Homebuilders, affiliated financing arms, and the mortgage crisis.
Agarwal, Sumit ; Amromin, Gene ; Gartenberg, Claudine 等
Introduction and summary
Nearly a third of all families purchasing new homes in 2006
obtained a mortgage from a financing company owned by or affiliated with
a large homebuilder (see figure 1). (1) Eighty percent of these loans
were made by financing companies associated with one of the ten largest
homebuilders in the country. (2) In addition to accounting for a large
share of new home sales and financing, homebuilders were particularly
active in areas of the country where the subprime crisis was most acute
(Arizona, California, Florida, and Nevada). As well as being important
simply because of the number of loans that they underwrite, homebuilder
financing arms are interesting because their incentives differ from
those of unaffiliated lenders. (3) Press accounts of homebuilder lending
practices have focused on their incentive to sell homes and their
purported willingness to extend unconventional mortgage products to
borrowers with less-than-stellar credit histories. (4) These factors
have led to accusations that homebuilders contributed to the formation
of the housing bubble and the ensuing foreclosure crisis. However,
despite playing a potentially important role in explaining house price
trends and mortgage defaults, homebuilder mortgage lending has received
little research attention to date. (5)
At first glance, the allegations of the nefarious role played by
the homebuilders in the crisis are consistent with academic research on
the behavior of lenders affiliated with a company that produced the good
that is being financed. From an intuitive viewpoint, homebuilder
financing arms may behave differently because their corporate parent
profits from both the sale of the house and its financing and continues
to lose money the longer the home stays in inventory. Consequently, such
lenders have a strong motivation to find financing terms that will lead
to a sale. This incentive may in turn lead to less screening of
borrowers and to mortgage terms that get the deal done but may not be
sustainable for the borrower. As the pace of home purchases slowed in
2006-07 and homebuilders were faced with growing inventories of unsold
homes, these incentives may have become even stronger.
This intuition has been evaluated empirically in other
(non-housing) markets by a number of studies that looked at credit
decisions and subsequent performance of loans made by the affiliated
lenders. In particular, studies that compare bank lending with that of
captive finance companies (Carey, Post, and Sharpe, 1998) and of auto
lending (Barron, Chong, and Staten, 2008) suggest that affiliated
finance companies have a greater incentive to focus on moving inventory
into the "sold" column. Both of these papers find evidence
that finance companies serve observably riskier borrowers and, in the
case of auto loans, that loans by affiliated lenders experience higher
default rates. A related literature focuses on the more general case in
which some lenders possess superior information about the borrower,
which is arguably true in the case of affiliated lenders. For instance,
Degryse and Ongena (2005) and Agarwal and Hauswald (2010) evaluate the
effects of proximity between lenders and borrowers on credit allocation
decisions, with the premise that shorter distances proxy for better
information. These papers find that more-distant borrowers pay higher
interest rates, which is consistent with the idea of asymmetric
information between borrowers and lenders. In this article, we use
loan-level data from 2001 to 2008 to investigate the characteristics and
default outcomes of home purchase mortgages underwritten by
homebuilders, compared with those of mortgages issued by unaffiliated
financial institutions. Our findings indicate that homebuilder financing
affiliates do make loans to observably riskier borrowers, as one might
expect from the literature, and that a greater share of homebuilder
loans have risky characteristics (for example, little documentation).
Despite these limitations, loans made by homebuilders have lower 12- and
24-month delinquency rates over our full sample period than loans made
by unaffiliated lenders, even when loan and borrower characteristics are
held constant. While homebuilder loans outperform similar loans made by
other lenders throughout the period that we examine, their relative
default performance in the near term (12-month) is stronger even among
loans originated during the boom-and-bust period that includes 2005
through 2008. Even over a longer 24-month horizon, we find no evidence
that homebuilder loans had higher default rates. These findings are
surprising, given that industry lending standards were particularly lax
in 2005 and 2006 and that homebuilders were burdened by large unsold
home inventories in 2007 and 2008.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Our findings thus run counter to the existing work on affiliated
lending in auto lending and captive finance companies. They also pose a
challenge to explanations of the housing bubble and the foreclosure
crisis that assign a central role to homebuilders and their lending
affiliates. Indeed, since builder-affiliated lenders were able to lend
to riskier borrowers and still deliver superior default performance,
perhaps some aspects of their lending practices should be emulated as
policymakers aim to mitigate defaults while maintaining access to credit
for a wide cross section of home buyers.
