derive these estimates from the
household survey, which as previously noted is a representative sample
of approximately 60,000 households. Participating households are
surveyed for four months, left out of the sample survey for eight
months, and finally surveyed again for four additional months. Those
households in the fourth and eighth months of their participation are
known as the outgoing rotation groups (ORGs), and we use them in these
calculations. A major advantage of the ORGs files, relative to other
household-based samples like the Panel Study of Income Dynamics or the
National Longitudinal Surveys, is the large sample sizes, comprising
roughly 180,000 households per year. (16) However, the data only go back
to 1979, a relatively short period to evaluate. We end our analysis at
the first quarter of 2001, the end of the last expansion.
In order to evaluate the relationship between self-employment and
labor market conditions, we compute quarterly local area measures of
self-employment and unemployment rates back to 1979. Our geographic
boundary is the state, although we check the robustness of our results
to using cities, or more specifically metropolitan statistical areas
(MSAs), as well. Employing local measures of the key variables
introduces significantly more degrees of freedom to our estimation,
relative to a simple time series, by taking advantage of different
cyclical conditions across the country.
The actual regression that we run is:
1) [S.sub.it] = [alpha] + [beta][U.sub.it] + [delta]T + 1[T.sup.2]
+ [[epsilon].sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.it],
where [S.sub.it] and [U.sub.it] are the log self-employment and
unemployment rates for state i at time t, T references the quarters
elapsed since 1979, [[epsilon].sub.i] is a state-specific error term,
and [[epsilon].sub.it] is a normal disturbance term that is independent
of the other control variables. (17) We include quarterly dummies to
account for any seasonal patterns in the self-employment rate. We
eliminate the state-specific error term, [epsilon].sub.it], by including
state fixed effects. State fixed effects account for any time-invariant
unobserved characteristic of the area, in this case including laws or
customs related to state differentials in self-employment incentives or
ease of business incorporation. We use the remaining variation, how
changes in the state unemployment rates covary with changes in state
self-employment rates, to identify the cyclicality of self-employment.
Finally, we perform a number of specification checks on equation 1.
Two are particularly relevant. First, in this particular example,
secular trends in self-employment are captured by a national time trend.
(18) However, it is reasonable to imagine that this secular trend is
heterogeneous, related to changes in state laws, economic conditions, or
local customs. Therefore, we also estimate a version of equation 1, in
which T and [T.sup.2] are interacted with the state dummies, allowing
each state to have its own time trend.
Second, obviously not all small businesses are alike. This
heterogeneity prompts one to wonder whether it is high or low quality
firms that tend to open during booms and busts and whether this matters
in thinking about how to analyze the recent run-up in self-employment.
Unfortunately, we do not have financial measures of firm quality in the
household survey. Instead, we use an alternative proxy of quality:
whether the business is incorporated. This stratification has a second,
important advantage. Since the payroll survey includes incorporated but
not unincorporated firms, it is useful to know any distinctions between
how the two groups react to the business cycle.
Why do we link incorporation status with firm quality? The main
reason is that the cost, both in terms of the entrepreneur's time
and the direct outlays required to form and dissolve a corporation, is
likely to discourage businesses with an expected short window. Granted,
the direct outlays, which vary from state to state and depend upon
whether the newly formed entity is a corporation or limited liability
corporation, are not large. For example, in Illinois, various websites
offer to incorporate an Illinois business for under $500.(19) But
combined with the potentially substantial cost of the
entrepreneur's time in the process, this may be large enough to
discourage incorporation for those with lower expected success. (20) One
would also expect that the main advantages of incorporation-personal
financial protection to investors, officers, and directors through
limited liability--are likely to be more important among larger, high
asset businesses. (21)
Table 2 provides estimates of the cyclicality of the
self-employment rate, broken down by incorporation status. Results from
two general specifications are reported in the first and second row. The
first uses a national time trend and the second allows each state to
follow its own time trend. Each cell contains two numbers, the impact of
a 10 percent increase in the unemployment rate (the elasticity [beta] x
10) and, in parentheses, the standard error attached to that point
estimate.
Under the two columns labeled "Total self-employed," we
report results when all self-employed workers, regardless of
incorporation status, are evaluated. The first column uses weighted
least squares (weighted by the size of the state's labor force)
with Huber-White and state cluster-corrected standard errors. The second
column uses a biweight robust regression technique that we prefer for
its high degree of efficiency in the face of the kind of heavy-tailed
data that we employ here. For the most part, the results are robust to
different specifications and estimation techniques: A 10 percent
increase in the local unemployment rate increases the local
self-employment rate by about 0.1 percent to 0.2 percent, although none
of the estimates are statistically significant at standard significance
levels.
However, as we see in the next four columns, the legal type of
business matters a great deal. These columns stratify the self-employed
into those that own incorporated and unincorporated businesses. In
general, we find that there is a statistically and economically
important cyclical effect on unincorporated businesses but not on
incorporated ones. A 10 percent increase in the state unemployment rate
increases the state unincorporated self-employment rate by 0.2 percent
to 0.3 percent. However, there is no discernable effect on the
state's incorporated self-employment rate. (22)
What does this imply about the aggregate increase in
self-employment over the last two years? The last two columns of table 2
provide an answer. From the beginning of the last recession until the
end of 2003, the unemployment rate increased from 4.2 percentage points
to 5.9 percentage points or just over 40 percent. (23) Based on the
estimates reported in table 2, we would expect that such an increase in
the unemployment rate would increase the unincorporated self-employment
rate but not the incorporated rate, causing the total self-employment
rate to rise by roughly 0.05 percentage points from its early 2001
level. (24) This encompasses over one-third of the 0.14 percentage point
increase that we have seen since the first quarter of 2001. To be clear,
these predicted effects evaluate the growth of self-employment since the
beginning of the recession. The model has much less success in
forecasting the large decline and offsetting increase (see table 1) in
the intervening period.
