Financial constraints and entrepreneurship: evidence from the Thai financial crisis.
Paulson, Anna L. ; Townsend, Robert M.
Introduction and summary
Poorly functioning financial markets can limit entry of new firms
and lead to inefficient production in existing firms. Small-scale
entrepreneurs that have limited access to formal financial markets may
be particularly affected by financial constraints. Despite this, small
entrepreneurial firms are an important source of innovation, jobs, and
economic growth in both developed and developing countries. In the U.S.,
44 percent of the private work force is employed in small firms, which
account for approximately 50 percent of non-farm gross domestic product
(GDP). (1) Striking similarities exist between small firms in the U.S.
and those in developing countries. In Thailand, for example, small firms
employ 60 percent of the work force and account for approximately 50
percent of GDP. (2) Investment from banks and other formal financial
institutions is typically limited in small firms. Thus, in both the U.S.
and Thailand, two-thirds of the initial investment in small firms comes
from savings and funds from family and friends. (3)
Outside investment in small firms may be limited for a number of
reasons, including the difficulty of providing credible information to
investors about the expected profitability of a planned investment
project or the entrepreneurial skill of a potential borrower. This type
of problem is typically called asymmetric information. In addition, the
provision of a loan may reduce the incentives for an entrepreneur to
exert the necessary effort to make a project successful, since the
profits of a successful project will have to be shared with investors.
This type of problem is called moral hazard. Asymmetric information and
moral hazard are concerns in both developed and developing economies.
However, these problems are likely to be acute in developing economies
where financial markets are less efficient.
When financial markets are less developed, entrepreneurial activity
may also be vulnerable to events like the Asian Financial Crisis. This
crisis began in July 1997 when the Thai government abandoned its policy
of pegging the value of Thailand's currency, the baht, to a basket
of developed countries' currencies heavily weighted to the U.S.
dollar. The Asian Financial Crisis led to widespread turmoil in
international financial markets and to recessions in many Asian
countries. In the wake of the crisis, the Thai economy entered a period
of marked contraction. In 1997 Thailand's GDP fell 1.5 percent, and
in 1998 it fell 11 percent. (4)
At the same time, entrepreneurial activity in Thailand increased.
In the 12 months following the onset of the crisis, data from a survey
we conducted reveal that the number of business households more than
doubled (see figure 1). In the spring of 1997, approximately 11 percent
of survey households operated a business. One year later, the percentage
had tripled, with more than 30 percent of the survey households
operating a business. By studying entrepreneurial activity in Thailand
before, during, and after the financial crisis, we can enhance our
understanding of entrepreneurship and financial constraints generally,
and improve our understanding of the role of small businesses during a
period of economic contraction.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
We use new longitudinal data from rural and semi-urban Thailand to
examine the factors that influence entrepreneurial activity in the
pre-crisis and crisis periods. The data cover an interval from the
spring of 1997 to the spring of 2001, so we are also able to gain some
insight into the post-crisis period. We are particularly interested in
entrepreneurial activity during the crisis period.
Before the crisis, we find that wealthier households are more
likely to start businesses and that they invest more in these businesses
than their less wealthy counterparts (Paulson and Townsend, 2004).
During the crisis, however, the positive correlation between
entrepreneurial activity and wealth disappears. These findings are
robust to the inclusion of various control variables, alternative
functional form assumptions, and various techniques for controlling for
the endogeneity of wealth. The traditional explanation of these findings
would be that financial markets were inefficient prior to the Asian
Financial Crisis, but effectively allocated capital to entrepreneurial
activities during the crisis.
However, this interpretation strains credulity, given the major
weaknesses of the Thai financial system revealed by the crisis itself.
Restricting our attention to the operation of financial markets in rural
and semi-urban areas, where the survey takes place, we find it difficult
to imagine that imperfections in these financial markets were somehow
alleviated during the crisis period.
Instead, we argue that rising unemployment and falling real wages
during the crisis led to changes in the types of people who started
businesses--and in the types of businesses they started. For instance,
businesses that were initiated at the height of the financial crisis
required only a median of 1,250 baht (approximately $50) in start-up
capital. (5) The median initial investment in businesses that were
started prior to the crisis was 36,750 baht (approximately $1,470). To
put these figures into context, note that median annual income in
Thailand in the year before the crisis was 40,000 baht ($1,600) for
nonbusiness households and 100,000 baht ($4,000) for business
households.
In this article, we provide some insights into how rural and
semi-urban households in Thailand coped with the financial crisis. The
results of this article also underscore the importance of carefully
controlling for changes in the returns to non-entrepreneurial
activities, notably labor market conditions, in studying the
determinants of entrepreneurial activity more generally. These findings
help us to understand, for example, increases in self-employment observed in the U.S. during the recession that ended in November 2001.
The rest of this article is organized as follows. First, we discuss
some of the relevant related literature. Then, we provide more
background on the impact of the Thai financial crisis, detail the
financial environment in the survey areas, and describe the longitudinal
data that we analyze. Next, we use regression analysis to examine the
role of financial constraints in explaining patterns of entrepreneurship
before, during, and after the crisis. Finally, we consider how to
interpret these findings in the light of other trends in entrepreneurial
characteristics over the 1997-2001 period.
Related literature
If financial constraints were not important, then potential
entrepreneurs would make the decision to start a business based solely
on the expected profitability of the planned endeavor. If necessary,
they would be able to get outside financing to start the project, and
their own wealth would not be a significant factor in whether the
business was started. When financial constraints are important, however,
outside financing may be unavailable or insufficient. Wealthier
households will be more likely to start a business than poorer ones
under these conditions.
Holtz-Eakin, Joulfaian, and Rosen (1994) use data from tax records
in the U.S. to examine the reduced-form relationship between inheritance and entrepreneurship, and conclude that financial constraints are
important. Using U.S. data from the National Longitudinal Survey of
Youth (NLSY), Evans and Jovanovic (1989) draw the same conclusion in
their structural study of the impact of wealth on career choices. On the
other hand, Hurst and Lusardi (2004) find no evidence that
entrepreneurial activity in the U.S. is affected by financial
constraints when they allow for a non-linear relationship between wealth
and entrepreneurship.
In work that is particularly relevant to this article, Rissman
(2003) and Aaronson, Rissman, and Sullivan (2004) point to the
importance of taking into account labor market conditions when analyzing
the decision to be self-employed. Rissman (2003) models self-employment
as an alternative to unemployment, suggesting that self-employment is
countercyclical. This conclusion is supported by her analysis of U.S.
data from the NLSY. Aaronson, Rissman, and Sullivan (2004) also find
some evidence of countercyclical self-employment in the U.S. in their
analysis of Current Population Survey data. They find that higher rates
of unemployment are associated with higher rates of self-employment.