Although our study lacks the necessary data to determine specific
reasons behind homebuilder ability to achieve lower default rates, we
offer some potential explanations, most of which rely on the special
nature of housing markets. They include: 1) a superior ability of
homebuilder-affiliated lenders to procure information about borrowers
and the quality of housing collateral; 2) stronger incentives within
affiliated lenders for risk management in loan underwriting that may
stem both from their reliance on capital market funding and the
multistage nature of homebuilding projects; 3) the auxiliary provision
of financial education and coaching to borrowers; and 4) borrower
self-selection associated with a sometimes lengthy period between down
payment and taking possession of a finished home.
The next section of the article provides a description of the data.
This is followed by a univariate comparison of the borrower and loan
characteristics, as well as the delinquency experience of homebuilder
versus non-homebuilder loans over the 2001-08 period. Then we present
the associated multivariate analysis, which incorporates macroeconomic
factors as well as micro-data on borrower and loan characteristics. We
examine the potential role of changes in the underwriting process and
homebuilder incentives during two distinct periods: 2001-04 (the initial
buildup in housing prices) and 2005-08 (the period when housing prices
peaked and then declined sharply). Next, we focus on the relative
performance of homebuilder loans within specific mortgage contract
categories. Finally, we discuss the results and steps for future work.
Data
We use two main sources of data for our study: loan-level data
furnished by LPS Applied Analytics (LPS) and the public version of the
database of home loan applications and originations collected under the
Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA). LPS aggregates data from
mortgage-servicing companies that participate in the HOPE NOW Alliance.
(6) The most recent LPS data cover about 30 million mortgages throughout
the United States. Our sample covers mortgages originated between 2001
and 2008, which allows us to analyze the loans made during the housing
bubble buildup years 2001-04, as well as the 2005-08 period, during
which housing prices peaked and then collapsed. The data include prime
and subprime mortgages, as well as loans that are securitized or held on
bank balance sheets. In addition to monthly data on loan performance,
LPS contains information on key borrower and loan characteristics at
origination. Based on a comparison of the LPS and HMDA data, we estimate
that the LPS data cover about 60 percent of the prime market each year
from 2004 through 2007. Coverage of the subprime market is somewhat
smaller, but increases over time, going from just under 30 percent in
2004 to just under 50 percent in 2007. In addition to monthly data on
loan performance status, LPS contains information on key borrower and
loan characteristics at origination. This includes the borrower's
FICO credit score, the loan amount and interest rate, whether the loan
is a fixed or a variable-rate mortgage, the ratio of loan amount to home
value (LTV), and whether the loan was intended for home purchase or
refinancing. Unfortunately, we do not observe whether borrowers took on
additional mortgages in the form of piggyback loans that accompanied the
first mortgage, or in the form of second-lien lines of credit or
closed-end loans originated at some later point. The outcome variable
that we focus on is whether the loan becomes 90 days or more past due in
the 12 months following origination. We focus on loan performance during
the first 12 and 24 months since mortgage origination rather than a
longer period, so that loans made in 2008 can be analyzed in the same
way as earlier loans, as our data are complete through the end of 2010.
Because homebuilders do not participate in refinancing markets, we
limit our sample to mortgages used for home purchase. We further exclude
purchases of non-single-family residences, as well as FHA (Federal
Housing Administration) and VA (U.S. Department of Veterans Affairs)
mortgages. (7) The resulting sample consists of about 86,000 mortgages
originated by homebuilder-affiliated lenders and 5.2 million mortgages
originated by unaffiliated financial institutions between 2001 and 2008.
Homebuilder loans, borrowers, and their mortgage performance
The first two columns of table 1 compare the geographic
distribution of homebuilder lending activity and the attributes of
homebuilder borrowers with those of other lenders over the entire sample
period. It further contrasts loan characteristics and performance of
homebuilder and non-homebuilder loans.
Homebuilder lending appears to have been more concentrated in areas
that exhibited high house price growth during the formative years of the
bubble and that experienced a collapse in prices in 2006-08. In
particular, the four states most commonly associated with the
bubble--Arizona, California, Florida, and Nevada--account for about 32
percent of homebuilder lending, but only 21 percent of loans for home
purchase by other lender types. Figure 2, which presents a county-level
distribution of the mortgage market share attributed to the affiliated
homebuilder lenders, paints a similar picture.
Over the entire sample, the average FICO score of homebuilder
borrowers was lower than that of borrowers with loans from non-builders.