Furthermore, given the time it takes to open a new business, there
is reason to believe that the relationship between labor market
conditions and the self-employment decision is not contemporaneous, as
we have assumed thus far. Rather, it is some combination of past labor
market conditions that matter. Consequently, we reestimated equation 1
but included four quarters of lagged unemployment rates on the right
hand side. Table 3 reports the sum of these coefficients (including the
contemporaneous estimates) and the resulting prediction for
unincorporated self-employment.
Here, we find the magnitude of the cyclicality of self-employment
to be about double that reported in table 2. For example, a 10 percent
increase in the state unemployment rate increases the state
unincorporated self-employment rate by 0.4 percent to 0.7 percent,
compared with 0.2 percent to 0.3 percent when lagged effects are not
included. Again, assuming no effect on incorporated firms, a 40 percent
increase in the unemployment rate would imply a 0.08 percentage point to
0.13 percentage point increase in the self-employment rate, explaining
almost all of the small 0.14 percentage point gain that has occurred
since early 2001.
These results suggest that a sizable portion of the rise in the
self-employment rate since the beginning of the recession is likely
related to unincorporated firms surfacing during weak economic times.
Many of these new businesses are likely to disappear when the wage and
salary sector improves.
What caused the jobless recovery?
Why has employment failed to grow more vigorously the last two
years? Analysts have suggested many theories. These include the
possibility of an increased need for sectoral labor reallocation, the
emergence of just-in-time hiring practices, the rising cost of health
care benefits, a fall in labor supply, and the failure of aggregate
demand to keep pace with more rapid productivity growth. In this
section, we briefly review these theories and offer a few, very
speculative observations on their strengths and weaknesses.
Sectoral labor reallocation
One frequently mentioned explanation for the jobless recovery is
that there is currently an unusually great need to reallocate labor
resources across sectors of the economy. The movement of large numbers
of workers from one sector to another can be necessitated by changes in
trade patterns, shifts in product demand, productivity growth, and other
factors. Such movement is a normal feature of a dynamic economy in which
some firms contract or close, while others expand or open. Indeed, the
reallocation of labor from less to more productive uses is an important
source of overall productivity gains in the economy and, thus, of rising
living standards. However, because it frequently takes substantial time
for displaced workers to find new employers, these long-term benefits
often impose substantial short-term costs. This is especially true if
jobless workers need to be retrained to acquire the skills that growing
employers seek. Thus, if the pace of sectoral reallocation had recently
risen, the result would be a temporary increase in the natural rate of
unemployment and a temporary fall in employment growth. (25)
Many analysts claim a link between the disappointing employment
growth of the last two years and international trade. Especially great
attention has been focused on the new possibilities for
"offshoring" service jobs to countries such as China and
India, facilitated by the Internet. We interpret such claims as
contending that offshoring has forced an abnormally large number of
workers to make major career changes and that the increased need for
employment transitions has temporarily reduced employment growth.
Further, some commentators suggest that offshoring permanently
lowers U.S. employment. However, this view underestimates the ability of
our economy to adjust to changing circumstances. New jobs are constantly
being created to replace those that disappear. If necessary, wages
adjust over time to ensure that the growth of employment closely matches
the growth of the labor force. History makes it clear that increased
foreign trade is no permanent barrier to employment growth. Indeed, over
the last several decades there have been continuing concerns about job
losses from the U.S., first to Japan, then to Korea, Taiwan, and South
East Asia, and more recently to Mexico. All the while, however, U.S.
employment has continued to grow.
To say that the effects of increased trade are temporary, however,
is not to say that they are unimportant. New trade patterns could force
many workers to make significant career changes, increasing the need for
costly job search and retraining. (26) The same is true of reallocation
caused by shifts in relative product demand or differences across
industries in rates of productivity growth. A large enough increase in
sectoral labor reallocation, whether due to increased trade or other
reasons, could explain the weak employment growth of the last two years.
But, has there been a major increase in reallocation? We are
skeptical. The most frequently cited evidence of such an increase is
contained in a recent article by Groshen and Potter (2003). On the basis
of an analysis of industry-level employment data, they conclude that the
need for workers to shift to new jobs "largely explains why the
payroll numbers have been so slow to rise." However in Aaronson,
Rissman, and Sullivan (2004), our other article in this issue, we argue
that the statistic proposed by Groshen and Potter is unlikely to be a
good proxy for the extent of reallocation. Moreover, when we compute a
measure based on Rissman (1997), which better captures the need for
reallocation across industries, we find that reallocation rose less
during the last two recessions than in previous downturns and that once
the recent recessions ended, reallocation returned relatively quickly to
low levels. In essence, we find that employment shares by industry are
relatively stable and that what shifts we do see are typical of the
patterns usually observed when overall labor market conditions have been
weak. Thus, we do not think that the need to reallocate workers across
industries is a likely explanation of the jobless recovery.
Our findings in Aaronson, Rissman, and Sullivan (2004) indicate
that the need to reallocate workers across industries has not been
unusually great. However, our results do not necessarily rule out an
increase in other forms of sectoral reallocation, such as those in which
workers are forced to change occupations or geographic regions. However,
as we also discuss in Aaronson, Rissman, and Sullivan (2004), there is
some evidence that overall rates of job destruction and job creation are
both at low levels, which seems inconsistent with a major role for any
form of labor reallocation. Thus, we are skeptical that any form of
sectoral reallocation provides the explanation for the jobless recovery.
