What is behind the rise in long-term unemployment?
Aaronson, Daniel ; Mazumder, Bhashkar ; Schechter, Shani 等
This article analyzes what is behind the recent unprecedented rise
in long-term unemployment and explains what this rise might imply for
the economy going forward. In particular, the authors attribute the
sharp increase in unemployment duration in 2009 to especially weak labor
demand and, to a lesser degree, extensions in unemployment insurance
benefits.
Introduction and summary
As we entered 2010, the average length of an ongoing spell of
unemployment in the United States was more than 30 weeks--the longest
recorded in the post-World War II era. Remarkably, more than 4 percent
of the labor force (that is, over 40 percent of those unemployed) were
out of work for more than 26 weeks--we consider these workers to be
long-term unemployed. In contrast, the last time unemployment reached 10
percent in the United States, in the early 1980s, the share of the labor
force that was long-term unemployed peaked at 2.6 percent. Although
there has been a secular rise in long-term unemployment over the last
few decades, the sharp increases that occurred during 2009 appear to be
outside of historical norms. Further, this trend may present important
implications for the aggregate economy and for macroeconomic policy
going forward.
The private cost of losing a job can be sizable. In the short run,
lost income is only partly offset by unemployment insurance (UI), making
it difficult for some households to manage their financial obligations
during spells of unemployment (Gruber, 1997; and Cherty, 2008). In the
long run, permanent earnings losses can be large, particularly for those
workers who have invested time and resources in acquiring knowledge and
skills that are specific to their old job or industry (Jacobson,
LaLonde, and Sullivan, 1993; Neal, 1995; Fallick, 1996; and Couch and
Placzek, 2010). Health consequences can be severe (Sullivan and von
Wachter, 2009). Research even suggests that job loss can lead to
negative outcomes among the children of the unemployed (Oreopoulos,
Page, and Stevens, 2008) and to an increase in crime (Fougere, Kramarz,
and Pouget, 2009).
All of these costs are likely exacerbated as unemployment spells
lengthen. The probability of finding a job declines as the length of
unemployment increases. Although there is some debate as to exactly what
this association reflects, it is certainly plausible that when
individuals are out of work longer, their labor market prospects are
diminished through lost job skills, depleted job networks, or stigma associated with a long spell of unemployment (Blanchard and Diamond,
1994) (1) For risk-averse households that cannot insure completely
against a fall in consumption as they deplete their precautionary
savings, the welfare consequences of job loss rise as unemployment
duration increases. Welfare implications are particularly severe during
periods of high unemployment for individuals with little wealth (Kruseil
et al., 2008).
In this article, we analyze the factors behind the recent
unprecedented rise in long-term unemployment and explain what this rise
might imply for the economy going forward. Using individual-level data
from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics' Current Population Survey
(CPS), we show that all of the substantial rise in the average duration
of unemployment between the mid-1980s and mid-2000s can be explained by
demographic changes in the labor force, namely, the aging of the
population and the increased labor force attachment of women (Abraham
and Shimer, 2002). But only one-half of the increase in average duration
of unemployment at the end of 2009 relative to that of the early 1980s
may be due to demographic factors. This suggests that other factors have
come into play more recently. In particular, we attribute the sharp
increase in unemployment duration in 2009 to especially weak labor
demand, as reflected in a low rate of transition out of unemployment
into employment, and a smaller portion of this increase (perhaps 10
percent to 25 percent) to extensions in unemployment insurance benefits.
(2)
We show that, in any given month, individuals with longer
unemployment spells are less likely to be employed the following month.
This suggests that the average ongoing spell of unemployment is likely
to remain longer than usual well into the economic recovery and
expansion, plausibly keeping the unemployment rate above levels observed
in past recoveries. For example, we find that if the current
distribution of unemployment duration resembled historical
distributions, the unemployment rate would be roughly 0.4 percentage
points lower than it is today. Nevertheless, we find no evidence that
high levels of long-term unemployment will have a sizable impact on
compensation growth going forward.
We begin by presenting some descriptive facts about trends and
business cycle movements of unemployment duration. We then analyze how
much of the increase in the recent average duration of unemployment
compared with that of the previous severe recession and its aftermath
(in 1982-83) can be explained by changes in the demographic, industrial,
and occupational composition of the labor force versus changes in the
average duration of unemployment within the various groups. We next
consider how much of the remaining increase can be attributed to weak
labor demand and extensions of unemployment benefits. Finally, we
examine how high levels of long-term unemployment may affect the
unemployment rate and compensation growth going forward.
The rise of long-term unemployment
We begin by reviewing some facts about unemployment spell length.
Long-run estimates of unemployment duration are available back to the
late 1940s from the Current Population Survey, a monthly survey of
60,000 or more households. Respondents are 16 years and older and are
asked to classify themselves as employed, unemployed, or out of the
labor force. Those unemployed are further asked how long, in weeks,
their unemployment has lasted. As a result, the CPS duration measures
are based on ongoing spells of unemployment and are not measures of
completed spell length.
Figure 1 plots the average (and median) duration of unemployment
from 1948 (and 1967) through the end of 2009. Over the past half
century, the average length of spells of unemployment have increased,
from 11.3 weeks in the 1960s to 11.8 weeks in the 1970s, 11.9 weeks in
the 1980s, 15.0 weeks in the 1990s, and 17.4 weeks in the 2000s. (3)
Figure 2 plots the share of the unemployed that are short-term (fewer
than five weeks) versus long-term (more than 26 weeks). There has been a
pronounced shift over time in the composition of the unemployed by
duration, with a particularly sharp change in 2009. Long-term
unemployment accounted for 10 percent of the unemployed in the 1950s and
1960s; it reached 26 percent in the early 1980s; and it averaged roughly
20 percent between 2002 and 2007, but reached 40 percent as of December
2009. (4) By the end of last year, over 4 percent of the labor force was
long-term unemployed.
The average duration of unemployment is counter-cyclical--that is,
it increases when the overall economy is shrinking, as figure 1 makes
clear. Therefore, figure 3, panel A presents a scatter plot of average
duration of unemployment against the unemployment rate to provide a
simple way of comparing durations conditional on the unemployment rate.
Each blue or black box represents a month. The black line represents the
relationship between the unemployment rate and average duration of
unemployment over the period 1948-2007. Because the line is upward
sloping, it illustrates that worse labor market conditions (higher
unemployment rates) are associated with longer unemployment spells. In
particular, through 2007, an extra 1 percentage point on the
unemployment rate was associated with spells that lasted 1.2 weeks
longer on average.
For the most recent period, we use black boxes to represent months
between December 2007 (the start of the most recent recession) and
December 2009 in figure 3, panel A. Note that all the black boxes lie
near the top of the cloud of blue boxes, highlighting that the average
unemployment spell tends to be much longer now for any given
unemployment rate. As the economy weakened and the unemployment rate
rose, the length of unemployment spells increased--and at a pace that
was fairly typical for a recession. This is represented by the black
boxes that lie roughly parallel to the black line. But, starting in June
2009 (the half dozen or so black boxes on the right side of panel A),
unemployment spells began to lengthen to unprecedented levels. Much of
this spike in average duration of unemployment is driven by the
unmistakable increase in the share of the unemployed out of work for
more than 26 weeks, highlighted by the black boxes in figure 3, panel B.