This difference is due to the higher share of subprime and
near-sub-prime households among those financed by the homebuilders.
Among homebuilder borrowers, 21 percent had FICO scores below 660,
compared with 15 percent for those who borrowed from other lenders.
Loans originated by homebuilders were more likely to contain prepayment
penalties.
Relative to other borrowers, those obtaining credit from a builder
had similar annual incomes but purchased a somewhat more expensive
house. The resulting difference in median ratios of house value to
household income (VTI) is both economically and statistically
significant--for a given level of income, homebuilder borrowers
purchased houses valued at about 2.5 percent more than non-homebuilder
borrowers.
There is very little difference in average mortgage values or
first-lien loan-to-value (LTV) ratios of homebuilder and non-homebuilder
loans. Taken together with values for income and house values, this
suggests that homebuilder borrowers took on larger mortgages with lower
income bases. The weaker financial footing of homebuilder borrowers is
also underscored by their greater reliance on mortgages underwritten on
the basis of less-than-full documentation. At least 38 percent of
homebuilder loans were based on the borrowers' stated, as opposed
to verified, income. Earlier work has shown that stated income loans, on
average, overstated household earnings (Jiang, Nelson, and Vytlacil,
forthcoming). In addition, homebuilder mortgages were more likely to
have adjustable rates or be non-amortizing, thereby reducing the initial
monthly mortgage service flows relative to more traditional fixed-rate
loans.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
At first glance, this summary is consistent with the common
perception that homebuilders offered loans in bubble areas, were willing
to lend to less creditworthy buyers who were buying more expensive homes
relative to their (stated) incomes, and used loan contracts with riskier
features, such as prepayment penalties, adjustable interest rates, and
non-amortizing schedules.
However, as evidenced by the comparison of columns 1 and 2 in table
1, homebuilder lending resulted in lower defaults than other types of
lending. During the first 12 months following loan origination,
borrowers with loans from homebuilders defaulted at a 1.2 percent rate,
compared with a 1.6 percent rate among borrowers with non-homebuilder
loans. (8) This difference in loan performance was particularly
pronounced among the subset of borrowers with the lowest credit scores
(FICO scores below 660), for which homebuilder loans display markedly
lower default rates. Among such borrowers, the average 12-month default
rate on homebuilder loans originated during 2001-08 is 3.3 percent; the
corresponding figure for non-homebuilder loans is 6.4 percent. This
difference persists over a 24-month horizon when default rates for
homebuilder loans rise to 8.1 percent and for non-homebuilder loans to
15.0 percent. Among more-creditworthy borrowers (FICO scores above 660),
homebuilder loans outperform the non-homebuilder loans over the 12-month
horizon, but exhibit somewhat higher default rates over the 24-month
horizon.
Figure 3 provides some insight into temporal properties of defaults
on loans originated by the two types of lenders. For a given vintage of
loans (those originated in calendar year 2005), figure 3 plots the
monthly series of the fraction of loans that become 90 days or more past
due. The early relative performance of loans originated by homebuilder
lenders is particularly striking, as there are very few defaults in the
first nine months following origination. Although the monthly default
rates of the two lender types converge somewhat over time, the less
creditworthy borrowers served by the homebuilders fare better throughout
most of the 24-month horizon.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Figure 4 offers a spatial perspective on defaults during the first
12 months for loans originated in 2005. A quick visual inspection
suggests that the areas of the country that experienced the highest
mortgage default rates in 2006 were not the same ones that had the
largest fractions of home purchases financed by homebuilder lending
affiliates. (9)
Note that the above analysis focuses on the unconditional default
rate and does not take into account the geographic concentration of
homebuilder loans in the bubble states or the greater share of loan
features (for example, adjustable rates or less-than-full
documentation), all of which would tend to make homebuilder default
rates higher. Put differently, homebuilders make riskier loans, on
average, and these loans have lower defaults than safer loans made by
other lenders.