Just-in-time hiring
We are more sympathetic to the theory that the employment practices
some are calling just-in-time hiring have played a role in restraining employment growth since the end of the recession. To understand this
theory, consider the staffing decisions of a firm that expects, but is
not sure, that demand for its product is about to increase. Initially,
bringing on new workers takes significant time and expense to find,
screen, and deploy. In addition, once new workers are hired, they are
expensive to let go, perhaps because of the possibility of lawsuits. The
firm faces a tough choice. On the one hand, if it increases its
employment and perhaps builds inventories, but demand turns out to be
weak, then high payroll costs will mean poor profits. On the other hand,
if the firm maintains its current level of employment but demand picks
up, then it may initially be unable to increase production in line with
orders. By the time it has increased employment, it may have missed
making some profitable sales. Firms will deal with this tradeoff in
various ways, but at least some are likely to hire workers in
anticipation of increasing demand.
Now suppose that new institutions allow the firm to bring on
additional workers on very short notice. Moreover, the workers it brings
on can be dismissed on equally short notice. This new institution makes
the firm's choice much easier. It can wait to see whether demand
picks up and, if it does, summon additional workers to increase
production. It doesn't have to worry about having unneeded workers
on its payrolls or being unable to fill new orders. Given the new
option, fewer firms are likely to hire workers and begin to build
inventories before they can verify the increase in demand.
To a significant extent, such new hiring institutions have emerged
over the period of the two jobless recoveries. The most obvious example
is the temporary services industry. When the economy was recovering from
the recessions of the early 1980s, this industry was still very small
and mainly dedicated to providing clerical workers to fill vacancies
created by temporary absences of clients' regular employees. (27)
Since then, the industry has grown very rapidly as can be seen in panel
A of figure 7 overleaf. At its peak in 2000, it accounted for 2 percent
of nonfarm payroll employment. (28) Furthermore, the nature of the
workers the industry provides to client firms has changed. It now
provides many more light industrial, call center, and technical workers
than in the mid-1980s. (29) In addition, temporary service workers are
now sometimes the majority of workers at a client's establishment.
Thus, this industry's role has expanded from one of helping clients
deal with short employee absences to one of allowing them to vary the
scale of their operation.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
The temporary services industry is not the only one adding
flexibility to firms' staffing levels. Another example is
management and technical consulting. Consultants can quickly be deployed
to a firm needing increased access to specialized skills. As panel B of
figure 7 shows, this industry has also grown rapidly in recent years.
In addition to the growth of industries that directly provide labor
services, a number of other developments have likely made it easier for
firms to hire new workers quickly. These include fax machines and the
Internet, which can speed up the process of screening potential hires,
as well as new firm that match employers and employees and maintain
enormous files of potential job candidates. (30) All together, these new
developments may reduce hiring costs and make it more feasible for firms
to hire workers "just in time" to perform needed tasks.
The increase in the flexibility of firms' hiring decisions is
at least consistent with more sluggish employment growth at the
beginning of business expansions. Such periods are characterized by much
more than the usual degree of uncertainty. Indeed, it is often not clear
how strong and broad a pickup in economic activity is. It may not even
be clear that a pickup actually has started or if there is a significant
chance of a "double dip" recession. So, it is natural for
firms to be cautious. In the absence of the new hiring institutions, the
fear of getting caught with a large work force and few orders often may
be less than the fear of not having enough workers to meet rising
demand. So firms may tend to hire and build inventories in anticipation
of demand. However, with confidence that they can increase employment
rapidly when needed or with the temporary services industry as a backup,
firms may be more likely to wait to hire until demand is definitely
strong. We cannot claim that the evidence linking the growth of flexible
employment options to the jobless recoveries is extremely strong, but
the timing is right and it agrees with at least some anecdotal evidence.
This argument for just-in-time hiring institutions having
contributed to sluggish employment growth at the beginning of expansions
does not necessarily imply that there must be a major increase in
temporary services employment during these periods. It is the option
value that temps provide to firms that restrains hiring that might
otherwise have taken place in anticipation of demand growth. However,
under this theory, if temporary services hiring picks up, it is likely
to signal a pickup in overall hiring some time later. And, in fact,
Segal and Sullivan (1997a) and others have shown that temporary services
employment is a leading indicator for overall employment growth.
Panels C and D of figure 7 show how employment in the temporary and
management and technical consulting services industries has grown over
the last two recovery periods. In 1991, temp employment was flat for
approximately half a year after the trough, but then began to grow very
steadily. This takeoff was six to nine months before that of overall
employment. After the most recent recession, temporary employment
started to grow after a few months, but then fell back, and did not
start increasing in a significant way until the summer of 2003. If the
lag between the start of its growth and that of overall employment
growth matched that of the previous cyclical episode, the jobs figures
should have begun improving around the beginning of 2004. The March
employment report indicates improvement and the relatively robust growth
of temporary services jobs is one reason for at least modest optimism
going forward.
Health care costs
Another prominent theory is that increases in health care costs
have played a significant role in restraining employment growth. (31)
There seem to be two versions of this theory. One emphasizes that rapid
growth in health care premium costs may have temporarily raised total
employment costs above equilibrium levels, thus reducing labor demand.
The other emphasizes the increase in the importance of costs that are
fixed per worker, independent of hours worked or salary level. Such
costs can lead employers to reduce employment by requiring existing
employees to work longer hours or by employing fewer, more highly
skilled workers.
Figure 8 shows the rate of increase in health care costs relative
to the overall personal consumption expenditures (PCE) deflator. Clearly
the growth in health care costs has significantly outpaced overall
consumer price inflation in recent years. Such increases in health care
prices raise the cost of employers' existing medical benefit plans
and could make hiring less attractive. This view gains some additional
support from the observation that health care costs also rose very
rapidly during early 1990s, the time of the first jobless recovery.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Two major challenges can be offered to this theory. The first is
that employers can respond to such cost increases by reducing the
generosity of health insurance benefits or by altering other aspects of
compensation such as the level of wages and salaries. Thus, an increase
in premiums does not have to lead to higher total employment costs. A
possible response to this challenge is that the adjustment of other
aspects of the employers' compensation packages can take time. In
the short run, firms might not be able to fully offset medical cost
increases with cuts elsewhere. (32)
Another challenge to the theory that rapidly rising heath insurance
costs are behind the jobless recovery is that the recent growth of total
labor compensation costs has not been particularly rapid, especially
when judged relative to productivity growth. Growth in the employment
cost index has fallen only modestly since the onset of the recession,
going from 4.1 percent for the 12 months ending in December of 2000 to
3.8 percent for the 12 months ending in December of 2003. However, other
measures of labor compensation growth have dropped by substantially
more. In particular, over the same period, the four-quarter growth of
hourly compensation in the nonfarm business sector as reported in the
productivity and costs data fell from 7.0 percent to 3.2 percent.