They attribute recent increases in self-employment to weak labor market
conditions during the recession ending in November 2001.
The operation of existing businesses will also be affected by the
entrepreneur's wealth when financial constraints are present. In
particular, financial constraints may prevent entrepreneurs from
investing the optimal amount in their businesses. If financial
constraints did not exist, then entrepreneurs would be able to make up
the shortfall between their own funds and the profit-maximizing level of
investment by borrowing. In this situation, entrepreneurial investment
and entrepreneurial wealth would be independent of one another. When
there are financial constraints, however, entrepreneurs may be unable to
borrow, or only be able to borrow a limited amount. In this case,
wealthier entrepreneurs will be able to invest more in their own
businesses, since they are less dependent on the availability of outside
financing.
Fazzari, Hubbard, and Petersen (1988) explore this implication of
financial constraints in a sample of publicly traded manufacturing firms
in the U.S. and show that investment is sensitive to cash flows for some
firms. In their two studies, Petersen and Rajan (1994, 1995) hypothesize that banking relationships increase small businesses' access to
credit by overcoming information problems that would otherwise constrain the availability of credit to them. Their analysis of data collected by
the Small Business Administration (SBA) suggests that banking
relationships do indeed play this role for small firms. In contrast,
McKenzie and Woodruff (2003) use semi-parametric techniques to show that
returns on investment do not increase with investment in a sample of
small Mexican firms, as one would expect if financial constraints were
important.
A number of other theoretical studies, relying on a wide variety of
assumptions about how financial markets operate, imply a positive
relationship between entrepreneurship and wealth and between investment
and wealth. (6) Paulson, Townsend, and Karaivanov (2005) show that moral
hazard concerns limit entrepreneurial activity in Thailand in the period
leading up to the Asian Financial Crisis.
Background and data
Thai financial crisis
The initial repercussions of the Thai financial crisis were felt in
large urban areas, especially in Bangkok, where many construction
workers were laid off. Total unemployment increased from an annual rate
of 1.1 percent in 1996 to 3.4 percent in 1998, and wages and hours
worked fell as well. (7) By some measures, rural areas were particularly
hard hit. In these areas, unemployment increased from 3 percent to 8
percent. In the poor northeastern region, real earnings fell by 8
percent. (8) Workers with little education were particularly vulnerable.
Real earnings fell 13-20 percent among those who had, at most, completed
primary school. Prices also rose during this period, with the Consumer
Price Index increasing by 14 percent from 1996 to 1998. From 1998 to
2001, annual inflation in Thailand averaged 1.2 percent. (9)
The overall poverty rate in Thailand increased 24 percent from 1996
to 1999, from 17 percent to 21 percent. (10) However, increases in
poverty were not uniform across the country. In the Northeast, for
example, rural poverty rates increased nearly 40 percent, going from 28
percent to 39 percent. In the Central region, rural poverty actually
decreased from 13 percent to 12 percent from 1996 to 1999. However,
urban poverty in the Central region increased nearly 9 percent, going
from 6.96 percent to 7.59 percent.
Financial environment
The formal financial sector in Thailand provides two main sources
of funding for households in rural and semi-urban areas: the Bank for
Agriculture and Agricultural Cooperatives (BAAC) and commercial banks.
(11) Of these two, the BAAC is much more active in rural areas.
Ninety-five percent of northeastern Thai villages and 89 percent of
Central Thai villages had at least one BAAC borrower in 1994. The BAAC
offers two types of loans. One is a standard collateralized loan, and
the other requires no formal collateral and is secured instead through a
joint liability agreement with a group of farmers who all belong to a
BAAC group.
While the bulk of the BAAC's loans are uncollateralized, these
loans tend to be small, and the majority of funds are lent through
collateralized loans. Commercial banks are active lenders in 41 percent
of Thai villages. However, commercial bank borrowers tend to be
concentrated in the relatively prosperous Central region, where 50
percent of villages have at least one commercial bank borrower. In
contrast, only 31 percent of northeastern villages have a commercial
bank borrower. Commercial bank loans are almost always secured with a
land title. In addition to these formal sector lenders, there are a
number of quasi-formal institutions that offer savings and lending
services to villagers: village savings and lending institutions and rice
banks. It is also common for households to borrow from relatives and
neighbors and moneylenders. Often households will borrow from several
sources to finance one investment project.
Survey data
The data that we analyze were derived from our own ongoing
socioeconomic study in Thailand, which is funded by the U.S. National
Institutes of Health and the National Science Foundation. The initial
survey of households, village financial institutions, and village key
informants was completed in May 1997. It covers regions at the doorstep
of Bangkok as well as in the relatively poor Northeast. The data provide
a wealth of pre-financial crisis data from 2,880 households, 606 small
businesses, 192 villages, 161 local financial institutions, 262
borrowing groups of the BAAC, and soil samples from 1,880 agricultural
plots. A subset of these households was included in an ongoing
longitudinal survey, which takes place between March and May of each
year. The data we analyze cover the period from 1997 to 2001 and include
960 households.
The study focuses on four Thai provinces that were chosen because
of the availability of retrospective data from the Thai Socio-Economic Survey (SES). These provinces are emblematic of two distinct regions of
Thailand: rural and semi-urban households living in the Central region,
close to Bangkok, and more obviously rural households living in the
semi-arid and much poorer northeastern region. The Central region is
wealthier and more developed than the Northeast.
In each province, four geographic areas, called tambons, were
chosen at random. Each tambon includes approximately ten villages. In
each sample tambon, four villages were chosen at random. (12) Fifteen
households were randomly selected from each sample village. Overall, the
data include five years of information for 960 households (4 provinces x
4 tambons x 4 villages x 15 households) from 64 Thai villages (4
provinces x 4 tambons x 4 villages).
The data include survey year and retrospective information on
wealth (household, agricultural, business, and financial); occupational
history (transitions to and from farm work, wage work, and
entrepreneurship); and access to and use of a wide variety of formal and
informal financial institutions (commercial banks, agricultural banks,
village lending institutions, and moneylenders, as well as friends,
family, and business associates). The data also provide detailed
information on household demographics, entrepreneurial activities, and
education. The retrospective data on wealth and interactions with
financial institutions help us to disentangle the effects of running a
business from the forces that make it possible to start a business in
the first place.