Controlling for characteristics of loans, borrowers, and geography
The univariate comparisons in the preceding section do not take
into account the differences in homebuilder and non-homebuilder loans
summarized in table 1 or differences in trends in the relative activity
of homebuilders versus other lenders over time. To account for these
differences, we estimate a logit model of mortgage default that
conditions on location-specific macroeconomic factors, as well as the
borrower and loan characteristics described in table 1. (10) In addition
to a set of state dummies and origination year fixed effects, these
specifications also include the change in the MSA (metropolitan
statistical area) level home price index, the change in the average
unemployment rate, and the change in the market interest rate. All of
these changes are computed between the quarter of mortgage origination
and the earliest of the mortgage default rate or the end of the
evaluation horizon (either 12 or 24 months since origination). The model
is estimated on loan-level data, and standard errors are clustered at
the state level. The difference in conditional default rates between
homebuilder- and non-homebuilder-originated loans is captured by an
indicator variable for homebuilder mortgages.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The set of regression results that incorporates these controls is
shown in table 2, where the displayed coefficients represent marginal
effects measured in percentage points. The first column contains the
analysis of mortgage performance over the first 12 months since
origination, while the second column shows the results for the 24-month
horizon. Both regressions cover the entire sample period from 2001
through the end of 2008. We find that over both horizons, the estimated
coefficient on builder-affiliated loans is negative, suggesting lower
default rates conditional on a large set of observable factors. These
estimates are significant both statistically and economically. The 0.74
percentage point difference in conditional 12-month default rates is
very precisely estimated, and it represents a substantial improvement
over the baseline default rate of 1.6 percent. Similarly, the 1.24
percentage point difference in column 2 represents a sizable improvement
over the baseline 24-month default rate of 4.5 percent.
Among the macroeconomic control variables, the concurrent change in
the metropolitan-area-level home prices has a very strong effect on
defaults, with homes in areas with stronger past price growth (or
smaller declines) defaulting much less frequently. Turning to the set of
borrower and loan characteristics, we find a strong negative association
between FICO score at mortgage origination and subsequent loan
performance. We also find that higher default rates are associated with
greater leverage on the first-lien loan at origination (loan-to-value
ratios), lower borrower income, and higher loan amounts. We further
document that non-amortizing mortgages, mortgages that combined short
periods of fixed interest rates with adjustable rates thereafter (the
so-called 2/28 and 3/27 hybrid adjustable-rate mortgages [ARMs]), and
loans underwritten on the basis of incomplete documentation all
defaulted at higher rates. The presence of these controls suggests that
the estimated superior default performance of homebuilder loans derives
from other factors. Before delving into a discussion of potential
explanations, we test whether these results are present at different
phases of the housing cycle.
Change in homebuilder lending practices and mortgage performance
We next split the sample into two subperiods--the buildup to the
housing bubble, covering the years 2001-04, and the peak years, followed
by the housing price collapse (2005-08). If homebuilders were
predisposed to aggressive lending, such tendencies would arguably be
most pronounced in the latter period. In 2005-06, rapidly appreciating
home prices may have led homebuilders to ramp up production and sales.
In 2007-08, homebuilders found themselves with large excess inventories
of unsold homes and may have been tempted to sell them to even
marginally creditworthy borrowers.
Columns 3-6 of table 1 (p. 41) summarize dramatic changes in
borrower and loan characteristics over these two periods for
homebuilder-affiliated and other lenders. Of particular note is the
finding that the share of homebuilder borrowers with low FICO scores
(below 620) falls from 11 percent in 2001-04 to just 4 percent in
2005-08. A similar reduction (from 25 percent to 13 percent) is observed
for borrowers with FICO scores below 660. Although this result can be
partially explained by the drying up of securitization activity
beginning in the second half of 2007, we note the absence of a decline
in the share of low-FICO-score borrowers among other types of lenders.
Indeed, during the 2005-08 period, the share of affiliated lender loans
going to low FICO borrowers was lower than the corresponding share for
non-affiliated lenders.
However, homebuilders appeared to ratchet up the risk profile of
their lending activities along a number of other dimensions during
2005-08. Their lending became even more concentrated in the bubble
states; they appeared to be willing to finance houses at greater
multiples to income, and they relied increasingly on exotic mortgage
products, such as hybrid ARMs and non-amortizing mortgages. At the same
time, they also shifted toward underwriting practices that allowed for
incomplete income and asset documentation. All of these trends are
either absent or less pronounced among other lenders.
In terms of unconditional 24-month default rates, homebuilder loans
performed strictly better in the first half of the sample for both prime
and subprime borrowers, as shown in columns 3 and 5 of table 1 (p. 41).
However, in the later part of the sample, homebuilder loans have higher
unconditional default rates. Although homebuilders cut back on their
subprime exposure, their remaining subprime borrowers have higher
default rates than subprime households borrowing from non-homebuilder
lenders (27.4 percent versus 23.1 percent). Among prime borrowers,
homebuilder loans showed even greater deterioration in relative default
rates (6.6 percent versus 4.2 percent). The unconditional default rate
during the late bubble period thus appears consistent with reckless
homebuilder lending practices. Still, attributing higher defaults to
underwriting practices requires, at a minimum, that we remove the
potential influences of other default determinants.