For instance, the average length of unemployment during the last six
months of 2009 was over seven weeks longer than that of the first six
months of 1983, when unemployment had peaked at 10.8 percent.
Looking forward, we should expect to see a historically long
average duration of unemployment for some time, since it is typical for
average spell length to rise well past the business cycle trough. This
is apparent in figure 4, which plots the cyclical pattern in the average
duration of unemployment versus the unemployment rate for several
selected cycles. In both the mid-1970s and the early 1980s (blue lines),
average duration stayed persistently high, even as the unemployment rate
began to decline. (5) As labor demand picks up early in a recovery,
employers might turn to unemployed workers with shorter spells first,
leaving the unemployment pool increasingly composed of those with
relatively longer spells. Sequential hiring patterns like this may be
due in part to a selection effect: Those who are less employable are the
ones who are likely to remain unemployed longer and are less likely to
be rehired. However, the lower reemployment probability of the long-term
unemployed may also be due to diminished job skills, weakened social
networks, and the assumption by some employers of poor worker quality
that accompany those with longer spells. Declines in job separations,
which we discuss in more detail later, may also reduce the number of
short spells of unemployment in the early stages of a recovery.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Unemployment duration versus other labor market measures
It is important to emphasize that the recent spike in the duration
of unemployment not only is quite large by historical standards but also
stands out relative to the recent deterioration in many other key labor
market indicators, including three key measures used to gauge labor
market slack: the unemployment rate, a broader unemployment rate (the
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics' U-6 rate), (6) and total payroll
employment. That observation can best be seen from a very simple
statistical model that uses gross domestic product (GDP) growth to
generate out-of-sample forecasts of these labor market measures. This
exercise when applied to the unemployment rate is the basis for what is
often referred to as "Okun's law.'" We follow
Aaronson, Brave and Schechter (2009) and use two samples to estimate
these relationships: l) all data from the first quarter of 1978 through
the second quarter of 2007 and 2) data solely from the recessions during
that period.
Figure 5 shows the results for four measures of the labor
market--namely, the unemployment rate, the U-6 rate, total payroll
employment, and the average duration of unemployment. Each panel of
figure 5 contains three colored lines. The blue line represents the
actual data, the black line is the forecast based on the data from our
full sample, and the gray line is the forecast based on only recession
periods in the full sample. Note that the recession sample forecasts use
the recession-period coefficients to forecast through the end of 2009,
even though the recession likely ended earlier.
Across all the measures in figure 5, the forecasts based on the
full sample of data consistently under-predict the deterioration in
labor market conditions. For example, the unemployment rate forecasted
(panel A) at the end of 2009 lies roughly 2 percentage points below the
actual unemployment rate, a finding noted by many commentators who worry
that Okun's law no longer applies and labor markets are not
functioning as in the past. However, if we use the recession sample
(gray line), this simple activity model does a remarkably good job at
forecasting the cumulative rise in the standard (panel A) and broader
(panel B) unemployment rates and the fall in total payroll employment
(panel C). That is, labor markets have mostly evolved about as we would
expect given the severity of the recession.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
But such a conclusion is not warranted for unemployment duration
(panel D of figure 5). (8) Forecasts based on both the full and
recession samples fail to predict by up to over a month the dramatic
rise in that series, starting in the fourth quarter of 2008. The
remainder of this article is therefore focused on explaining the causes
of the strikingly unusual increase in the length of unemployment spells.
Who are the long-term unemployed and how have they changed over
time?
Figure 3 (p. 31) highlights the spike in average unemployment
duration and long-term unemployment in 2009. It also illustrates that
unemployment duration was already historically high going into the
recent recession given the unemployment rate at the time. Relative to
the black regression line that predicts duration based on the
contemporaneous unemployment rate (figure 3, panel A), the black boxes
there suggest that unemployment spells were already about four to five
weeks higher, on average, than those during 1948-2007. For that reason,
at least part of the explanation for current lengths of unemployment
happened years ago.
Accordingly, table 1 examines the background characteristics of the
long-term unemployed, in particular gender, age, marital status, race,
education, industry, and occupational background in 2009, in 1983 (when
unemployment rates last reached 10 percent--and for the sake of
comparison in the aftermath of a similarly severe recession), and in
2005-07 (before the start of the recent downturn). We also compare the
distributions of these characteristics to their distributions in the
entire labor force in the second set of columns. (9) In the third set of
columns, we report the ratio of the share of the long-term unemployed to
the share in the labor force for each group. A number above 1 would
imply that long-term unemployment was unconditionally more common in
that group than would be expected given their representation in the
labor force.
In the early 1980s, long spells of unemployment tended to be
concentrated among factory and machine workers, who made up 29 percent
of the labor force but 55 percent of the long-term unemployed, or nearly
twice their representation in the work force (final row of table 1).
Consequently, the long-term unemployed also tended to be heavily male
(first column, first row) and only one in five long spells were from
individuals with at least some college education (first column,
fifteenth and sixteenth rows).
In 2009, factory and machine workers (and construction and
manufacturing workers in general), males, and those with no college
education still represented a larger share of the long-term unemployed
than they did of the labor force (third column versus sixth column).
(10) However, the long-term unemployed became sectorally more diverse.
(11) For example, in 2009, the long-term unemployed were more likely to
come from professional and business services and finance, insurance, and
real estate relative to 1983, while the share of manufacturing/factory
workers went down. Generally, in 2009, long-term unemployment was more
equally weighted across industry, occupation, education, gender, and age
groups, and was therefore more representative of the labor force and the
population than it had been two and a half decades ago.
Many important demographic shifts in the labor force have occurred
concurrently with changes in the average length of unemployment. This
has led several researchers (for example, Abraham and Shimer, 2002;
Valletta, 2005; and Mukoyama and Sahin, 2009) to suggest a link between
work force trends and unemployment duration. These links can be caused
by differences in the propensity to be rehired in a timely fashion after
job loss for particular demographic groups. For example, increases in
college experience, as well as the general skills that education
provides, might enable workers to be more adaptable and thus find job
matches more quickly (of course, more job-specific or industry-specific
skills could potentially slow the process down).
In table 2, we provide a simple breakdown of changes in average
duration of unemployment, using an approach called a Blinder/Oaxaca
decomposition. (12) This decomposition enables us to estimate how much
of the rise in unemployment duration is due to compositional changes in
the pool of unemployed workers (for example, age, gender, education, and
industrial composition); how much is due to longer spell lengths within
each group (for example, longer spells among women or construction
workers), holding the composition constant; and how much is due to
interactions between changes in compositional effects and coefficients.
We calculate these changes over two time periods roughly 20 to 25 years
apart. First, we compare 1985-86 to 2005-06, when the economy was in the
midst of expansions. Second, we examine two periods in our sample where
unemployment was 10 percent or higher--the first six months of 1983 and
the last six months of 2009 (that is, 1983:Q1-Q2 and 2009:Q3-Q4).
We find that most changes in the composition of the work force
account for little of the increase in average duration of unemployment.
(13) The notable exception is the age structure of the population.