Moreover, this fall occurred while productivity growth was increasing
from 2.8 percent to 4.4 percent. Thus, the growth in unit labor costs,
which measure the nominal cost of producing a unit of output, fell from
4.2 percent to -1.2 percent. Unit labor costs have been falling since
the first quarter of 2002, accumulating to a 4.1 percent decline, the
largest such drop since at least the early 1960s. As a result, the share
of labor in total costs has fallen sharply since the first quarter of
2001. This drop is also the largest since the early 1960s. Given that
total labor compensation levels are not rising particularly quickly, we
do not place much weight on the possibility that rapidly rising medical
costs are boosting overall compensation costs above levels consistent
with employment growth.
What about the version of the health costs theory that points to
higher fixed costs per worker? As figure 9 shows, health insurance costs
rose from 5.4 percent of compensation in 1999 to 6.5 per-cent in 2003.
This fraction rose to similar levels during the jobless recovery of the
early 1990s before declining in the mid-1990s. So, high health costs per
worker have tended to correlate with sluggish employment growth. (33)
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
An increase in fixed costs per worker tends to give firms an
incentive to hire fewer workers, while increasing their average work
week. (34) However, the average work week has not been rising. In fact,
average weekly hours of production workers are at the same level as they
were at the trough of the recession in November 2001. It is possible
that work hours are, in fact, increasing, but that this is somehow not
being recorded in the data. But, we know of no evidence that this is the
case. Moreover, one would expect that if actual hours per worker were
rising, there would be at least some increase in measured hours as well.
Possibly, the reason average hours per worker are not rising is that
some firms have responded to higher insurance premiums by keeping more
workers' hours below the threshold they use to qualify employees
for benefits. However, if this were true then fixed benefits costs would
not be restraining employment growth. Thus, we do not find the
fixed-cost version of the employment costs theory very persuasive
either. (35)
Labor supply
Just-in-time hiring and health care costs are reasons why labor
demand may be unusually low. Logically, another possibility is that
labor supply may have declined. Under this theory, employment growth may
be lagging in part because relatively few people want to work.
As support for this theory, one might point to the unusually large
decline in labor force participation over the course of the recession
and the following two years. Historically, labor force participation has
been only modestly procyclical. But since the most recent recession
began, labor force participation has fallen substantially, from 67.1
percent (just off the all-time high) at the March 2001 peak to 65.9
percent in February 2004, the lowest value since 1988. Because of the
steep drop in labor force participation, the unemployment rate has
fallen considerably since the end of the recession even while the growth
in employment (by either the payroll or household survey measures) has
been slower than the growth in population.
An obvious objection to interpreting the decline in labor force
participation as a fall in labor supply is that it may reflect
people's discouragement over their chances of finding a job rather
than a decline in their desire to work. A corollary of this view would
be that the standard unemployment rate offers a misleading view of the
degree of slack in the labor market. However, as Barrow (2004)
discusses, relatively little of the increase in nonparticipation is
attributable to greater numbers of discouraged workers; the increase in
those out of the labor force who report wanting a job has been quite
small. Therefore, the majority of the decline in the participation rate
appears to be a genuine fall in labor supply.
Given that the drop in participation appears to a substantial
extent to represent a fall in labor supply, a quick bounce back to the
levels of late 2000 does not seem particularly likely. Rather, those
pre-recession levels may have been the result of some overshooting in
the labor market, much like the unemployment rates of 4 percent were
likely lower than the long-run equilibrium unemployment rate. Moreover,
the standard unemployment rate may not be a particularly good indicator
of labor market conditions.
Table 4 breaks down the changes in labor force participation by age
and gender. These figures suggest two groups are primarily driving the
decline. First, there has been a remarkably large fall in the labor
force participation rate of teenagers and young adults in their early
20s. The decline in teenage labor force participation since January 2001
accounts for over 0.5 percentage points, or about half, of the decline
in the economy-wide labor force participation rate. The second critical
group is women between the ages of 25 and 44. The fall in this
group's labor force participation since January 2001 accounts for
about 0.4 percentage points, or roughly 40 percent, of the aggregate
decline.
The drop in teenage and young adult labor force participation seems
especially large, recently falling to post-World War II lows among males
and 30-year lows among females. Is this a normal cyclical response to an
extended period of disappointing employment growth or a permanent shift
in the school--work decision? Table 5 offers some clues.
Here, we display the annualized growth in the share of the teen and
young adult (20 to 24) population that are in school (column 2) and not
in school (column 5). (36) Between 2000 and 2002 (latest available
data), the share of teenagers in school grew by 1.2 percent per year,
double the rate of the mid- to late 1990s, when labor markets were
strengthening. However, the share of students in the teen population was
growing even faster--l.7 percent per year--during the recession and
jobless recovery of the early 1990s. The growth in the share of young
adults 20 to 24 that are in school was roughly 2.5 percent per year
during both jobless recoveries, slightly faster than the 1990s and 1980s
expansions. So there has been a noticeable shift in school going
activity but it does not seem to be especially large, at least relative
to the previous recession.