Because these data provide rich and detailed information about both
the firm and the entrepreneurial household, as well as information on
financial intermediaries, they are particularly well designed for
studying the relationship between entrepreneurship and the financial
system. Economic theory emphasizes that both firm and entrepreneurial
characteristics are important in determining the supply and demand for
credit. In many studies the available data force a focus on either the
firm or the entrepreneur, but do not allow both to be treated with equal
thoroughness. (13)
Business characteristics
In this section we highlight some of the key features of the data
that are important for this article. The businesses we study are quite
varied and include shops and restaurants, trading activities, raising
shrimp or livestock, and the provision of construction or transportation
services. We rely on household reports on whether its members ran a
business except in the case of shrimp and fish farming. All of these
activities are treated as businesses. It is quite common for households
to run a business in addition to working for wages and farming, usually
rice. Most business households run only a single business and rely very
heavily on family workers. Only 10 percent of the businesses paid anyone
for work during the year prior to the survey.
While there are many different types of businesses, shrimp and/or
fish raising, shops, and trade account for most of the businesses. These
categories account for 65 percent of businesses founded prior to the
crisis, 60 percent founded in the year of the crisis, and 39 percent
founded in the immediate post-crisis period. The distribution of
business types within these categories changes substantially following
the crisis. Trade accounts for 17 percent of all businesses that were
started in the five years before the crisis. However, 47 percent of the
businesses that were founded in the year of the crisis were in trade.
The trade category includes retail and wholesale trading activities,
ranging from selling desserts in a local market to selling gasoline to
shops and gas stations.
There is substantial variation in initial investment in new
businesses over time, as we alluded to in the introduction (see table
1). The median initial investment in a business founded prior to the
crisis, between 1992 and 1997, is 36,747 baht. The median initial
investment in a business that began at the height of the crisis in 1998
is 1,350 baht. The median initial investment in a trading business was
52,533 baht prior to the crisis, just 793 baht in the year of the
crisis, and zero in the three years following the crisis. For all the
major business types, median initial investment is substantially lower
for businesses founded during the first year of the crisis and
afterwards compared with businesses founded between 1992 and 1997.
Households rely heavily on savings (either in the form of cash or
through asset sales) to fund initial investment in their businesses.
Approximately 60 percent of the total initial investment in household
businesses that were founded between 1992 and 1997 comes from savings.
Loans from commercial banks account for about 9 percent of total
business investment, and BAAC loans account for another 7 percent. In
the Northeast, the BAAC plays a larger role compared with commercial
banks, and in the Central region, the opposite is true. In the crisis
and post-crisis periods, when investment is lower, the importance of
credit for funding initial investment in the business declines.
In some of the empirical work, we control for participation in
formal and informal financial markets by business and non-business
households. We group formal and informal financial institutions into six
categories. The first, formal financial institutions, includes
commercial banks, finance companies, insurance companies, and national
employee credit unions, such as the Teachers Credit Union. The second,
village institutions and organizations, is made up of production credit
groups (PCGs), (14) rice and buffalo banks, and village poor and elderly
funds. Formal loans from the BAAC, the Agricultural Cooperative, and
local farmers' groups are included in the third group, agricultural
organizations. BAAC customers whose loans are secured through joint
liability arrangements make up the fourth group. Moneylenders and
rotating savings and credit associations (ROSCAs) make up the fifth and
sixth groups, respectively. Households were asked to report when they
became a customer or member of each organization. Hence, we are able to
look at the influence of participation in these organizations prior to
starting a business, as distinct from becoming a client of an
institution because of the business.
Because households were asked to report when they acquired
household and agricultural assets and land, the data provide measures of
past wealth as well as current wealth. In the empirical work, which we
discuss in the next section, we examine the relationship between past
wealth (that is, wealth prior to starting a business) and
entrepreneurship. This allows us to avoid some problems of endogeneity
that are likely to plague current wealth measures, since current wealth
reflects both the resources available to start a business for potential
entrepreneurs and the past profitability of a business for current
entrepreneurs. Because we can measure wealth before a business was
founded, we can isolate the resources available to start a business.
For the time being, however, our interest is in current rather than
past wealth. Panel A of figure 2 describes the trend in median wealth in
real 1997 Thai baht for business and non-business households over the
years 1997-2001. Business households are wealthier than their
non-business counterparts over the entire span, and all households
experience modest declines in wealth during the crisis. Between 2000 and
2001, median wealth increases for all households, with increases being
more dramatic for business households compared with non-business
households.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In figure 2, we compare important characteristics of business and
non-business households from 1997 to 2001. Prior to the crisis, the
heads of business households were more educated than the heads of
non-business households (see figure 2, panel B). Business household
heads had almost 4.8 years of schooling compared with 3.9 years for
non-business household heads. Table 2 provides further details on the
distribution of education (and other variables) for business and
non-business households. While 61 percent of business and non-business
household heads had completed four years of school in 1997, 23 percent
of business household heads had additional education compared with just
13 percent of non-business household heads. (15) During the crisis, the
gap in education between business and non-business households narrowed
substantially, indicating that individuals who started businesses during
the crisis were less educated than those who started businesses prior to
the crisis. Among households that started businesses in 1999, for
example, 35 percent of household heads had less than four years of
schooling (see table 2, panel B).
We see a similar pattern with age (see figure 2, panel C). The
heads of business households tend to be younger than the heads of
non-business households. Before the crisis, they are almost three years
younger. However, this gap virtually disappears during the crisis. This
indicates that the people who founded businesses during the crisis were
significantly older than the individuals who founded businesses prior to
the financial crisis.
In panel D of figure 2, we examine trends in household size for
business and non-business households. Here we see a different pattern.
Business households tend to be larger than non-business households, and
the difference increases between 1997 and 2001. There are two potential
explanations for this trend, both of them related to urban migrants
returning to rural and semi-urban areas in the wake of the crisis. One
possibility is that existing business households were more likely to be
joined by family members who had migrated prior to the crisis. Another
possibility is that urban migrants were more likely to rejoin households
that did not have a business prior to the crisis, and these migrants
spurred the creation of businesses during the crisis.
Panel E of figure 2 reports on trends in median income (net of
expenses for business and farm activities) for business and non-business
households. (16) Business households have higher median income than the
non-business households over the 1997-2001 period. However, while
non-business income drops modestly during the crisis, business income
decreases significantly with the onset of the crisis. In 1997 median
business income is nearly 90,000 baht, and in 1998 it is just 65,000
baht. As before, there are two potential factors that lie behind this
decline. Businesses in operation prior to the crisis may have
experienced a dramatic drop in income during the crisis. In addition,
businesses started during the crisis may simply generate less income
than those started before the crisis. We return to which of these
factors is likely to be more important later in this article.
In panel F of figure 2, we examine trends in median expenditure for
business and non-business households. Expenditure provides a measure of
both current welfare and also reflects expectations about future
economic conditions. Households that expect crisis conditions to
continue are likely to curtail their expenditures more than households
that expect the crisis to be resolved relatively quickly. Median
expenditure is higher for business households compared with non-business
households throughout the 1997-2001 period, and expenditure decreases
from 1997 to 2000 and then increases in 2001 for all households.