Younger workers in the midst of a long unemployment spell tend to have
shorter spells of unemployment than older workers in the same situation
(Abraham and Shimer, 2002). Therefore, as the labor force has become
older, average spells have tended to become longer. In table 2 (first
column, second row), we show that changes in age can account for 0.7
weeks of the 1.3 increase in weeks from the mid-1980s to the mid-2000s,
or about 53 percent. Yet, the changing age composition only accounts for
about 25 percent of the rise in duration across the two periods of high
unemployment (second column, second row). This suggests that as the baby
boom generation continues to transition out of the labor force over the
next decade, we should expect the average duration of unemployment to
slowly fall.
The results of the decomposition also suggest that rising length of
unemployment among women (holding the share of women in the labor force
fixed) can account for virtually the entire increase in the average
duration from the mid-1980s to the mid-2000s (table 2, first column,
ninth row). This corresponds to the greater labor force attachment of
women in recent decades and confirms Abraham and Shimer (2002), whose
findings have a similar pattern. Change in unemployment duration within
industries (first column, twelfth row) can also account for some of the
secular pattern across expansions.
However, both the female and industry effects can explain a notably
smaller share of the total change in spell length when we compare the
changes across the two periods of high unemployment in the second column
of table 2. For example, changing coefficients for women can only
account for about 35 percent of the rise in the average duration of
unemployment across the two periods of high unemployment (second column,
ninth row). Industry effects almost completely disappear (second column,
twelfth row). Just under one-half (2.8 weeks out of 6.2 weeks) of the
increase in duration from the first half of 1983 to the second half of
2009 is explained by direct shifts in composition and coefficients
(second column, seventh and thirteenth rows).
Overall, the decomposition suggests that although demographic
factors can account for much of the secular increase in unemployment
duration, they can only account for a portion of the especially sharp
rise in durations that has accompanied this most recent recession. This
suggests that other factors must be driving this phenomenon--the topic
that we turn to next.
Labor market transitions, the unemployment rate, and unemployment
duration
In order to better understand the causes of the recent sharp rise
in long-term unemployment, it is useful to develop a framework for
studying labor market dynamics during the business cycle. In this
section, we begin formulating this framework by showing how movements
between being employed, unemployed, and out of the labor force (labor
market transitions) have contributed to cyclical patterns in
unemployment historically and during the most recent recession. We then
generate a model that uses labor market transitions to create
counterfactual scenarios that would correspond to alternative views of
what may be driving labor markets. Finally, we use this apparatus to
provide some insight into the causes of long-term unemployment. We also
use these results later to analyze the implications of long-term
unemployment for the aggregate economy going forward.
To measure labor market transitions, we exploit the fact that the
CPS interviews whatever household unit is living at a particular address
for four consecutive months, skips the address for eight months, and
then returns for more interviews over four consecutive months. This
allows us to track many household units over time. We follow previous
studies that have used matching algorithms to identify individuals who
are living at the same address in consecutive months and build a panel
data set containing the labor market status of individuals at multiple
points in time. Specifically, we consider the nine possible transition
probabilities (transition rates) across the states of employment (E),
unemployment (U), and out of the labor force (O).
Transition rates and the unemployment rate
Figure 6 plots these nine seasonally adjusted monthly transition
rates (blue lines), along with six-month moving averages of each to
smooth out some of the noise in the data (black lines). Two key
transitions for explaining past changes in the unemployment rate are
movements from employment to unemployment (EU) and unemployment to
employment (UE). (14) The EU transition rate measures the fraction of
employed individuals who separate from their employer and move into
unemployment. We will hereafter refer to this as the "separation
rate." (15) The UE rate is sometimes referred to as the hiring
rate. Shimer (2007) has argued that most of the variation in the
unemployment rate is due to fluctuations in the hiring rate rather than
the separation rate, although this conclusion has been disputed by
Elsby, Michaels, and Solon (2009), who argue that both rates have been
of significant importance. (16)
Movements in the EU have been particularly pronounced in this
recession: The separation rate has risen by nearly 70 percent. This
disproportionate hike is shown more clearly in figure 7 (p. 40), where
we compare the proportional change in the EU and UE transition rates in
the current business cycle with the recessionary periods in 1981-82 and
2001. The EU transition rate followed its historical pattern during 2008
but then began rising sharply early in 2009. Relative to the
acceleration in the EU rate, the UE rate appears to have fallen more
gradually, though proportionately more than in previous recessions.
To assess how important the transitions out of employment versus
transitions out of unemployment have been in explaining the rise in the
unemployment rate during the most recent downturn, we perform some
simple simulations. We start with the actual levels of those who are
employed, unemployed, and out of the labor force and the smoothed values
of all nine of the labor market transition rates at the end of 2007. We
then use the actual transition rates starting in January 2008 to
simulate the new counts of individuals in each labor market state for
each month going forward. This is described in greater detail in box 1
(p. 41). With some basic adjustments, we are able to match the actual
monthly unemployment rates through the end of 2009 almost perfectly.
We then conduct the following two experiments. First, we hold all
transition rates constant at their December 2007 values except for the
three transitions that start with the employment state in the initial
month (EE, EU, and EO). (17) Those transition rates are allowed to vary
according to what actually transpired in 2008 and 2009. In essence, this
exercise, which is plotted as the dark blue line on figure 8 (p. 42),
captures the effects of transitions out of employment into
non-employment (being either unemployed or out of the labor force) on
the aggregate unemployment rate. (18) Analogously, we do a second
experiment where only the transitions from the state of unemployment
(UE, UU, and UO) are allowed to change. This captures the effects of the
fall in the exit rate out of unemployment into being either employed or
out of the labor force. Those results are shown as the light blue line
in figure 8. The black line is the actual unemployment rate, and the
gray one is the actual unemployment rate in December 2007.
We find that the changes in the transition rates out of employment
(all else being equal) would only raise the unemployment rate by 1
percentage point by the end of 2009. In contrast, changes in the
transition rates out of unemployment would raise the unemployment rate
by 2.2 percentage points. Broadly speaking, this suggests that the
combined effects of moving out of unemployment (UE, UU, and
UO)--including, prominently, the transition into a job--explain more of
the actual increase in the unemployment rate over the past two years
than the combined effects of moving out of employment (EE, EU, and EO).