To do that, we repeat the multivariate analysis described in the
previous section for each of the two subperiods. The results, presented
in table 3, are revealing. Even after conditioning on geographic and
macroeconomic factors, as well as mortgage and borrower characteristics,
homebuilder-affiliated mortgages originated during the early period
(2001-04) exhibit lower default rates. This finding is true both for the
short-horizon performance (column 1) and the longer-horizon performance
(column 2). This result also suggests that the outperformance of
homebuilder loans in the early period cannot be fully explained by the
fact that homebuilders benefited from being particularly active in
bubble states, where home prices increased the most.
If active participation in the boom areas was the only explanation
for lower default rates of homebuilder loans during the formative years
of the bubble, we would expect such loans to default more when home
prices declined during the later period, as suggested by the comparison
of unconditional default rates discussed above. In stark contrast,
however, we find that conditional default rates on homebuilder loans are
lower in the late bubble period (2005-08) over the short 12-month
horizon (column 3). Over the 24-month horizon, the conditional default
rates on homebuilder loans are statistically indistinguishable from
those on non-homebuilder loans.
Put differently, homebuilder loans originated during the peak
bubble years and in the dire aftermath of the housing collapse perform
as well or better than their non-homebuilder counterparts issued in
similar geographies to similar borrowers. This result is robust to
sample choice, the definition of default, the set of covariates, and the
type of econometric model. (11)
Loan performance by contract type
The results in table 3 highlight an intriguing contrast between the
strength of relative outperformance of homebuilder loans originated in
2005-08 over the 12- and 24-month horizons. As noted earlier, during
this period, homebuilders increasingly utilized mortgage contracts that
did not require amortization in the early years of the loan. In our
sample, such contracts accounted for 25 percent of homebuilder loans
originated during 2005-08.12 The distinguishing characteristic of
non-amortizing contracts is that they allow the borrower to make a lower
payment initially compared with, say, a conventional fixed-rate
amortizing mortgage. The ability to lower early payments is particularly
pronounced in the case of the so-called negative amortization (or option
ARM) contracts that allow payments to be less than the interest charges.
Such lower payments, however, are only temporary, as all non-amortizing
contracts have to begin paying down principal at some point.
The question that arises, therefore, is whether homebuilder loans
originated during the bubble formation period did better in the short
term because they were structured to make them easier to afford in the
early years. In other words, can our results be ascribed to
homebuilder-affiliated lenders' practice of designing loans that
kicked potential problems down the road?
To get some insight into this possibility, we repeat the analysis
of the previous section on subsamples defined by specific contract
types. Although we used contract-type indicator variables in our
preceding analysis, such controls are imperfect. Consequently, we use
more flexible specifications that look separately at all non-amortizing
contracts (interest-only or negative amortization) originated by
homebuilder-affiliated and other lenders. We carry out a similar
analysis on a subsample of conventional fixed-rate amortizing mortgages.
The results are shown in table 4. Since the focus is on
homebuilder-affiliated lenders, we do not show the coefficients on all
of the other controls, although they are included in all of the
regressions. Indeed, we find a telling contrast between the 12- and
24-month default rates among non-amortizing mortgages (table 4, panel
A). Whereas homebuilder loans experienced lower 12-month default rates
on mortgages originated during the 2005-08 period (column 3), their
relative default rates became higher over the longer 24-month horizon
(column 6). Although the latter result is only marginally statistically
significant, it is consistent with the possibility that better
performance of homebuilder loans is more illusory than real.
Why could the homebuilders have been interested in originating
loans that make it easier to avoid default in their early years? Part of
the answer may lie in homebuilders' reliance on securitization
markets to fund their mortgages (Gartenberg, 2010). Under standard
securitization agreements, an originator agrees to buy back from an
investor any loan that defaults shortly (typically, within three or four
months) after origination. Since homebuilder lenders had relatively
little capital to accommodate such repurchase requests, they may have
chosen to utilize non-amortizing mortgages as the means to manage this
risk.