However, business households experience a sharper decline in expenditure
from 1997 to 1998 than non-business households, potentially driven by
the entry of new households into this category. By 2001, median
non-business household expenditure exceeds pre-crisis levels. For
business households, median expenditure in 2001 is still lower than it
was in 1997.
Before moving on to discuss the results of a more formal analysis
of the role of financial markets before, during, and after the crisis
period, it is useful to review the observations that we would like to be
able to account for:
* The percentage of business households nearly tripled during the
crisis.
* Businesses started during the crisis tend to have very low or
even no initial investment.
* The heads of households who established businesses during or
after the crisis tend to be less educated and older than the heads of
households with businesses already in operation prior to the crisis.
* Business households have higher wealth, net income, and
expenditure compared with non-business households, although the gap
between business and non-business households narrows during the crisis
period.
Evidence of financial constraints
In this section, we consider the evidence that financial market
imperfections played a role in shaping patterns of entrepreneurship
before, during, and after the financial crisis. We examine the
implications of financial constraints for business start-ups and for
initial investment in new businesses.
In the analysis, we divide household businesses into three groups:
1) Pre-crisis businesses: businesses founded between 1992 and 1997,
still in operation in 1997;
2) Crisis businesses: businesses founded in 1998, still in
operation in 2001; and
3) Post-crisis businesses: businesses founded between 1999 and
2001, still in operation in 2001.
For ease of exposition, we label the third group
"post-crisis," but we do not mean to imply that the impact of
the Thai financial crisis was limited to 1998. We concentrate on
businesses that survived for some period because of the design of the
1997 survey. The 1997 survey identifies businesses that were in
operation at the time of the survey--that is, businesses that were
started at some point in the past and were still in operation in 1997.
We restrict our attention to businesses that were started in the five
years prior to this survey. To make sure that we are looking at roughly
comparable businesses after 1997, the analysis excludes businesses that
were started in 1998 but failed between 1998 and 2001 and businesses
that were started between 1999 and 2001 and were not in operation in
2001. Of the businesses that were founded at the height of the crisis in
1998, 63 percent were still in operation in 2001.
To examine the importance of financial constraints, we focus on two
key relationships. The first is the relationship between the likelihood
that a household starts a business and household wealth prior to the
time that the business was founded. The second is the relationship
between the initial investment in the business and household wealth
prior to the time that the business was founded. If financial
constraints are important, we expect that business start-ups will be
sensitive to the wealth of potential entrepreneurs and that wealthier
entrepreneurs will invest more in their businesses. (17)
In order to evaluate the implications of financial constraints, we
need to come up with appropriate measures of entrepreneurial talent and
wealth. The proxy we use for entrepreneurial talent is education. While
education is certainly not a perfect indicator of entrepreneurial
talent, it is likely to be positively related to business skill. In
Paulson, Townsend, and Karaivanov (2005), we show that, at least for
Thailand, formal education seems to be strongly associated with business
skill.
The appropriate wealth variable is wealth at the time the decision
is made to start a business. For the pre-crisis analysis, we use wealth
six years prior to the 1997 survey as an empirical counterpart to this
variable. We exclude households with businesses that were founded prior
to 1992 from the analysis. For the crisis and post-crisis periods, we
measure wealth in the year before the business was started. The items
that are included in the wealth variable are: the value of household and
agricultural assets and land. We do not include the value of any
business assets that the household may have owned prior to starting a
business.
By using past, rather than current wealth, and by excluding
business assets acquired before the business was started, we hope to
avoid issues of endogeneity: Wealthier people are more likely to start
businesses, and business owners have higher earnings than wage workers,
which allow business owners to become even richer. In this scenario,
current wealth captures both the cause and the effect of having been
able to start a business in the past.
Wealth and the likelihood of starting a business
In table 3, we estimate probit models of who becomes an
entrepreneur for the three periods. The first set of results in this
table reports on the pre-crisis findings. The dependent variable is
equal to one if the household runs a business in 1997 that was founded
between 1992 and 1997 and zero if the household does not have a business
in 1997. (18) The second set of results reports on the crisis findings,
where the dependent variable is equal to one if the household starts a
business in 1998 that survives until 2001, and it is equal to zero
otherwise. The post-crisis findings are found in the third set of
results, and the dependent variable in this regression is equal to one
if the household has a business in operation in 2001, which was founded
between 1999 and 2001, and it is equal to zero otherwise. The figures
reported in the table indicate the marginal effect of an infinitesimal
change in each continuous variable on the probability of starting a
business. For dummy variables, we report the impact of changing the
variable in question from zero to one.
In addition to wealth prior to starting a business, the explanatory variables include characteristics of the household head that may be
indicators of business talent--age, age squared, and years of schooling.
There are also variables that control for the amount of household labor
that is available--the number of adult males, adult females, and
children under the age of 18 living in the household. (19)
We control for credit market availability by including measures of
whether the household was a member or customer of various financial
institutions in the past. Like the labor supply variables, we include
these variables so that we can appropriately interpret the coefficient of the wealth variable. In order to separate the impact of the
availability of a particular credit institution in the local area from
the impact of being a client of the institution, the estimates also
include controls for each of the tambons that were sampled. The tambon
controls are meant to capture geographic variations in the supply of
credit along with other important characteristics, such as
infrastructure and the size of the market. The inclusion of the tambon
controls means that the credit market variables provide an indication of
the average probability that patrons of the various institutions will
start businesses, relative to the probability that households in a
particular tambon will start businesses.
During the pre-crisis period, the likelihood that a household
starts a business is positively related to preexisting wealth. In
particular, the coefficients reported in the first set of results imply
that a 1,000,000 baht ($40,000) increase in wealth would be associated
with a 2.3 percentage point increase in the likelihood of starting a
business. (20) This is an increase of 21 percent above the observed
percentage of households that have started a business in the past five
years. The coefficient on wealth squared is significant, although very
small, suggesting that the impact of wealth on starting a business
decreases as wealth increases.
In contrast to the pre-crisis findings, during the crisis and
post-crisis periods, there is no statistically significant relationship
between wealth and the likelihood of starting a business. This suggests
that the importance of financial constraints declines during the crisis
and post-crisis periods.
Table 3 estimates also reflect trends in the difference between the
characteristics of business and non-business households over the crisis
period, described previously. Prior to the crisis, older household heads
are significantly less likely to start a business. During and after the
crisis, there is no significant relationship between the age of the
household head and the likelihood of starting a business. More education
is associated with a greater likelihood of starting a business prior to
the crisis, but has no significant impact on business start-ups during
the crisis. Larger households, as captured by the number of adult males
and females, are more likely to start businesses during and after the
crisis. These variables have no significant impact on the likelihood of
starting a business prior to the crisis. Business talent appears to have
been more important prior to the crisis than during the crisis, and the
availability of household labor seems to be more important during the
crisis than before the crisis.