(19)
Transition rates and unemployment duration
We next turn to using these exercises to explain unemployment
duration. The simulation is similar as before except that we now
explicitly incorporate the distribution of unemployment duration into
the analysis by using five-week "bins" of unemployment spells
(that is, 0-4 weeks, 5-9 weeks, and so on). We start with the
distribution of unemployment duration at the end of 2007 and use
estimates of the actual transition rates into and out of unemployment
for each bin, along with estimates for the other transition rates, to
update the distribution of duration each month. We again find that the
simulation does extremely well at replicating the sharp rise in the
average duration of unemployment during 2009. (20)
In figure 9 (p. 42), we show that if only the EE, EU, and EO
followed their actual paths and all the other transition rates stayed
constant at their December 2007 values, the average duration of
unemployment would have only increased slightly, to about 19 weeks by
the end of 2009 (dark blue line). If, however, only UE, UU, and UO
followed their actual paths and the other transition rates stayed fiat,
unemployment duration would have increased to nearly 23 weeks (light
blue line). So it appears that for both the unemployment rate and the
average duration of unemployment, transition rates from the starting
state of unemployment have been the important driving influences. (21)
Simulated effects of federal unemployment insurance benefit
extensions
As noted previously, the spike in the average duration of
unemployment starting in mid-2009 is hard to explain using demographics or the standard association with deteriorating GDP growth. One plausible
explanation is the unprecedented extension of unemployment insurance
benefits. The maximum number of weeks of eligibility rose from 26 weeks
to 39 weeks in July 2008 with the passage and creation of the Emergency
Unemployment Compensation (EUC) federal program. Since then, extensions
have risen at varying rates, depending on the unemployment situation of
individual states. (22) Figure 10 (p. 43) plots the weighted national
average of the maximum number of weeks of unemployment benefit receipt
allowed (blue line); the weights for this average are based on the size
of the unemployment pool in each state. As of January 2010, unemployed
workers in 14 states were allowed the maximum of 99 weeks of UI benefits
and the national average was 90 weeks. By contrast, in 1983, the maximum
potential duration of UI coverage in any state had reached 55 weeks.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
In order to estimate the possible effect of UI benefit extensions
on unemployment duration, we use previous studies of the effect of an
additional week of maximum benefits on average duration. A prominent
example in this literature is Katz and Meyer (1990), who use a rich
statistical model and administrative data from the UI system to estimate
the probability of leaving unemployment during the early 1980s
recessions. They identify the impact of UI through variation in maximum
benefits both within and across states that shift as a result of
eligibility rules and legislative changes. They find that the average
duration of unemployment rises by 0.16 weeks to 0.2 weeks for each
additional week of benefits extended.
Katz and Meyer (1990) face the difficult problem of disentangling
the effects of UI benefit extensions from the effects of poor economic
conditions that typically prompt benefit extensions in the first place.
When the economy is in a recession, longer spells of unemployment are
expected irrespective of the generosity of the unemployment insurance
program. To get around this problem, Card and Levine (2000) use an
increase in the maximum number of weeks of benefit eligibility in New
Jersey in 1996; this increase was unrelated to the state of the economy
at the time. In fact, this particular extension, which was driven by
political considerations, took place in the midst of an expansion and
therefore might be less susceptible to the bias of recession-driven
extensions. Indeed, they find a smaller effect than Katz and Meyer
(1990) and much of the rest of the literature; mean duration rises by
about 0.1 weeks for each additional week of benefits. In order to
reflect our uncertainty over the true effect, we use both estimates.
We begin our analysis in June 2008, when maximum UI eligibility was
26 weeks and unemployment spells lasted about 17 weeks on average (the
six-month mean from January through June 2008). We then calculate an
estimated effect of the extension in unemployment benefits for each
subsequent month beginning with July 2008. (23) For such a calculation,
two additional inputs are required. First, we need the share of the
unemployed who are actually receiving benefits because they are the only
ones who would be directly affected by policy changes. The black line in
figure 10 (p. 43) shows that the share of the unemployed receiving UI
surged from 41 percent in July 2008 to 67 percent in December 2009.
Second, we must assume a time period over which to distribute the full
effect of the extension in benefits. We distribute the effects of the
initial 13-week extension of benefits that took place in July 2008 over
a full year. (24) The additional extensions that increased the maximum
potential duration in the UI system beyond 52 weeks, beginning in
December 2008, are spread over two years because the much larger
extensions are likely to alter behavior over a longer period of time.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Using these inputs, our estimates based on the Katz and Meyer
(1990) elasticity suggest that the extension of U1 benefits during 2008
and 2009 may account for as much as 3.1 weeks of the 12-week increase in
the average duration of unemployment that took place over this period.
The estimate based on the Card and Levine (2000) analysis suggests that
it could explain about 1.6 weeks. These assessments, which we consider
our range of preferred estimates, suggest that the effect of
unemployment insurance extensions on the average duration of
unemployment is on the order of 10-25 percent of the total increase
since July 2008. Alternatively, if we spread the effect of the
extensions beginning in December 2008 over just one year, this would
raise our estimates of the contributions to between 3 weeks and 6 weeks,
or between 25 percent and 50 percent. It is also important to note that
our calculations have not considered the potential effect of the
"reach back" provision in the EUC program that allowed
extensions for those who had exhausted their unemployment benefits as
early as May 1, 2007. It is possible that this provision could further
raise our estimates of the impact of UI benefits.
Effects of unemployment insurance benefit extensions on the
unemployment rate
We can also utilize the transition data to examine whether
movements from unemployment to out of the labor force (UO) and those in
the opposite direction (OU) yield additional clues about possible
changes in classification between the non-employed that may have arisen
as a result of UI benefit extensions. In figure 11, panel A (p. 44), we
plot all the possible transitions from unemployment during the current
business cycle (blue lines) and compare them with those during the 2001
recession and its aftermath (black lines). The series with the boxes
represent the UE transition rates and are identical to those shown in
figure 7 (p. 40). To this we add UU transition rates (diamonds) and UO
(circles) rates. It appears that the UU and UO rates in the current
recession track the rates in 2001 reasonably well for the first 16 or so
months of the downturn before beginning to diverge. In contrast, the UE
rates diverge earlier in the cycle. One possible reason for this pattern
is that individuals who would have normally dropped out of the labor
force at this point in the cycle chose to remain unemployed--perhaps to
continue to collect unemployment benefits.
BOX 1
Methodology for simulating paths of the unemployment rate and
unemployment durations
In this article, we use transitions across different labor market
states as a tool for simulating the paths of the unemployment rate
and unemployment durations. This allows us to consider alternative
scenarios for the path of the unemployment rate or durations either
historically or going forward based on changing the paths of
particular transitions. Using this approach, we can infer the
relative importance of particular economic phenomena that are
related to certain transitions as described in the text. An
important caveat is that this is a mechanical approach that may or
may not correspond well to changes in the actual economy. For
example, conditions that may change a particular transition rate
may also affect other transition rates in ways that we may not
consider.
If we consider time as discrete and denote it as t and let x stand
for a particular labor market state, that is, employed, unemployed,
or out of the labor force, (x = {E,U,O}), then each of the nine
possible transitions are defined as the probability of being in a
particular labor market state in t conditional on having been in
the same or different labor market state in the prior period. For
example, the EU transition is defined as:
EU = Prob ([x.sub.t] = U][x.sub.t-1] = E).
For each initial state in t - 1, the three possible transitions
must sum to 1. For example, EE + EU + EO = 1. Each of the nine
transitions for each month is estimated empirically using the
matched Current Population Survey as described in the text. To
implement the simulation we start by inputting the levels of those
who are employed, unemployed, and out of the labor force for a
chosen base period. We then simulate the next period's level of E,
U, and O, using the assumed levels for the base period and an
assumed path for the transition probabilities. For example, if we
wish to simulate the actual path of the unemployment rate through
2008 and 2009, we define December 2007 as our base period and then
use the actual estimated values of the transition probabilities for
January 2008 through December 2009. (1)
For example:
[E.sub.Jan08], = [E.sub.Dec07] x [EE.sub.Jan08] + [U.sub.Dec07] x
[EU.sub.Jan08] + [O.sub.Dec07] x [EO.sub.Jan08]
We use several methods to pose alternative transition rates,
depending on our question of interest. To address the relative
importance of transitions from employment versus transitions from
unemployment, we start with a baseline path where all of the
transition rates are constant. We then change the paths of all
three transition rates from either employment or unemployment
simultaneously. For example, we simulate the effects arising only
from changes from the employment state by changing the paths of EE,
EU, and EO simultaneously.