However, there is at least one notable distinction during the most
recent period. In the remaining columns, we look at the joint decision
to be in school and in the labor force. Whereas the gain in schooling
during the early 1990s was fairly evenly split between those who
remained in the labor force and those who did not, this has not been the
case in the early 2000s. Recently, there has been a sizable increase in
the share of young people in school but not in the labor force--4.6
percent per annum for teens and 8.9 percent per annum for 20-24 year
olds--but a drop in the share both in the labor force and in school.
Thus, not only has there been a fall in labor force participation of
those not in school but, in contrast to previous patterns, of those in
school as well.
It is hard to say why this has happened. One highly speculative
explanation for the school group's behavior is that the strong
productivity growth of late 1990s might have seemed transitory as it was
occurring. Now, after almost a decade of stronger growth, it seems more
permanent. Consequently, workers expect wages to be higher in the
future. A classic "intertemporal" response to such
expectations is to work less now and more in the future. Furthermore, if
productivity growth is expected to be higher in higher skilled
occupations, we would expect an increase in school enrollments as well.
This story might also be consistent with the labor supply behavior of
secondary earners in general and, thus, help to explain some of the fall
in the labor force participation of women in the traditional
child-rearing age groups.
However, in the end, we doubt that the decline in labor supply is
the primary reason for the sluggish employment growth of the last two
years. If declining labor supply were the cause, we would expect to see
relatively strong wage growth. However, as we noted in the discussion of
health care costs, growth in labor compensation has not been
particularly strong recently, especially relative to productivity
growth. Nevertheless, even if a decline in labor supply is not the
primary cause of the jobless recovery, it may be a contributing factor.
If fewer workers had withdrawn from the labor force, the unemployment
rate would have been higher and wage growth might have fallen further.
Lower wage growth could, in turn, have led to an increase in firms'
employment of workers.
Inadequate aggregate demand growth
Probably the most frequently mentioned explanation for the weak
employment growth of the last two years is rapid productivity growth. As
can be seen in figure 10, productivity growth has been very impressive
of late. In the two years since the trough of the recession, output per
hour worked in the nonfarm business sector has risen by more than 9
percent, approximately 3.5 percentage points more than in the typical
post-recession period. Moreover, relative to the peak of the last
business cycle, productivity growth has been even more impressive, with
output per hour having risen by more than 12 percent or 5.5 percentage
points more than the typical cyclical pattern.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
Holding constant growth in output, greater growth in productivity
implies less growth in hours worked and likely, therefore, less growth
in employment. In this sense, rapid productivity growth explains weak
employment growth. However, there are no fixed speed limits to economic
growth. So, there is no reason to expect output growth to remain
constant in the face of more rapid productivity growth. Rather, economic
theory suggests that a pickup in the growth of aggregate supply induced
by more rapid productivity growth would ordinarily lead to expectations
of higher incomes and a comparable pickup in aggregate demand and output
growth. Thus, those who attribute the jobless recovery to rapid
productivity growth must implicitly be attributing it to some break in
the normal link between aggregate supply and aggregate demand.
Why should aggregate demand have failed to increase sufficiently in
response to the pickup in productivity growth? Quite possibly, demand
growth has been held back over the last two years by a series of
shocks--concerns over terrorism, the buildup to the Iraq war,
revelations of poor corporate governance, and the hangover from the fall
in the stock market. These shocks likely made firms unusually cautious
and, therefore, reluctant to invest and hire. (37) Similarly, in the
early 1990s, the savings and loan crisis may have created a credit
crunch that restrained aggregate demand and hiring. Such an
interpretation suggests that absent such post-recession shocks, future
recoveries may see employment expansions more like those before the
1990s.
Another possible explanation for the failure of demand to keep up
with the strong productivity growth of the last two years is that recent
productivity gains may owe more to the ebbing of adjustment costs
associated with previously high investment levels than to new
breakthroughs in technology that increase expectations for future
income. Under this interpretation, rapid technological advance led to
very high levels of investment in new equipment in the late 1990s. The
need to make all this new equipment work may have led in turn to what
now looks like excessive hiring. This story suggests that firms recently
have been eliminating those excesses. As a result, measured productivity
growth has been strong. But because the driver of productivity growth is
not new breakthrough technology, there is no support for additional
increases in expectations of future incomes. Thus, increased measured
productivity growth is not associated with increased aggregate demand
and hiring. Rather, employment levels might be interpreted as returning
to normal after a period in which they were temporarily elevated in
order to implement new technology.
Conclusion
This article reviews evidence on the jobless recovery. We began by
summarizing recent employment trends, showing, as has the BLS, that the
major surveys of employment can be reconciled for much of the last ten
years. But a gap developed between 1998 and 2002 that has led to
somewhat different interpretations of what has happened to the labor
market during the last three years. While we have sketched reasons to
put more weight on the survey of employers rather than households,
regardless of which survey we use employment growth has been
historically weak. Furthermore, we have provided new evidence that the
small increase in self-employment since the beginning of the recession,
which has been interpreted by some as a hopeful sign for labor markets,
is likely a reflection of the weak labor market conditions of the last
three years.
Finally, we have offered some speculative thoughts on the strengths
and weaknesses of the various explanations analysts have given for the
jobless recovery. These include the possibility of an increased need for
sectoral labor reallocation, the emergence of just-in-time hiring
practices, the rising cost of health care benefits, a fall in labor
supply, and the failure of aggregate demand to keep pace with more rapid
productivity growth. We argue that the most plausible culprits are
just-in-time hiring and inadequate aggregate demand in the face of rapid
productivity growth. Ultimately, however, we must conclude that it is
not yet clear what forces have kept employment from growing more
robustly the last two years.