In general, access to credit, as measured by past patronage of the
various financial institutions, does not seem to play an important role
in business start-ups before, during, or after the crisis. With one
exception, the variables that control for access to credit are
insignificant. During the crisis, however, households that had a prior
relationship with the BAAC, in the form of a joint liability borrowing
arrangement, are 7.5 percentage points more likely to start a business
than those without prior ties to the BAAC. This corresponds to nearly a
30 percent increase in the likelihood of starting a business during the
crisis period.
Wealth and initial business investment
In table 4, we examine the relationship between initial business
investment and preexisting household wealth for pre-crisis, crisis, and
post-crisis businesses. In these regressions, the log of initial
business investment plus one is regressed on household wealth prior to
the period when the business was started. In panel A, the sample
includes only businesses with positive initial investment. In panel B,
the sample is augmented with businesses that began with zero initial
investment. When we restrict the sample to businesses with positive
initial investment, as we do in panel A, it makes it more difficult to
find no relationship between investment and wealth.
In addition to household wealth, these regressions also include the
same household controls discussed earlier. (21) For businesses with
positive initial investment, higher levels of wealth prior to starting a
business are associated with greater initial business investment prior
to the crisis and after the crisis but not during the crisis (see table
4, panel A). An increase in past wealth of 1,000,000 baht is associated
with an increase in investment of 46 percent prior to the crisis. These
findings suggest that financial market imperfections restrict investment
levels prior to the crisis and after the crisis but not during the
crisis itself.
After the height of the crisis in 1998, the importance of financial
constraints on investment levels appears to return, at least for
businesses with positive initial investment. For these businesses, an
increase in past wealth of 1,000,000 baht is associated with an increase
in investment of 26 percent. Interestingly, during the crisis more
educated business household heads invest significantly more in their
businesses. There is some evidence that this is also the case prior to
the crisis, but the size and the significance of the coefficient on
schooling is smaller.
When we include businesses that begin with zero initial investment
(see table 4, panel B), we find no relationship between initial business
investment and past wealth before, during, or after the crisis. (22)
Education is a strong predictor of initial business investment during
the crisis and post-crisis periods according to these estimates,
although the magnitude of the effect is fairly small. An additional year
of schooling is associated with an increase in initial investment of 1.3
to 1.4 baht. Keep in mind, however, that 37 percent of the crisis
businesses and 56 percent of the post-crisis businesses had zero initial
investment.
Overall, the relationship between investment and past wealth
suggests that financial constraints led to underinvestment in existing
businesses prior to the crisis, and possibly after the crisis, but did
not place important restrictions on business investment during the
crisis.
Business performance
In figure 3, we examine the performance of the three groups of
business households from 1997 to 2001. We examine three indicators of
business household success: gross income, expenditure, and profit
(panels A, B, and C, respectively). Figure 3 underscores the emerging
picture that households that start businesses during and after the
crisis are different along important dimensions from households that
were running businesses when the crisis hit. Gross income, expenditure,
and profit are all much higher for households that were already running
a business at the time of the crisis compared with households that
started a business during or after the crisis. Businesses founded in the
post-crisis period have notably lower profits (figure 3, panel C). One
potential explanation for this finding is that households with more
entrepreneurial talent started businesses earlier--either before the
crisis or during the crisis. The businesses that were founded in the
post-crisis period may be operated by relatively untalented individuals,
and hence have very low profits.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
These patterns suggest that the narrowing gap between business and
non-business households--in terms of wealth, net income, and expenditure
(figure 2, panels A, E, and F, respectively)--is primarily due to the
entry of new businesses with lower income and expenditure during and
after the crisis rather than a weakening of the economic status of
existing businesses. Note, in particular, that the income of households
that had businesses at the time of the crisis went up from 1997 to 1999
at the height of the crisis (figure 3, panel A).
Conclusion
Beginning with the observation that the number of household
businesses in rural and semi-urban Thailand nearly tripled in the wake
of the Thai financial crisis, we describe and analyze a number of
important features of pre-crisis, crisis, and post-crisis businesses. In
particular, we show that businesses started during and after the Thai
financial crisis are more similar to non-business households than
households that started businesses prior to the crisis. Prior to the
crisis, business start-ups and initial investment are significantly
related to past household wealth. However, during the crisis, business
start-ups and initial investment are unaffected by household wealth. In
addition, crisis and post-crisis businesses are characterized by low
initial investment.
During the post-crisis period, business start-ups are unaffected by
wealth, but initial business investment (for businesses with non-zero
investment) is increasing with wealth. Recall that the median business
founded during the post-crisis period has zero initial investment.
Profits are highest for businesses started prior to the crisis and
lowest for businesses started during the post-crisis period. Compared
with businesses started during and after the crisis, pre-crisis
businesses appear to recover faster and more sharply.
Financial market imperfections seem to restrict business start-ups
and investment prior to the crisis but not during the crisis. What might
account for this finding? It seems plausible to rule out improvements in
financial markets as an explanation, since the crisis itself suggests
that Thai financial markets are (or at least were) quite fragile. The
key to understanding the apparent lack of financial constraints during
the crisis period in Thailand--and how financial constraints have an
impact on entrepreneurial activity more generally--is to consider the
alternative occupations available to households.
The model of Evans and Jovanovic (1989) provides a useful framework
for understanding the increase in business activity during the Thai
financial crisis and over the business cycle. Their model implies that
when wages fall, more businesses will be started as the returns to
entrepreneurial activity exceed wages for more households. In addition,
this model implies that the new businesses will tend to be capitalized at lower levels and be run by less talented entrepreneurs. We see
evidence of this in the data--crisis and post-crisis investment levels
are very low, profits are also low, and the household heads that founded
crisis and post-crisis businesses are also less educated than those that
founded businesses prior to the crisis. We can reconcile the facts we
have described above by understanding how falling wages affect both who
finds entrepreneurial activity profitable and how much they invest in
business activity.
As alternatives to business employment worsened during the Thai
financial crisis, households began businesses because their wage
employment options deteriorated. Low capital business opportunities that
were unattractive prior to the crisis looked good during the crisis.
Note that business investment during the crisis period generated lower
profits than pre-crisis investment. Despite the finding that business
start-ups and investment are insensitive to wealth during the crisis,
there was no improvement in financial markets during this period.
Instead, typical business investment during the financial crisis was so
low that credit was not required.
This article's findings underscore the general importance of
taking into account economic conditions at the time a business is
founded in order to account for firm investment and profitability. This
insight extends to both developed and developing countries, and applies
to dramatic events like the Thai financial crisis, as well as to more
modest business cycle type variation in economic conditions.