A second approach is used when we wish to hold the UO and OU
transition rates fixed at a particular rate. In this case, we allow
the UE and OE rates to follow their actual paths and then adjust
the UU and OO so that the probabilities from U and from 0 each sum
to I. Finally, for the simulation that attempts to reproduce the
forecast of the unemployment rate according to the Blue Chip
Economic Indicators, we assume that the EU, EE, UU, and UE rates
take five years to return to their historical average values. We
then adjust the EO and UO rates so that the three transitions from
E and from U sum to 1.
(1) Rather than immediately going from the base period to the first
period of the simulation, we first use the transition rates from
the base period and run about ten iterations of the model so that
the values or E, U, and O and the implied unemployment rate reach a
steady state, where they are unchanging. We then proceed to use the
steady-state values for the simulation. The steady-state values may
differ from the actual values in the base period. For example, the
steady-state value of the unemployment rate in December 2007 is
about 80 percent of the actual value. We therefore scale the
subsequent values of the simulation by a factor of 1.25. This
discrepancy is likely due in part to the inability to account for
month-to-month compositional changes that arise from the fact that
individuals enter or exit the working age population. Measurement
error and differences between the complete population and the
matched sample may also play a role. This approach assumes that
although we cannot match the level of unemployment, we can match
changes over time.
In figure 11, panel B (p. 44), we focus only on the rate of UO
transitions and add data from the 1981-82 recession (dotted). This panel
shows that the UO path during the current recession resembles the UO
path during the 1981-82 recession reasonably well, suggesting that the
departure from the 2001 pattern may simply reflect the greater severity
of the current recession. That said, figure 11, panel C suggests that
the rate of OU transitions in the current recession appears to move
substantially higher in percentage terms than the patterns observed
during the previous downturns.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
We conduct a simulation motivated by figure 11 to ask how different
the unemployment rate would be had the paths of the UO and OU
transitions stayed constant at their values 16 months after the start of
the recession (April 2009). In order to ensure that the probabilities
from a particular state add up to 1, we allow the UE and OE rates to
follow their actual paths and adjust the UU and OO rates so that the
probabilities sum to 1. Figure 12 shows that under this counterfactual
scenario the result of this exercise would be to lower the unemployment
rate to 9.3 percent as of December 2009--about 0.7 percentage points
below the actual unemployment rate that month. Although this is a
relatively crude and mechanical approach, it nonetheless provides a
magnitude for the possible effect of unemployment insurance benefit
extensions on the unemployment rate.
Implications of long-term unemployment for the aggregate economy
In this section, we consider how the increase in long-term
unemployment may affect the economy going forward. We consider the
effects of the unemployment duration structure on the unemployment rate
and then on compensation growth.
Effects of duration structure on the unemployment rate
As unemployment spells lengthen, the probability of finding a job
in a given time period declines--an association that is robust across
time and demographic groups. The pattern is illustrated in figure 13 (p.
46), which plots the probability of being employed today for various
lengths of unemployment duration in the previous month (horizontal
axis). For example, at 0-4 weeks of unemployment, the average
probability of finding a job in the following month is 34 percent, but
at 25-29 weeks, it is only 19 percent. (25) As much as this phenomenon
is due to diminished job skills and weakened social networks, it could
have a real impact on the labor market recovery while the broader
economic recovery takes hold.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
In order to investigate this possibility, we use our transition
rate model but substitute aggregate transition rate probabilities for
movement from unemployment (UE, UU, and UO) with analogous transition
rate probabilities for each five-week bin of unemployment duration. We
start by simulating a baseline path that roughly matches the January 10,
2010, forecast of the unemployment rate through 2011 according to the
Blue Chip Economic Indicators (Blue Chip), a survey of America's
top business economists (Aspen Publishers, 2010). We then pose an
alternative path where the only change is to make the share of the
unemployed in each five-week bin at the beginning of the simulation
(January 2010) match their mean historical values. In figure 14, panel
A, we show that this alternative initial distribution of duration would
immediately lower the unemployment rate by about 0.4 percentage points
relative to the Blue Chip path. We find, however, that duration quickly
reverts back to high levels (figure 14, panel B) and that the
unemployment rate path converges to what it would have been had the
model started with the actual distribution of duration. The main lesson
we take from this exercise is that the unemployment rate is probably
about half a point higher than it would be if unemployment spell lengths
were at more historical levels.
Effects of duration structure on compensation growth
Lastly, we consider the possible effects of higher long-term
unemployment rates on aggregate wage growth. It is not obvious a priori what the expected effects should be. If the long-term unemployed are
readily employable and can fulfill vacancies, then there is a sense in
which they may be more eager to return to work at the prevailing wage than individuals with short unemployment durations. In this case, the
long-term unemployed may reduce wage pressures. If, however, many of the
long-term unemployed are more akin to individuals who have stopped
searching for work and have left the labor force, perhaps because of a
geographical or skills mismatch, then they may play little role in
bidding down wages.
Since this is ultimately an empirical question, we undertake a
simple exercise using Phillips curve style regressions to address this.
We use data on year-over-year growth in real compensation per hour.
Figure 15 (p. 48) shows that, as expected, there is a negative
relationship between compensation growth and the unemployment rate. The
black boxes signify the values starting with 2008:Q1, when the recession
began. We regress compensation growth on the unemployment rate for the
post-1975 period and calculate the predicted values. We then add the
share of the unemployed in each of the five-week bins of unemployment
duration to the regression and reestimate the model. We plot both sets
of the forecasted values, along with the actual growth rate of real
compensation, in figure 16. We find that there is little difference in
magnitude between the two forecasts. For much of the past 20 years, the
predictions that incorporate unemployment duration are slightly lower
than those that do not. However, there is little economically important
difference in the most recent period. Overall, this suggests that at
least for predicting aggregate compensation trends, there is no
clear-cut indication that rising unemployment duration will signify any
more or less slack than the information contained in the unemployment
rate. This might be because rising unemployment duration produces
countervailing forces on wage pressures as hypothesized earlier.