However, this does not imply that homebuilder default performance
documented earlier in the article was driven exclusively (or even
primarily) by such window-dressing practices. Panel B of table 4 shows
that for fixed-rate amortizing mortgage contracts, which accounted for
the lion's share of lending, homebuilder loans performed much
better over the 12-month horizon for the entire period and each of the
subsamples (columns 1-3). Over the 24-month horizon, their performance
was better for the 2001-04 loan originations and effectively the same as
that for non-homebuilder loans for the 2005-08 originations. These
results are in line with our earlier analysis, while removing any
potential contamination from improper controls for different mortgage
contract composition.
Discussion of results and directions for future work
We find that relative to other lenders, homebuilders financed
mortgages in riskier geographies and served borrowers with observably
riskier characteristics during the 2001 to 2008 period. However, we also
show that these mortgages defaulted at significantly lower rates over
the total sample period, once we control for the confounding influences
of time, location, and risk characteristics. The finding of similar or
better default rates on homebuilder loans is particularly interesting
for the 2005-08 origination period, when lending standards in mortgage
markets were considered most lax and when the inventory of unsold houses
was rising rapidly. While our study focuses on the performance of
homebuilder loans and not on their building activity, the fact that
these loans defaulted less than comparable loans by other lenders is
inconsistent with explanations of the subprime mortgage crisis that
envision a large role for homebuilders.
In addition, our findings cannot be easily reconciled with the
existing literature on lending by affiliated firms. Like Carey, Post,
and Sharpe (1998) and Barron, Chong, and Staten (2008), we find that
homebuilder financing affiliates lend to riskier borrowers. However,
unlike Barron, Chong, and Staten's (2008) study of auto loans, we
find that homebuilder affiliate loans have lower rather than higher
default rates.
What is it about homebuilder financing affiliates that might
account for this difference? As is the case for other captive lenders,
the corporate parent profits from both the loan and the sale of the
primary good. In addition, the incentives for riskier underwriting grow
stronger when inventory levels are high, as signaling and agency issues
offset the benefits of knowledge and coordination gained with
integrating lending and sales (Pierce, 2012).
Research on bank lending provides one possible explanation. For
instance, Agarwal and Hauswald (2010) show that banks with greater
access to "soft" information are more willing to take on
problematic borrowers. Homebuilders can arguably produce
"soft" information more easily than other lenders as they
interact with borrowers frequently during the home buying process. These
interactions have the potential to reveal borrower characteristics--such
as punctuality, willingness to provide information, or ability to meet
pre-construction financial obligations--that are not captured by broadly
available measures of risk such as FICO scores and income
characteristics. Having such information increases the ability of
homebuilder lenders to avoid fraudulent transactions and make sound
credit allocation decisions.
Stroebel (2013) offers a novel information-based channel to explain
the superior performance of homebuilder-affiliated lenders. His paper
emphasizes the informational advantages of affiliated lenders that
manifest themselves not just through better ability to assess borrower
creditworthiness, but also through better knowledge of the quality of
housing construction. Better-built homes maintain higher collateral
values and therefore represent a safer investment, holding borrower
characteristics constant. Stroebel (2013) shows that houses financed by
homebuilders indeed exhibited higher ex post appreciation rates and were
less likely to experience major depreciation events, such as
foundational cracks and leaky roofs. Moreover, this outperformance was
greater among houses built on unstable (expansive) soil, where the
quality of construction mattered most and where that quality could be
best observed by the homebuilder.
Other aspects of the home buying process and the organization of
homebuilders may help to explain the superior performance of homebuilder
loans. Gartenberg (2010) emphasizes the role of organizational form and
sources of financing in disciplining homebuilders. She shows that
homebuilders employed lower-powered incentives than financial lenders,
in order to balance competing internal goals (Holmstrom and Milgrom,
1991). Homebuilders also allocated limited capital to their lending
units, forcing them to have little capacity to take back securitized
loans, which further strengthened their incentives for careful
underwriting (Gartenberg, 2010). As our results suggest, these
incentives may also have contributed to greater utilization of
non-amortizing mortgage contracts by homebuilder lenders, which have a
particularly strong impact on short-term loan performance.