REFERENCES
Aaronson, Daniel, Ellen R. Rissman, and Daniel G. Sullivan, 2004,
"Assessing the jobless recovery," Economic Perspectives,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 28, No. 2, pp. 2-20.
Aghion, Phillippe, and Patrick Bolton, 1997, "A trickle-down
theory of growth and development," Review of Economic Studies, Vol.
64, No. 2, April, pp. 151-172.
Binford, Michael, Tae Jeong Lee, and Robert Townsend, 2001,
"Sampling design for an integrated socioeconomic and ecologic survey using satellite remote sensing and ordination," University
of Chicago, manuscript.
Bitler, Marianne P., Alicia M. Robb, and John D. Wolken, 2001,
"Financial services used by small businesses: Evidence from the
1998 Survey of Small Business Finance," Federal Reserve Bulletin,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, April, pp. 183-205.
Evans, David S., and Boyan Jovanovic, 1989, "An estimated
model of entrepreneurial choice under liquidity constraints,"
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97, No. 4, August, pp. 808-827.
Fazzari, Stephen M., R. Glenn Hubbard, and Bruce C. Petersen, 2000,
"Investment-cash flow sensitivities are useful: A comment on Kaplan
and Zingales," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, No. 2, pp.
695-705.
--, 1988, "Financing constraints and corporate
investment," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1, pp.
141-195.
Greenwood, Jeremy, and Boyan Jovanovic, 1990, "Financial
development, growth, and the distribution of income," Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, pp. 1076-1107.
Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, David Joulfaian, and Harvey S. Rosen, 1994,
"Sticking it out: Entrepreneurial survival and liquidity
constraints," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 102, No. 1,
February, pp. 53-75.
Hurst, Erik, and Annamaria Lusardi, 2004, "Liquidity
constraints, household wealth, and entrepreneurship," Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 112, No. 2, April, pp. 319-347.
Kaboski, Joseph, and Robert Townsend, 1998, "Borrowing and
lending in semi-urban and rural Thailand," University of Chicago,
manuscript.
Lerner, Josh, 1999, "The government as venture capitalist: The
long-run impact of the SBIR program," Journal of Business, Vol. 72,
No. 3, July, pp. 285-318.
Lloyd-Ellis, Huw, and Dan Bernhardt, 2000, "Enterprise,
inequality, and economic development," Review of Economic Studies,
Vol. 67, No. 1, pp. 147-168.
McKenzie, David, and Christopher Woodruff, 2003, "Do entry
costs provide an empirical basis for poverty traps? Evidence from
Mexican microenterprises," Stanford University, manuscript.
Paulson, Anna L., and Robert M. Townsend, 2004,
"Entrepreneurship and financial constraints in Thailand,"
Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 10, No. 2, pp. 229-262.
Paulson, Anna L., Robert M. Townsend, and Alexander K. Karaivanov,
2005, "Distinguishing limited liability from moral hazard in a
model of entrepreneurship," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
working paper, revised April 2005, No. WP-2003-06.
Petersen, Mitchell A., and Raghuram G. Rajan, 1995, "The
effect of credit market competition on lending relationships,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 2, May, pp. 407-443.
--, 1994, "The benefits of lender relationships: Evidence from
small business data," Journal of Finance, Vol. 49, No. 1, pp. 3-37.
Rissman, Ellen R., 2003, "Self-employment as an alternative to
unemployment," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper, No.
WP-2003-34.
Thailand Development Research Institute, 2003, "Thailand
Economic Information Kit: 2003," Bangkok, report.
Townsend, Robert M., with Anna L. Paulson, Sombat Sakuntasathien,
Tae Jeong Lee, and Michael Binford, 1997, "Questionnaire design and
data collection for NICHD grant 'Risk, insurance, and the
family' and NSF grants," University of Chicago.
World Bank Group, The, 2000, "Thai workers and the
crisis," Thailand Social Monitor, July.
NOTES
(1) Small Business Administration (SBA) statistics are drawn from
the U.S. Bureau of the Census and Current Population Survey data.
According to the SBA, small firms are defined as manufacturing firms
with fewer than 500 employees and non-manufacturing firms with less than
$5 million in annual sales.
(2) APEC (Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation) Center for Technology
Exchange and Training for Small and Medium Enterprises. Small Thai firms
include manufacturing and service firms with 50 or fewer employees;
wholesale trade firms with 25 or fewer employees; and retail trading
operations with 15 or fewer employees. Medium-sized firms may have up to
200, 50, and 30 employees in each of these categories, respectively.
(3) This is determined from Bitler, Robb, and Wolken (2001) and
calculations from the authors' survey from Thailand.
(4) In the years leading up to the crisis, the Thai economy had
grown rapidly. From 1980 to 1995, real per capita GDP had grown 8
percent per year. Following the crisis, the Thai economy recovered
somewhat, and real per capita GDP growth averaged 3 percent per year
from 1999 to 2001 (World Bank, World Development Indicators).
(5) Throughout this article, monetary values are reported in real
1997 Thai baht. Prior to the devaluation in July 1997, 25 Thai baht
equaled 1 U.S. dollar (25 baht = $1).
(6) For example, these implications are shared by a model where
there is no credit (Lloyd-Ellis and Bernhardt, 2000), a model where
credit is exogenously limited to be a fixed multiple of household wealth
(Evans and Jovanovic, 1989), and a model where credit is allocated as
the optimal solution to an information-constrained moral hazard problem
(Aghion and Bolton, 1997). They are also consistent with the asymmetric
information framework emphasized by Fazzari, Hubbard, and Petersen
(1988, 2000).
(7) Unemployed individuals are those who are currently not working
but are actively looking for work (World Bank, World Development
Indicators).
(8) See The World Bank Group (2000).
(9) Prior to the crisis, inflation in Thailand was determined by
inflation in the currencies to which the Thai baht was pegged; this
means that price increases in Thailand largely mimicked those of the
U.S.
(10) All poverty rate figures are reported in Thailand Development
Research Institute (2003) and are based on calculations from the Thai
National Statistics Office, Socio-Economic Survey (SES) data. The
poverty rate is defined as the percentage of people in a given region
living below the poverty line for that region.
(11) This section is based on the authors' observations and
discussions with BAAC officials as well as on data from the Community
Development Department of the Thai Ministry of the Interior that cover
60,000 Thai villages every other year from 1988 through 1994.
(12) Each village is a distinct political entity with an elected
headman or woman, very much like a mayor.
(13) For example, the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth,
analyzed by Evans and Jovanovic (1989), has detailed information on the
self-employed, but very sparse information on the businesses they run.
The Small Business Administration (SBA) data analyzed by Petersen and
Rajan (1994, 1995) provide a wealth of details about the firm but very
little information about the entrepreneur.