However, the statistical model used to estimate these relationships is
based on historical associations, whereas the current distribution of
unemployment spell length is unprecedented.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
Conclusion
The average length of an ongoing spell of unemployment topped 30
weeks in December 2009, with more than 40 percent of the unemployed out
of work for over six months. These numbers far exceed anything recorded
in the post-World War II era. In this article, we analyze the factors
behind this historically unprecedented rise in long-term unemployment
and explain what it might imply for the economy going forward. We show
that roughly half of the rise relative to previous deep modern
recessions was due to demographic factors in place well before the
recession began. The remaining unexplained increase is due primarily to
especially weak labor demand, reflected in low levels of hiring. Perhaps
10-25 percent of the increase in long-term unemployment from mid-2008 to
the end of 2009 is associated with extensions of unemployment insurance
benefits. These estimates for the current business cycle constitute a
notable departure from historical patterns in transitions between being
unemployed and out of the labor force. Some simple counterfactual
estimates suggest that had these transitions followed more typical
patterns, the unemployment rate might be about 0.7 percentage points
lower. Finally, we find that high levels of long-term unemployment
typically persist well into an economic recovery, since firms tend to
hire the long-term unemployed last. Some simple simulations suggest that
a historically long unemployment duration distribution as currently
experienced in the United States could slow the process of labor market
recovery, but it is not expected to have much of an impact on
compensation growth.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 16 OMITTED]
REFERENCES
Aaronson, Daniel, Scott Brave, and Shani Schechter, 2009, "How
does labor adjustment in this recession compare with the past?,"
Chicago Fed Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, No. 263, June.
Aaronson, Daniel, and Daniel G. Sullivan, 1998, "The decline
of job security in the 1990s: Displacement, anxiety, and their effect on
wage growth," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, Vol. 22, No. 1, First Quarter, pp. 17-43.
Aaronson, Daniel, Ellen R. Rissman, and Daniel G. Sullivan, 2004,
"Can sectoral reallocation explain the jobless recovery?,"
Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 28, No. 2,
Second Quarter, pp. 36-49.
Abraham, Katherine G., and Robert Shimer, 2002, "Changes in
unemployment duration and labor force attachment," in The Roaring Nineties: Can Full Employment Be Sustained?, Alan B. Krueger and Robert
M. Solow (eds.), New York: Russell Sage Foundation and Century
Foundation, pp. 367-420.
Aspen Publishers, 2010, "Quarterly Blue Chip forecasts,"
Blue Chip Economic Indicators, Vol. 35, No. 1, January 10, p. 5.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Peter Diamond, 1994, "Ranking,
unemployment duration, and wages," Review of Economic Studies, Vol.
61, No. 3, July, pp. 417-434.
Card, David, and Phillip B. Levine, 2000, "Extended benefits
and the duration of UI spells: Evidence from the New Jersey extended
benefit program," Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 78, Nos. 1-2,
October, pp. 107-138.
Chatterjee, Satyajit, and Dean Corbae, 2007, "On the aggregate
welfare cost of Great Depression unemployment," Journal of Monetary
Economics, Vol. 54, No. 6, September, pp. 1529-1544.
Chetty, Raj, 2008, "Moral hazard versus liquidity and optimal
unemployment insurance," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 116,
No. 2, pp. 173-234.
Couch, Kenneth A., and Dana W. Placzek, 2010, "Earnings losses
of displaced workers revisited," American Economic Review, Vol.
100, No. 1, March, pp. 572-589.
Eichengreen, Barry, and T. J. Hatton (eds.), 1988, Interwar Unemployment in International Perspective, Dordrect, Netherlands: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Elsby, Michael W. L., Ryan Michaels, and Gary Solon, 2009,
"The ins and outs of cyclical unemployment," American Economic
Journal. Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, No. 1, January, pp. 84-110.
Fallick, Bruce C., 1996, "A review of the recent empirical
literature on displaced workers," Industrial and Labor Relations
Review, Vol. 50, No. 1, October, pp. 5-16.
Fougere, Denis, Francis Kramarz, and Julien Pouget, 2009,
"Youth unemployment and crime in France," Journal of the
European Economic Association, Vol. 7, No. 5, September, pp. 909-938.
Gruber, Jonathan, 1997, "The consumption smoothing benefits of
unemployment insurance," American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 1,
March, pp. 192-205.
Ham, John C., and Samuel A. Rea, Jr., 1987, "Unemployment
insurance and male unemployment duration in Canada," Journal of
Labor Economics, Vol. 5, No. 3, July, pp. 325-353.
Jacobson, Louis S., Robert J. LaLonde, and Daniel G. Sullivan,
1993, "Earnings losses of displaced workers," American
Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 4, September, pp. 685-709.
Katz, Lawrence F., and Bruce D. Meyer, 1990, "The impact of
the potential duration of unemployment benefits on the duration of
unemployment," Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 41, No. 1,
February, pp. 45-72.
Kiefer, Nicholas M., 1988, "Economic duration data and hazard
functions," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 26, No. 2, June,
pp. 646-679.
Krusell, Per, Toshihiko Mukoyama, Aysegul Sahin, and Anthony A.
Smith, Jr., 2008, "Revisiting the welfare effects of eliminating
business cycles," Federal Reserve Bank of New York, working paper,
December, available at www.newyorkfed.org/
research/economists/sahin/kmss.pdf.
Machin, Stephen, and Alan Manning, 1999, "The causes and
consequences of long-term unemployment in Europe," in Handbook of
Labor Economics, Vol. 3C, Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.),
Amsterdam: Elsevier, North-Holland, pp. 3085-3139.
Mazumder, Bhashkar, 2008, "New evidence on labor market
dynamics over the business cycle," Economic Perspectives, Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 31, No. 1, First Quarter, pp. 36-46.
Meyer, Bruce D., 1995, "Lessons from the U.S. unemployment
insurance experiments," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 33,
No. 1, March, pp. 91-131.
--, 1990, "Unemployment insurance and unemployment
spells," Econometrica, Vol. 58, No. 4, July, pp. 757-782.
Mukoyama, Toshihiko, and Aysegul Sahin, 2009, "Why did the
average duration of unemployment become so much longer?," Journal
of Monetary Economics, Vol. 56, No. 2, March, pp. 200-209.
Neal, Derek, 1995, "Industry-specific human capital: Evidence
from displaced workers," Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 13, No.
4, October, pp. 653-677.
Oreopoulos, Philip, Marianne Page, and Ann Huff Stevens, 2008,
"The intergenerational effects of worker displacement,"
Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 26, No. 3, pp. 455-483.
Rissman, Ellen R., 2009, "Employment growth: Cyclical
movements or structural change?," Economic Perspectives, Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 33, No. 4, Fourth Quarter, pp. 40-57.
Shimer, Robert, 2007, "Reassessing the ins and outs of
unemployment," National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper,
No. 13421, September.
Sullivan, Daniel G., and Till von Wachter, 2009, "Job
displacement and mortality: An analysis using administrative data,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 124, No. 3, August, pp. 1265-1306.
Valletta, Robert G., 2005, "Rising unemployment duration in
the United States: Causes and consequences," Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco, working paper, May, available at
www.frbsf.org/economics/ economists/rvalletta/RV_duration_5-05_new.pdf.
Valletta, Robert G., and Aisling Cleary, 2008, "Sectoral
reallocation and unemployment," FRBSF Economic Letter, Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, No. 2008-32, October 17.
Woytinsky, W. S., 1942, Three Aspects of Labor Dynamics,
Washington, DC: Social Science Research Council.
NOTES
(1) Alternatively, the relationship between the length of time out
of work and the diminishment of work prospects could be picking up
unobserved differences in worker quality between those who are
unemployed for short and long spells (Ham and Rea, 1987; Kiefer, 1988;
and Machin and Manning, 1999). In this case, longer spells in and of
themselves do not lead to worse outcomes. It is very difficult to
convincingly identify which of these channels dominates without strong
statistical assumptions.