Two other aspects of buying new homes from a large corporate
homebuilder merit discussion. The process of selecting a new home and
its many features is often protracted and involves multiple interactions
between the sales agent, prospective buyer, and eventually the loan
underwriter. Although the credit decision is done separately from the
sales process, homebuilder sales agents often engage in some form of
financial education in their interactions with prospective buyers. They
discuss topics such as typical maintenance expenses (for example, those
covered or not covered by the homeowners association), relative
cost-benefit trade-offs of different building features, and ability to
generate rental income, among others. All of these discussions arguably
allow prospective borrowers to form more-accurate forecasts of expenses
associated with homeownership. Other research has found that financial
education programs geared toward budgeting for homeownership, both from
the standpoint of amassing a down payment and contingency funds for home
maintenance, have a sizable positive effect on subsequent mortgage
performance (Agarwal et al., 2010). Finally, the often considerable time
lag between signing the original sales contract and taking final
possession of a completed house implies a number of differences between
buyers who pre-commit to purchasing a new home and the general home
buyer population. New home buyers (the only kind that homebuilder
lenders serve) are willing to wait longer to get into their new homes.
They are also less likely to be liquidity-constrained, since they are
able to tie up sizable purchase contract deposits for long periods.
Again, these factors are likely to be positively associated with better
mortgage performance.
These explanations have different implications for what policy
should or can do. Should policy goals be centered on changing incentives
for lenders? Would greater investment in financial education improve
credit decisions and outcomes? Or, is it perhaps true that buyers of new
homes simply represent a different population of borrowers and their
experience cannot be translated to other types of borrowers? Similarly,
part of the superior performance of homebuilder loans originated during
the boom-and-bust years appears to have come from the utilization of
contract types that made early defaults less likely. In those years,
capital markets did not generally condition early pay defaults on
contract type; this may no longer be the case in the future given the
experience of the recent mortgage crisis. Understanding how homebuilders
were able to lend to riskier borrowers, use riskier loan terms, be very
active in risky locations, and still underwrite mortgages with lower
default rates than other lenders is an important research goal and may
provide useful insights for housing policy.
REFERENCES
Agarwal, Sumit, Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala
Chomsisengphet, and Douglas D. Evanoff,
2010, "Learning to cope: Voluntary financial education and
loan performance during a housing crisis," American Economic
Review, Vol. 100, No. 2, May, pp. 495-500.
Agarwal, Sumit, and Robert Hauswald, 2010, "Distance and
private information in lending," Review of Financial Studies, Vol.
23, No. 7, July, pp. 2757-2788.
Barron, John M., Byung-Uk Chong, and Michael E. Staten, 2008,
"Emergence of captive finance companies and risk segmentation in
loan markets: Theory and evidence," Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, Vol. 40, No. 1, February, pp. 173-192.
Carey, Mark, Mitch Post, and Steven A. Sharpe, 1998, "Does
corporate lending by banks and finance companies differ? Evidence on
specialization in private debt contracting," Journal of Finance,
Vol. 53, No. 3, June, pp. 845-878.
Degryse, Hans, and Steven Ongena, 2005, "Distance, lending
relationships, and competition," Journal of Finance, Vol. 60, No.
1, February, pp. 231-266.
Der Hovanesian, Mara, 2007, "Bonfire of the builders,"
BusinessWeek, August 13.
Gartenberg, Claudine, 2010, "Tempted by scope? Homebuilder
mortgage affiliates, lending quality and the housing crisis,"
Harvard Business School, unpublished paper.
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Paul Milgrom, 1991, "Multitask
principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job
design," Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, Vol. 7,
Special Issue, January, pp. 24-52.
Jiang, Wei, Ashlyn Aiko Nelson, and Edward Vytlacil, 2013,
"Liar's loan? Effects of origination channel and information
falsification on mortgage delinquency," Review of Financial
Studies, forthcoming.
Pierce, Lamar, 2012, "Organizational structure and the limits
of knowledge sharing: Incentive conflict and agency in car
leasing," Management Science, Vol. 58, No. 6, June, pp. 1106-1121.
Stroebel, Johannes, 2013, "The impact of asymmetric
information about collateral values in mortgage lending," New York
University, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, working paper.
NOTES
(1) See figure 1 (p. 39) for a time series of new and existing home
purchases and the fraction of new home purchases financed by
homebuilders. During the housing boom years (2004-06), there was a
gradual increase in the share of homebuilder-financed homes.
(2) Nine of the ten largest homebuilders have a financing
affiliate. Among the ten largest homebuilders, the share of loans
financed by an affiliate ranges from 57 percent for KB/Countrywide to 91
percent for Pulte.
(3) Like many other lenders, builder-affiliated lenders securitize
most of their loans, so incentives arising from the ability to
securitize are likely to be similar for them as for unaffiliated lenders
that also securitize.
(4) See, for example, www.businessweek.com/stories/2007-08-12/
bonfire-of-the-builders.