(14) These are village-run savings institutions where members
pledge to save a certain amount and interest earnings are determined by
the profitability of the whole institution for the year. A sizable fraction of PCGs offer loans, which are secured by savings, as well.
(15) Four years of schooling was the statutory minimum at the time
most of the sample's household heads were in school.
(16) In each survey year, households were asked to report on income
and expenditure for the 12 months prior to the survey. Thus, for the
survey year 1997, income and expenditure figures cover the period from
the spring of 1996 to the spring of 1997.
(17) We explain why financial constraints generate these
predictions in the Related literature section.
(18) Households with businesses that are operating in 1997 but were
founded prior to 1992 are eliminated from the analysis.
(19) In table 2, these variables are summarized in panel A for
non-business households, by year, and in panel B for business
households, by the year the business was started.
(20) A 1,000,000 baht increase in wealth corresponds to doubling
the current wealth of the median business household in 1997 and tripling
the wealth of the median non-business household.
(21) Because the sample sizes are smaller here, we do not control
for past use of financial institutions and geographic location.
(22) We have experimented with different statistical models and
gotten qualitatively similar results. For example, we have estimated
probit models where 0 corresponds to zero initial investment and 1
corresponds to positive initial investment and ordered probit models
where 0 corresponds to zero initial investment, 1 corresponds to initial
investment of less than 10,000 baht, and 2 corresponds to initial
investment greater than 10,000 baht.
Anna L. Paulson is a senior economist at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. Robert M. Townsend is the Charles E. Merriam Distinguished
Service Professor of the Department of Economics at the University of
Chicago and a consultant to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The
authors wish to thank Kristin Butcher, Craig Furfine, Xavi Gin,, Ellen
Rissman, and Alicia Williams for helpful comments, and Shirley Chiu for
excellent research assistance. They are also grateful to Sombat
Sakuntasathien for making the data collection possible and to the
National Science Foundation and the National Institutes of Health for
funding.
TABLE 1
Thai business types and median initial investment
Pre-crisis Crisis Post-crisis
Median Median Median
Business types Percent inv. Percent inv. Percent inv.
Shrimp and/or
fish 19 42,027 6 37,800 10 14,745
Shop 29 26,595 7 10,366 4 5,362
Retail and
wholesale
trade 17 52,533 47 793 25 0
Other 35 78,626 40 5,166 61 0
All 100 36,747 100 1,350 100 0
Sample size 102 208 213
Notes: Pre-crisis refers to businesses that were started between 1992
and 1997 and were still in operation in 1997. Crisis refers to
businesses that were started in 1998 and were still in operation in
2001. Post-crisis refers to businesses that were started between 1999
and 2001 and were still in operation in 2001. Median initial
investment (median inv.) is in real 1997 Thai baht.
TABLE 2
Thai household characteristics
A. Non-business households, by year
1997 1998 1999
Age of head 51.51 52.28 52.80
(13.45) (13.71) (13.58)
Years of schooling--head
Average 3.86 3.88 3.92
(2.81) (2.84) (2.89)
0-3 years (percent) 26 24 24
4 years (percent) 61 63 64
5-16 years (percent) 13 13 13
No. of adult males in household 1.42 1.39 1.43
(0.94) (0.84) (0.91)
No. of adult females in household 1.55 1.49 1.51
(0.78) (0.73) (0.73)
No. of children (< 18 years) 1.60 1.58 1.69
in household (1.24) (1.20) (1.25)
Mean past wealth (in 000s) 803 945 360,000
(3,217) (3,615) (5,630,000)
Median past wealth (in 000s) 135 254 270
No. of observations 790 607 547
2000 2001
Age of head 53.45 55.08
(13.84) (13.44)
Years of schooling--head
Average 3.89 3.86
(2.87) (2.79)
0-3 years (percent) 25 24
4 years (percent) 62 64
5-16 years (percent) 14 12
No. of adult males in household 1.38 1.38
(0.91) (0.91)
No. of adult females in household 1.49 1.49
(0.75) (0.73)
No. of children (< 18 years) 1.64 1.52
in household (1.26) (1.22)
Mean past wealth (in 000s) 1,140,000 20,400
(25,100,000) (428,000)
Median past wealth (in 000s) 244 237
No. of observations 492 479
B. Business households, by year business was started
1992-97 1998 1999
Age of head 48.79 52.37 53.22
(14.89) (13.18) (13.99)
Years of schooling--head
Average 4.74 4.18 3.74
(3.35) (2.98) (3.04)
0-3 years (percent) 16 23 35
4 years (percent) 61 62 52
5-16 years (percent) 23 16 14
No. of adult males in household 1.46 1.56 1.39
(0.88) (1.01) (0.83)
No. of adult females in household 1.55 1.63 1.45
(0.77) (0.76) (0.61)
No. of children (< 18 years) 1.75 1.67 1.30
in household (1.20) (1.22) (1.00)
Mean past wealth (in 000s) 1,479 1,196 1,432
(2,994) (2,817) (3,383)
Median past wealth (in 000s) 258 414 398
No. of observations 102 208 67
2000 2001 1999-2001
Age of head 55.16 53.07 53.95
(12.69) (12.76) (13.11)
Years of schooling--head
Average 4.15 3.97 3.97
(3.01) (2.93) (2.99)
0-3 years (percent) 19 28 26
4 years (percent) 71 54 60
5-16 years (percent) 11 18 14
No. of adult males in household 1.44 1.61 1.47
(0.78) (0.97) (0.86)
No. of adult females in household 1.59 1.52 1.53
(0.68) (0.67) (0.66)
No. of children (< 18 years) 1.52 1.69 1.50
in household (1.12) (1.26) (1.13)
Mean past wealth (in 000s) 110,000 3,853 45,500
(1,000,000) (23,700) (634,000)
Median past wealth (in 000s) 325 319 328
No. of observations 85 61 213
Notes: Standard deviations are in parentheses. For 1998 through 2001,
two rows--mean past wealth and median past wealth--refer to wealth
in real 1997 Thai baht in the year prior to the year the business
started. For example, for the column headed 2000, past wealth is the
value of wealth in 1999, expressed in real 1997 Thai baht. However,
for the column headed 1997 in panel A, past wealth is the value of
wealth in 1991, expressed in real 1997 Thai baht. And for the column
headed 1992-97 in panel B, past wealth is the value of wealth in 1991,
expressed in real 1997 Thai baht. In panel B, for 1998 through 2001,
the figures describe businesses that were started in that given year
and were still in operation in 2001; the column headed 1992-97
describes businesses that were started between 1992 and 1997 and were
still in operation in 1997.