Table 1
Self-employed during this recovery
Number of Self-employment
self-employed as share of nonfarm
Selected dates (thousands) payroll employment
2001:Q1
(end of last expansion) 9,245 6.84
2001:Q4
(end of recession) 8,926 6.67
2002:Q1
(self-employment 8,665 6.49
reached low)
2003:Q4 9,493 6.98
Table 2
Cyclicality of self-employment
Impact of 10% increase in the unemployment rate
Total self-employed Incorporated
Time trend WLS Robust WLS Robust
State-specific 0.24 0.12 0.18 0.13
(0.14) (0.08) (0.20) (0.16)
National 0.14 0.12 -0.45 -0.19
(0.17) (0.08) (0.24) (0.16)
Impact of 10% increase in the unemployment rate
Unincorporated
Time trend WLS Robust
State-specific 0.28 0.17
(0.15) (0.09)
National 0.37 0.29
(0.21) (0.09)
Predicted
percentage point
increase in total
self-employment rate,
2001:Q1 to 2003:Q4
(actual = 0.14)
Time trend WLS Robust
State-specific 0.05 0.03
National 0.07 0.05
Notes: These estimates are ([beta] (or standard error) x 10. WLS
regressions are weighted by state labor force size. Standard
errors (in parentheses) are Huber-White and corrected for state
clustering. Robust regressions are based on the rreg algorithm
described in StataCorp (2001). Sample used is nonfarm workers
aged 16 and over in the Current Population Survey, 1979 to first
quarter of 2001. Observations are aggregated to the state level.
Table 3 Cyclicality of unicorporated self-employment
(includes four-quarter lag in state unemployment rate)
Impact of 10%
increase in the
unemployment rate:
Sum of coefficients
Time trend WLS Robust
State-specific 0.47 0.42
(0.30) (0.25)
National 0.61 0.68
(0.48) (0.26)
Predicted percentage
point increase in
total self-employment
rate, 2001:Q1
to 2003:Q4
(actual = 0.14)
Time trend WLS Robust
State-specific 0.09 0.08
National 0.11 0.13
Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis. See table 2 for
more detail.
Table 4
Labor forse participation by age and gender
Share of the
January January % change noninstitutionalized
2001 2004 16 + population
Females January 2004
16-19 50.5 44.3 -12.3 3.6
20-24 73.6 70.1 -4.8 4.5
25-34 75.9 73.7 -2.9 8.8
35-44 77.8 75.1 -3.5 9.9
45-54 76.6 76.7 0.1 9.4
55+ 26.4 30.1 13.9 15.6
Males
16-19 53.0 44.5 -16.0 3.7
20-24 83.4 79.8 -4.3 4.5
25-34 93.4 92.0 -1.5 8.7
35-44 92.8 91.9 -1.0 9.6
45-54 88.6 88.3 -0.4 9.0
55+ 40.8 43.2 6.0 12.7
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Table 5
Growth in share of 16 to 24 year olds in school and labor
force (annualized percentage growth rates)
In school Not in school
Not in
In labor labor In labor Not in
Total force force Totalforce labor
force
16 to 19 year olds
2000-2002 1.2 -3.5 4.6 -5.0 -6.3 -0.7
1993-2000 0.6 1.0 0.4 1.5 2.00 0.3
1990-1993 1.7 1.7 1.70 -5.2 -6.3 -1.7
1984-1990 0.0 0.5 -0.3 -3.0 -2.9 -3.5
20 to 24 year olds
2000-2002 2.5 -1.2 8.9 -1.9 -2.6 1.6
1993-2000 1.7 2.4 0.6 0.6 0.9 -1.0
1990-1993 2.6 3.5 1.1 -0.9 -1.5 1.9
1984-1990 2.1 2.8 1.20 -2.1 -2.0 -2.6
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
NOTES
(1) Recent newspaper reports suggest that the NBER dating committee
is considering the unusual step of changing the date of the cycle peak.
See, for example, Henderson (2004).
(2) In fact, employment was growing within four months, and in two
cases within one month, of the trough in all five of the 1960--80s
recoveries. To a degree, this is no accident; the NBER uses payroll
employment, along with real gross domestic product (GDP), real income,
industrial production, and real manufacturing and trade sales, as one of
its key indicators for dating cycle turning points. There is no fixed
rule as to how these variables are weighted, although real GDP and other
output measures get "considerable weight." See the discussion
at www.nber.org/cycles/recessions.html.
(3) The survey on which these numbers are based, the payroll
survey, reports hours data for production or nonsupervisory workers
only. By industry, this would include production workers in mining and
manufacturing, construction workers in construction, and nonsupervisory
workers in service-providing industries.
(4) For example, see Meltzer (2003). Articles and op-eds
questioning the payroll survey's accuracy have been published in
numerous magazines and newspapers over the last year.
(5) On the other hand, 15-year-olds are included in the payroll
survey but not the household survey.
(6) The household employment series are smoothed to account for
population control corrections that are incorporated discretely into the
reported figures.
(7) The adjusted series is from BLS (2004). See Nardone et al.
(2003) for a detailed discussion and attempted reconciliation of the gap
that developed during the 1990s and BLS (2004) for a discussion of the
recent data.
(8) To quantify the importance of sample size, any monthly change
above 108,000 jobs is considered statistically different from no change
in the payroll survey. To claim statistical significance in the
household survey, the monthly change must be greater than 290,000. See
BLS (2004).
(9) The UI records provide a count of the number of employees
covered by unemployment insurance laws. They cover over eight million
establishments and nearly 97 percent of total nonfarm employment. The
BLS uses alternative sources for the population not covered by UI. This
full employment count is benchmarked to the sample-based counts in the
payroll survey once a year. See www.bls.gov/ces/cesmetho.htm#10 for more
details about the UI records, benchmarking, as well as the models used
to estimate firm births and deaths prior to the UI benchmarking.
(10) The empirical evidence on this point is quite thin though.
Hanson and Spilimbergo (1999) use U.S.-Mexico border apprehensions to
show that illegal immigration is quite responsive to changes in U.S. and
Mexican real wages.