(2) Based on transition patterns between being employed,
unemployed, and out of the labor force altogether, we estimate that UI
extensions increased the unemployment rate by roughly 0.7 percentage
points during 2008-09.
(3) Long-term unemployment is a good deal less common in the United
States than in much of the developed world (for example, Machin and
Manning, 1999). As of 2008, the last year for which comparable data are
available, the share of the unemployed out of work more than six months
was two times, and in some cases four times, higher in Belgium, the
Czech Republic, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Luxembourg, the
Netherlands, Portugal, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and Japan.
(4) The most recent numbers from the Current Population Survey are
still well below the prevalence of long-term unemployment during the
Great Depression. Unfortunately, national data on unemployment duration
before World War 11 are not systematically available. Definitions of
unemployment also varied across surveys and are different from the
modern one. That said, Eichengreen and Hatton (1988) report that more
than a third of males who were looking for work in 1930 had been
unemployed for at least 14 weeks and 55 percent of ongoing unemployment
spells had lasted at least six months in 1940. Eichengreen and Hatton
also reproduce data from Woytinsky (1942), showing the year-to-year
changes in unemployment duration in Philadelphia during the 1930s. In
1933, for example, over 80 percent of the unemployed had spells of at
least six months. Chatterjee and Corbae (2007) describe a special
January 1931 census of the unemployed in Boston, New York, Philadelphia,
Chicago, and Los Angeles, which reported that 45 percent, 61 percent, 45
percent, 61 percent, and 33 percent were jobless for at least 18 weeks,
respectively.
(5) As can also be seen in figures 1 and 2 (p. 30), it took
particularly long for average and median unemployment duration and the
share of the long-term unemployed to return to pre-recession levels
following the 1990-91 and 2001 recessions.
(6) The U-6 rate, available since 1994, includes marginally
attached workers and part-time workers who want and are available for
fulltime work but had to settle for a part-time schedule for economic
reasons. The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics classifies individuals as
"marginally attached" if they "indicate that they want
and are available for a job and have looked for work sometime in the
recent past" but are not currently looking We derived a simulated
U-6 series from 1978 onward based on similar questions in the CPS The
simulated series replicates the actual reported series from 1994 onward.
(7) Okun's law simply states a linear negative relationship
exists between economic activity (that is, GDP growth) and the
unemployment rate.
(8) To be clear, there are other series that are hard to forecast
within this simple statistical model. We also underpredict the increase
in those who are part-time workers for economic reasons and the fraction
of the population outside of the labor force but not marginally
attached. These results are not reported but available upon request.
(9) All of the inferences here are the same if the base of
comparison is the full population rather than the labor force.
(10) This is true even when controlling simultaneously for all of
the characteristics listed in table 1 (p. 35) in a regression framework
(11) See Aaronson and Sullivan (1998) for similar results on job
displacement and job insecurity.
(12) To implement the Blinder/Oaxaca decomposition, a separate
regression is run for each time period. The change in average duration
of unemployment over the two periods is then decomposed into a portion
due to changes in the levels of the explanatory variables (for example,
the fraction of females and the fraction that has completed less than
high school), a portion due to changes in the coefficients on these
explanatory variables, and a residual term that captures the effects of
the interactions (that is, simultaneously changing the levels and
coefficients)
Specifically, let unemployment duration [D.sub.it] be specific to
an individual i and a time period t. To keep things simple, we use two
time periods--the 1980s, which is indexed as t = 1, and the 2000s, which
is indexed as t = 2. We show the results by comparing expansions
(1985-86 versus 2005-06 in the first column of table 2 on p. 36) and
comparing periods of high unemployment (first half of 1983 versus second
half of 2009 in table 2, second column). Duration is determined by
characteristics [X.sub.it] (for example, gender and age) that are also
specific to individual i and time period t.
We can write this statistical model as [D.sub.it] =
[X.sub.it][b.sub.t] + [e.sub.it], where [e.sub.it] is an error term. The
decomposition is then [D.sub.1] - [D.sub.2] = ([X.sub.t] -
[X.sub.2])[b.sub.2] + [X.sub.2]([b.sub.1] - [b.sub.2]) + ([X.sub.1] -
[X.sub.2])([b.sub.1] - [b.sub.2]). The first term after the equal sign
is reported in the first set of rows in table 2 ("due to changes in
composition"). The second term is reported in the second set of
rows ("due to changes in coefficients"), and the third term is
the row labeled "interactions between changes in composition and
coefficients."
Running this decomposition on the share of the unemployed
undergoing long-term spells of unemployment yields similar results.
Those are available upon request.
(13) Notably, changes in industrial structure have little impact.
See, for example, Rissman (2009), Valletta and Cleary (2008), and
Aaronson, Rissman, and Sullivan (2004) on the role of sectoral
reallocation on labor market conditions during recent recessions.
(14) Movements between being in and out of the labor force play a
much smaller role in explaining shifts in the unemployment rate, so this
discussion largely abstracts from these transitions for simplicity. But
we return to transitions between being unemployed and out of the labor
force (UO and OU) during the most recent recession later in the article.
(15) The term "separations," however, is often used
elsewhere to represent all transitions out of a particular job,
including job-to-job transitions. The separation and hiring rates
reported in the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics' Job Openings and
Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS) and Business Employment Dynamics (BED)
survey also include out of the labor force transitions.
(16) Mazumder (2008), using the US. Census Bureau's Survey of
Income and Program Participation (SIPP), also finds that the separation
rate has been of somewhat greater importance in recent recessions than
suggested by Shimer (2007).
(17) Typically, EE is a continuously employed person. However, it
can also be someone who transitions from one job to another without a
spell of non-employment.
(18) It is important to note that there is an "adding up"
constraint because the three probabilities must sum to 1. Therefore, it
is not possible to vary the paths of all three variables simultaneously.
(19) It should be noted that this transition model is not additive.
Allowing all of the transitions starting from E and all the transitions
starting from U to follow their actual course (simultaneously) accounts
for about 3.4 percentage points of the actual increase of 5 percentage
points in the unemployment rate, leaving some significant share of the
increase attributable to changes in transitions starting from O.
(20) We also match the rise in the share of the long-term
unemployed quite well.
(21) While this result is unlikely to be surprising, it should be
noted that it need not be the case. The length of unemployment can
increase, with a lag, from a surge in job separations.
(22) Some of the variation in federal extensions occurs at the
state level because of state-specific triggers for unemployment
insurance benefit extensions that depend on the severity of unemployment
at the state level.
(23) Specifically, for each month we multiply the difference in the
maximum eligibility of UI benefits over and beyond 26 weeks by the
elasticity of a one-week increase in extensions on average duration of
unemployment. This product is scaled by the fraction of the unemployed
receiving UI benefits in that month. The resulting estimate represents
the full effect of the extension over some period of time. We then
divide this effect by 12 to effectively spread out the total effect over
the next 12 months. Finally, we take a running sum of the effects over
the previous 12 months. Starting in December 2008, when maximum UI
eligibility exceeded one year, we began to spread the effect over the
next two years. See note 24 for more details on the choice of how long
to spread out the impact of the extension.