TABLE 3
Probit estimates of Thai business start-ups
Pre-crisis
dF/dx z-statistic
Age of head -0.0127 -2.36
Age of head squared 0.0001 2.14
Years of schooling--head 0.0097 2.46
No. of adult males in household 0.0135 1.12
No. of adult females in household 0.0055 0.37
No. of children (< 18 years) in household 0.0030 0.34
Past wealth 0.0226 2.53
Past wealth squared -0.0008 -1.77
Past member or customer of
Formal financial institutions (a) 0.0135 0.44
Village institutions/organizations (a) -0.0398 -1.12
Agricultural lenders (a) 0.0332 1.11
BAAC groups (a) -0.0009 -0.03
Moneylenders (a) -0.0160 -0.28
Pseudo R-squared (%) 12.94
Log likelihood -268.58
No. of observations 824
Crisis
dF/dx z-statistic
Age of head -0.0003 -0.02
Age of head squared 0.0000 -0.08
Years of schooling--head 0.0086 1.25
No. of adult males in household 0.0311 1.63
No. of adult females in household 0.0662 2.68
No. of children (< 18 years) in household -0.0014 -0.08
Past wealth 0.0318 1.11
Past wealth squared -0.0022 -0.77
Past member or customer of
Formal financial institutions (a) -0.0128 -0.33
Village institutions/organizations (a) -0.0320 -0.76
Agricultural lenders (a) -0.0033 -0.08
BAAC groups (a) 0.0749 1.70
Moneylenders (a) 0.0143 0.27
Pseudo R-squared (%) 14.67
Log likelihood -244.27
No. of observations 514
Post-crisis
dF/dx z-statistic
Age of head 0.0062 0.93
Age of head squared 0.0000 -0.83
Years of schooling--head 0.0079 1.88
No. of adult males in household 0.0217 1.72
No. of adult females in household -0.0077 -0.47
No. of children (< 18 years) in household 0.0021 0.22
Past wealth -0.0040 -0.85
Past wealth squared 0.0000 0.85
Past member or customer of
Formal financial institutions (a) 0.0098 0.43
Village institutions/organizations (a) 0.0096 0.39
Agricultural lenders (a) 0.0158 0.67
BAAC groups (a) -0.0086 -0.34
Moneylenders (a) 0.0404 1.21
Pseudo R-squared (%) 17.00
Log likelihood -212.70
No. of observations 472
(a) Dummy variables.
Notes: Pre-crisis refers to businesses that were started between 1992
and 1997 and were still in operation in 1997. Crisis refers to
businesses that were started in 1998 and were still in operation in
2001. Post-crisis refers to businesses that were started between 1999
and 2001 and were still in operation in 2001. For dummy variables,
dF/dx represents the change in probability when the dummy variable goes
from zero to one. For all other variables, dF/dx is the change in
probability from an infinitesimal change in the independent variable
in question. Past wealth is made up of the value of household assets,
agricultural assets, and land. The coefficient on past wealth in the
table is the actual one x [10.sup.6]. The coefficient on past wealth
squared is the actual one x [10.sup.12]. Sixteen geographic controls
are also included (tambons).
TABLE 4
Regression estimates of log initial Thai business investment
A. Businesses with initial investment greater than zero
Pre-crisis
Coefficient t-statistic
Age of head -0.0346 -0.37
Age of head squared 0.0000 0.06
Years of schooling--head 0.0914 1.54
No. of adult males in household 0.2145 0.96
No. of adult females in household 0.7075 2.57
No. of children (< 18 years) in household -0.1862 -1.07
Lag wealth 0.3930 2.16
Lag wealth squared -0.0156 -1.68
Constant 10.3572 4.28
Adjusted R-squared (%) 19.67
No. of observations 69
Crisis
Coefficient t-statistic
Age of head 0.0524 0.40
Age of head squared -0.0007 -0.56
Years of schooling--head 0.2669 3.57
No. of adult males in household -0.3217 -1.27
No. of adult females in household 0.8533 2.46
No. of children (< 18 years) in household -0.1154 -0.50
Lag wealth 0.0754 0.46
Lag wealth squared 0.0007 0.11
Constant 6.4398 1.83
Adjusted R-squared (%) 10.98
No. of observations 131
Post-crisis
Coefficient t-statistic
Age of head -0.2004 -1.58
Age of head squared 0.0018 1.55
Years of schooling--head 0.0278 0.41
No. of adult males in household 0.2084 0.70
No. of adult females in household 0.0865 0.24
No. of children (< 18 years) in household 0.1042 0.55
Lag wealth 0.2120 4.12
Lag wealth squared -0.0000 -4.12
Constant 12.9643 3.82
Adjusted R-squared (%) 16.13
No. of observations 95
B. All businesses
Pre-crisis
Coefficient t-statistic
Age of head 0.2688 1.07
Age of head squared -0.0027 -1.15
Years of schooling--head 0.0198 0.12
No. of adult males in household 0.6307 1.02
No. of adult females in household 0.7356 0.99
No. of children (< 18 years) in household -0.8216 -1.90
Lag wealth -0.8890 -1.05
Lag wealth squared 0.0212 0.17
Constant 1.3736 0.22
Adjusted R-squared (%) 8.89
No. of observations 99
Crisis
Coefficient t-statistic
Age of head 0.0288 0.15
Age of head squared -0.0005 -0.27
Years of schooling--head 0.2668 2.23
No. of adult males in household 0.2218 0.58
No. of adult females in household 0.2362 0.46
No. of children (< 18 years) in household 0.1276 0.42
Lag wealth 0.2720 1.03
Lag wealth squared -0.1150 -0.11
Constant 3.3881 0.65
Adjusted R-squared (%) 2.02
No. of observations 206
Post-crisis
Coefficient t-statistic
Age of head -0.3250 -1.68
Age of head squared 0.0028 1.63
Years of schooling--head 0.3569 3.18
No. of adult males in household 0.1204 0.33
No. of adult females in household 0.2049 0.40
No. of children (< 18 years) in household 0.4046 1.38
Lag wealth 0.0055 0.22
Lag wealth squared -0.0000 -0.21
Constant 10.3189 1.97
Adjusted R-squared (%) 6.37
No. of observations 214
Notes: Pre-crisis refers to businesses that were started between 1992
and 1997 and were still in operation in 1997. Crisis refers to
businesses that were started in 1998 and were still in operation in
2001. Post-crisis refers to businesses that were started between 1999
and 2001 and were still in operation in 2001. Lag wealth is made up
of the value of household assets, agricultural assets, and land in the
year prior to starting a business. The coefficient on lag wealth is
the actual one x [10.sup.6]. The coefficient on lag wealth squared is
the actual one x [10.sup.12]. The dependent variable is the natural
log of initial investment plus one. In panel A, only businesses with
non-zero initial investment are included. In panel B, all businesses,
regardless of initial investment, are included.