(11) One bit of corroborating evidence is that only five million
immigrants applied for green card visas in 2003, roughly 60 percent
below a typical year's applicant pool.
(12) Population controls adjustments provided by the 2000 Census
increased the level of household employment by 1.7 million, narrowing
but not fully eliminating the cumulative 1990s gap between the household
and payroll employment counts.
(13) For example, Meltzer (2003), Hilsenrath (2003), and Kudlow
(2004).
(14) These calculations are based on the raw household employment
figures and therefore do not smooth out the population adjustments, This
adjustment would have little impact on the results reported below. We
report quarterly figures because of concern about the variability of the
monthly figures.
(15) Rissman uses the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, a
large panel data set that follows individuals over time. The individuals
are interviewed annually from 1979-94 and again in 1996 and 1998. The
participants range in age from 14 to 22 in 1979.
(16) We use the 16 and over population and exclude agricultural
workers. The results are robust to reasonable changes to both of these
groups.
(17) By specifying the regression equation in logs, the coefficient estimates have an intuitive interpretation as an elasticity. A 1 percent
increase in the unemployment rate is associated with a [beta] percent
increase in self-employment. Furthermore, by framing the regression in
logs we avoid the problem of having predicted values of self-employment
less than 0 or larger than 1.
(18) An alternative approach to control for secular trends is
including year dummies. Unfortunately, this sops up too much of the
variation and results in highly imprecise parameter estimates. In future
work, we plan to explore these specification issues further.
(19) Without a service, the current filing fee is $150, plus an
additional franchise fee of at least $25 and a $25 fee for reserving the
company name. Incorporation in Delaware costs about half as much.
Additionally, owners may wish to consult with an attorney or CPA and
will likely need to open a bank checking account at some cost.
Unfortunately, we do not have information about the cost of dissolving a
corporation.
(20) As a barometer consider the average start-up cost for a small
business. In the 1992 Characteristics of Business Owners Survey, 27
percent of respondents report no start-up capital and another 34 percent
report start-up capital of less than $5,000. Only 10 percent had over
$50,000 in capital at start-up. So the fees and opportunity costs associated with incorporation would be substantial relative to the
start-up cost of many businesses.
(21) Limited liability means that if the corporation suffers
losses, the corporation itself must bear those losses. The personal
assets of the individual shareholders are not at risk. This is in
contrast to unincorporated businesses, which do not offer personal
liability protection to their owners or employees. Other advantages of
incorporation include the ease of ownership transfer. Corporate shares
may be transferred without dissolving the corporation. Additionally,
incorporation offers different tax options that encourage pension,
profit sharing, and stock option plans. The main disadvantage of a
corporation is that the dividends paid by corporations to their
shareholders are taxed twice--once as income to the corporation and
again as dividend income to the shareholder. Some corporate structures,
such as a Subchapter S Corporation, eliminate this double taxation. The
S Corporation allows certain income, deductions, and losses to be passed
through the corporation to the individual tax return of each
shareholder. For unincorporated businesses, net income flows to the
owner and the owner is taxed.
(22) Similar results arise using a different definition of the
local labor market--metropolitan statistical area (MSA). Because the
signal to noise ratio is low in smaller MSAs with few observations, we
include only the largest 100 MSAs and do the analysis at an annual
frequency.
(23) Technically, this unemployment rate includes agricultural
workers. However, adjusting the unemployment rate in a rough way to be
more consistent with a nonfarm measure would have a small impact on the
change in the unemployment rate over the last two years.
(24) This assumes the effect on the incorporated firms is zero,
which cannot be rejected by our estimates. The total self-employment
predictions are derived by multiplying the relevant elasticity by the
percentage change in the unemployment rate, the share of workers in that
category, and the initial self-employment rate. For example, the 0.05
percentage point figure for the WLS estimate reported in table 2 is
calculated as 0.28 (the unincorporated elasticity when the
state-specific time trend is used) x 0.405 (the percentage change in the
unemployment rate) x 0.67 (the share of self-employed who own
unincorporated firms) x 0.068 (the self-employment rate in the first
quarter of 2001).
(25) Lilien (1982) argues that variation in the pace of sectoral
reallocation may contribute significantly to unemployment fluctuations.
Davis and Haltiwanger (1990) and Davis, Haltiwanger, and Schuh (1996)
discuss the role of job creation and destruction over the business
cycle.
(26) The costs to the affected workers can also be quite
significant as is discussed, for example, in Jacobson, LaLonde, and
Sullivan (1993a and 1993b).
(27) See Segal and Sullivan (1997a and 1997b) for more on the
temporary services industry. Schreft and Singh (2003) also discuss the
role of the industry over the business cycle.
(28) Moreover, as Segal and Sullivan (1997b) show, because the
industry has very high turnover, a significantly higher fraction of
workers have a temporary services job over a period of a year or two.
(29) Many temp firms also provide general computer training, a
service that Autor (2001 a) argues allows these firms to screen
potential employees for their clients.
(30) See Autor (2001b) for a discussion of the role of the Internet
in the labor market.
(31) See, for example, Wessel (2004).
(32) However, Gruber and Krueger (1991) and Anderson and Meyer
(2000) find that the additional costs of workers compensation and
unemployment insurance are largely passed onto employees in the form of
lower wages. A related objection to the health costs theory is that
medical insurance costs also rose rapidly in the early 1980s, but
employment growth was very rapid following the recession trough of 1982.
A possible response to this challenge is to argue that the lower
inflation environment that has prevailed since the late 1980s makes it
more difficult for firms to offset medical insurance cost increases with
lower wage and salary growth. This would be the case if it were easier
to reduce nominal wage growth from, say, 8 percent to 6 percent in a
high inflation environment than to reduce wage growth from, say, 3
percent to 1 percent in a low inflation environment. This argument
relies on some form of "money illusion," which we do not find
very appealing. However, researchers have found evidence of nominal wage
rigidities that may be consistent with such effects--for example,
Altonji and Devereux (2000) and Lebow et al. (1999).