(24) The effect of an extension on the average duration of
unemployment is not instantaneous. For example, the elasticity of 0.2
from Katz and Meyer (1990) is based on simulating their model on
individuals over a two-year period. They found similar results from
simulating the model over one year or three years. If we were to spread
the effect of the initial increase in benefits over two years, this
would lower the estimated contributions of the UI extensions only up
until October 2009, but would have no effect on the total contributions
as of December 2009.
(25) Note that there is no spike at 26 weeks, the typical maximum
number of weeks of U1 eligibility. Although the CPS does not show a
spike, administrative unemployment insurance records typically do (see,
for example, Ham and Rea, 1987; Katz and Meyer, 1990; and Meyer, 1990,
1995).
Daniel Aaronson is a vice president and economic advisor in the
Economic Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Bhashkar Mazumder is a senior economist in the Economic Research
Department and the executive director of the Chicago Census Research
Data Center at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Shani Schechter is
an associate economist in the Economic Research Department at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors thank Lisa Barrow, Bruce
Meyer, and Dan Sullivan for helpful comments and Constantine Yannelis
for excellent research assistance.
TABLE 1
Descriptive statistics: Long-term unemployed and labor force
Long-term unemployed
1983 2005-07 2009
Gender Male 67.6 55.5 58.6
Female 32.4 44.5 41.4
Age 16-24 23.6 21.0 18.3
25-54 65.5 62.1 63.4
55-64 9.8 13.5 14.3
65 and over 1.1 3.5 4.0
Marital Not married 50.9 65.7 62.4
status Married 49.1 34.3 376
Race White 70.6 56.9 59.8
Black 20.6 23.0 18.4
Hispanic 3.1 8.5 6.9
Other 5.6 11.6 14.9
Education Less than high school 32.8 23.2 18.9
High school graduate 46.3 35.6 37.1
Some college 13.4 24.5 27.4
College graduate 7.6 16.7 16.5
Industry Agriculture, fishing, forestry,
and mining 5.1 1.7 2.0
Utilities and sanitation 0.8 0.6 0.7
Construction 11.4 10.2 14.1
Manufacturing 34.6 13.8 15.7
Wholesale trade 3.2 2.6 2.3
Retail trade 9.7 13.8 12.2
Transportation and warehousing 4.5 3.8 3.9
Finance, insurance, and real
estate and leasing/rental 2.6 4.7 5.8
Professional/business services
and information 5.2 15.8 15.3
Health, education, and social
services 8.1 13.4 11.4
Other services 11.1 16.3 14.4
Government 3.0 3.0 1.8
Occupation Executive and managerial 4.8 8.1 10.1
Professional and technical 5.3 11.3 10.5
Sales 6.3 11.7 11.5
Administrative support 10.7 14.1 13.6
Services 14.6 21.5 18.0
Farming, forestry, and fishing 2.6 1.2 1.0
Factory/machine workers 55.0 31.6 35.0
Labor force
1983 2005-07 2009
Gender Male 56.0 52.4 52.2
Female 44.0 47.6 47.8
Age 16-24 21.1 14.1 13.1
25-54 64.9 67.7 66.4
55-64 11.1 14.1 15.7
65 and over 3.0 4.1 4.8
Marital Not married 39.0 43.8 44.1
status Married 61.0 56.2 55.9
Race White 83.1 73.9 72.9
Black 8.8 8.6 8.8
Hispanic 3.1 6.5 6.7
Other 5.0 11.0 11.6
Education Less than high school 29.3 17.2 15.9
High school graduate 37.9 30.9 30.3
Some college 17.0 26.6 27.2
College graduate 15.9 25.3 26.7
Industry Agriculture, fishing, forestry,
and mining 5.2 2.6 2.6
Utilities and sanitation 1.4 1.1 1.2
Construction 6.7 8.1 7.5
Manufacturing 19.1 10.9 10.2
Wholesale trade 4.1 3.0 2.6
Retail trade 11.8 11.7 11.4
Transportation and warehousing 4.0 4.2 4.1
Finance, insurance, and real
estate and leasing/rental 6.0 7.0 6.7
Professional/business services
and information 7.5 12.2 12.6
Health, education, and social
services 16.5 21.4 22.7
Other services 12.9 13.0 13.5
Government 4.8 4.8 4.9
Occupation Executive and managerial 10.2 14.7 15.3
Professional and technical 14.8 20.3 21.3
Sales 11.3 11.4 11.0
Administrative support 15.6 13.6 13.0
Services 14.4 16.6 17.4
Farming, forestry, and fishing 4.4 0.8 0.8
Factory/machine workers 29.1 22.6 21.1
Ratio of long-term
unemployed share to
labor force share
1983 2005-07 2009
Gender Male 1.21 1.06 1.12
Female 0.73 0.93 0.87
Age 16-24 1.12 1.49 1.40
25-54 1.01 0.92 0.95
55-64 0.88 0.95 0.91
65 and over 0.38 0.84 0.85
Marital Not married 1.30 1.50 1.42
status Married 0.81 0.61 0.67
Race White 0.85 0.77 0.82
Black 2.34 2.68 2.10
Hispanic 0.99 1.30 1.02
Other 1.14 1.06 1.29
Education Less than high school 1.12 1.35 1.19
High school graduate 1.22 1.15 1.23
Some college 0.79 0.92 1.01
College graduate 0.48 0.66 0.62
Industry Agriculture, fishing, forestry,
and mining 0.99 0.66 0.75
Utilities and sanitation 0.62 0.55 0.58
Construction 1.70 1.25 1.89
Manufacturing 1.81 1.26 1.53
Wholesale trade 0.78 0.88 0.90
Retail trade 0.82 1.18 1.07
Transportation and warehousing 1.13 0.90 0.94
Finance, insurance, and real
estate and leasing/rental 0.44 0.67 0.87
Professional/business services
and information 0.69 1.29 1.22
Health, education, and social
services 0.49 0.62 0.50
Other services 0.86 1.26 1.07
Government 0.63 0.62 0.35
Occupation Executive and managerial 0.47 0.55 0.66
Professional and technical 0.35 0.56 0.49
Sales 0.56 1.03 1.04
Administrative support 0.68 1.04 1.05
Services 1.02 1.29 1.03
Farming, forestry, and fishing 0.60 1.57 1.21
Factory/machine workers 1.89 1.40 1.66
Notes: All values are in percent. Some columns may not total because
of rounding.
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from the U.S. Bureau of
Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey, basic monthly files.
TABLE 2
Decomposition of the secular change in the average duration
of unemployment, 1980s to 2000s
1985-86 1983:011-012
to to
2005-06 2009:03-014
Total change to explain 1.3 6.2
Due to changes in composition
Age 0.7 1.6
Gender -0.1 0.0
Race 0.0 0.1
Education -0.1 -0.5
Industry 0.0 0.0
Total 0.5 1.2
Due to changes in coefficients
Age 0.0 -0.3
Gender 1.6 2.1
Race -1.0 0.0
Education -0.3 -0.3
Industry 1.3 0.1
Total 1.6 1.6
Interactions between changes
in composition and coefficients -0.8 3.3
Notes: All values are in weeks. See note 12 for further details. The
second column does not total because of rounding.
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from the U.S. Bureau of
Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey, basic monthly files.