(33) Unfortunately, these data only go back to 1986. Thus, we
don't know whether health care was a high or low percentage of
employment costs in the periods of rapid employment growth following
earlier recessions.
(34) Alternatively, they might tilt their hiring towards fewer more
highly skilled workers.
(35) A somewhat similar theory is that increased requirements to
fund pensions for retired workers impose an increased burden on firms
that is restraining hiring. However, retiree pension obligations are
fixed costs that do not depend on current employment or production
levels. Thus, basic economic theory predicts they should have no effect
on firms' decisions, except perhaps their decisions on whether to
stay in business. Some researchers have found evidence that accounting
changes can affect aspects of firm behavior such as investment. However,
we are skeptical that such costs have played a significant role in the
jobless recoveries.
(36) The data are based on special education supplements to the
household survey given every October.
(37) The emergence of just-in-time hiring practices might also have
damped demand growth if it led firms to delay hiring and rebuilding
inventories. Alternatively, a lack of employment growth caused by the
growth of just-in-time hiring practices could have had a deleterious effect on consumer or business confidence.
REFERENCES
Aaronson, Daniel, Ellen Rissman, and Daniel Sullivan, 2004,
"Can sectoral reallocation explain the jobless recovery?,"
Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 28, Second
Quarter.
Altonji, Joseph, and Paul Devereux, 2000, "The extent and
consequences of downward nominal wage rigidity," Research in Labor
Economics, Vol. 19, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, pp. 383-431.
Anderson, Patricia, and Bruce Meyer, 2000, "The effects of the
unemployment insurance payroll tax on wages, employment, claims, and
denials," Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 78, No. 1-2, pp.
81-106.
Autor, David, 2001a, "Why do temporary help firms provide free
general skills training?," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
116, No. 4, pp. 1409-1448.
--, 2001b, "Wiring the labor market," Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. 25-40.
Barrow, Lisa, 2004, "Is the official unemployment rate
misleading? A look at labor market statistics over the business
cycle," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Vol. 28, Second Quarter.
Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2004, "Employment from the BLS
household and payroll surveys: Summary of recent trends,"
Washington, DC, available at www.bls.gov/cps/ces_cps_trends.pdf, posted
March 5, 2004.
Davis, Steven, and John Haltiwanger, 1990, "Gross job creation
and destruction: Microeconomic evidence and macroeconomic implications," NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1990, Cambridge, MA, and
London: MIT Press, pp. 123-168.
Davis, Steven, John Haltiwanger, and Scott Schuh, 1996, Job
Creation and Destruction, Cambridge, MA, and London: MIT Press.
Groshen, Erica, and Simon Potter, 2003, "Has structural change
contributed to a jobless recovery?," Current Issues in Economics
and Finance, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Vol. 9, No. 8, August.
Gruber, Jonathan, and Alan Krueger, 1991, "The incidence of
mandated employer-provided insurance: Lessons from workers'
compensation insurance," in Tax Policy and the Economy, Vol. 5,
David Bradford (ed.), Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 111-144.
Hanson, Gordon, and Antonio Spilimbergo, 1999, "Illegal
immigration border enforcement and relative wages: Evidence from
apprehensions at the U.S.-Mexico border," American Economic Review,
Vol. 89, No. 5, pp. 1337-1357.
Henderson, Nell, 2004, "Economists say recession started in
2000," Washington Post, January 22.
Hilsenrath, Jon, 2003, "Self-employed boost the economic
recovery, Wall Street Journal, December 1.
Jacobson, Louis, Robert LaLonde, and Daniel Sullivan, 1993a,
"Earnings losses of displaced workers," American Economic
Review, Vol. 83, No. 4, pp. 685-709.
--, 1993b, "Long-term earnings losses of high seniority
displaced workers," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, Vol. 17, No. 6, pp. 2-20.
Kudlow, Lawrence, 2004, "This recovery's not
broken," National Review On-line, March 8.
Lebow, David, Raven Saks, and Beth Anne Wilson, 1999,
"Downward nominal wage rigidity: Evidence from the Employment Cost
Index," Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance
and Economics Discussion Series, working paper, No. 31.
Lilien, David, 1982, "Sectoral shifts and cyclical
unemployment," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90, No. 4, pp.
777-793.
Meltzer, Alan, 2003, "A jobless recovery?," Wall Street
Journal, October 1.
Nardone, Thomas, Mary Bowler, Jurgen Kropf, Katie Kirkland, and
Signe Wetrogan, 2003, "Examining the discrepancy in employment
growth between the CPS and CES," Bureau of Labor Statistics,
working paper.
Rissman, Ellen R., 2003, "Self-employment as an alternative to
unemployment," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper.
--, 1997, "Measuring labor market turbulence," Economic
Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 21, No. 3, pp. 2-14.
Schreft, Stacey, and Aarti Singh, 2003, "A closer look at
jobless recoveries," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, pp. 45-73.
Segal, Lewis, and Daniel Sullivan, 1997a, "The growth of
temporary services work," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol.
11, No. 2, pp. 117-136.
--, 1997b, "Temporary services employment durations: Evidence
from state UI data," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working
paper.
StataCorp, 2001, Stata Statistical Software: Release 7.0 Manual,
College Station, TX: Stata Corporation.
Wessel, David, 2004, "Health care costs blamed for hiring
gap," Wall Street Journal, March 11, p. A2.
Daniel Aaronson is a senior economist and economic advisor, Ellen
R. Rissman is an economist, and Daniel G. Sullivan is a vice president
and senior economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors
would like to thank Kate Anderson for research assistance and Spencer
Krane and Craig Furfine for their helpful comments and suggestions.