(5) Two important exceptions are Gartenberg (2010) and Stroebel
(2013), which are discussed in more detail later in this article.
(6) See www.hopenow.com for additional details on activities of the
Alliance.
(7) Our results are fully robust to including FHA and VA mortgages
in the sample.
(8) We define a loan as being in default if it is 90 days or more
past due, in foreclosure, or is real-estate owned in the first 12 (or
24) months after the first mortgage payment date.
(9) A county-level correlation between the share of
homebuilder-originated loans in 2005 (depicted in figure 2, p. 42) and
12-month default rates on loans originated in 2005 (depicted in figure
4, p. 44) is -0.02.
(10) We also estimate ordinary least squares (OLS) and Cox
proportional hazard models, which produce qualitatively similar results.
(11) Gartenberg (2010) obtains similar results in a sample of
new-construction homes in the top 100 zip codes by building activity,
using a Cox proportional hazard model of defaults. For the logit, OLS,
and hazard models based on the data in this article, we evaluated both
the 12- and 24-month default rates. These results are available on
request.
(12) The majority (88 percent) of non-amortizing loans originated
by homebuilder-affiliated lenders during this period were interest-only
loans. The rest were negative amortization loans that allow mortgage
balances to grow over time.
Sumit Agarwal is a professor of economics, finance, and real estate
at the National University of Singapore. Gene Amromin is a senior
financial economist and economic advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago. Claudine Gartenberg is an assistant professor of management at
New York University. Anna Paulson is a vice president and the director
of financial research at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Sriram
Villupuram is an assistant professor of finance and real estate at
Colorado State University. Caitlin Kearns, Rob McMenamin, and Edward
Zhong provided outstanding research assistance. The authors thank
seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
TABLE 1
Homebuilder loans, borrowers, and mortgage performance
The sample includes purchase, conventional, first-lien mortgages for
single-family homes.
Builder Other
affiliates lenders
Year of origination 2001-08 2001-08
Number of loans 85,767 5,234,080
Bubble state loans (%) 0.32 0.21
Median FICO score 720 732
FICO below 620 (%) 0.08 0.05
FICO below 660 (%) 0.21 0.15
Median household income ($) 76,000 78,000
Median home value ($) 233,000 225,000
Median value-to-income ratio 3.08 3.01
Median mortgage amount ($) 179,350 173,375
Median loan-to-value (LTV) ratio 79.59 79.79
Fixed-rate mortgages (%) 0.71 0.73
Adjustable-rate mortgages (%) 0.14 0.08
Hybrid adjustable-rate mortgages (%) 0.03 0.05
Non-amortizing mortgages (%) 0.12 0.15
Prepayment penalties (%) 0.13 0.09
Less-than-full documentation (%) 0.38 0.29
12-month securitization rate 96.0 90.2
12-month default rate 1.2 1.6
24-month default rate 3.9 4.4
12-month default rate (FICO < 660) 3.3 6.4
24-month default rate (FICO < 660) 8.1 15.0
12-month default rate (FICO > 660) 0.6 0.8
24-month default rate (FICO > 660) 2.8 2.5
Builder
affiliates
Year of origination 2001-04 2005-08
Number of loans 54,487 31,280
Bubble state loans (%) 0.29 0.35
Median FICO score 714 730
FICO below 620 (%) 0.11 0.04
FICO below 660 (%) 0.25 0.13
Median household income ($) 71,000 88,000
Median home value ($) 200,000 295,495
Median value-to-income ratio 2.92 3.43
Median mortgage amount ($) 157,736 224,800
Median loan-to-value (LTV) ratio 79.78 79.20
Fixed-rate mortgages (%) 0.74 0.65
Adjustable-rate mortgages (%) 0.21 0.03
Hybrid adjustable-rate mortgages (%) 0.01 0.07
Non-amortizing mortgages (%) 0.04 0.25
Prepayment penalties (%) 0.17 0.07
Less-than-full documentation (%) 0.32 0.40
12-month securitization rate 95.7 96.3
12-month default rate 0.5 2.4
24-month default rate 1.0 9.0
12-month default rate (FICO < 660) 1.4 10.3
24-month default rate (FICO < 660) 2.7 27.4
12-month default rate (FICO > 660) 0.2 1.2
24-month default rate (FICO > 660) 0.4 6.6
Other
lenders
Year of origination 2001-04 2005-08
Number of loans 2,559,824 2,674,256
Bubble state loans (%) 0.23 0.20
Median FICO score 731 732
FICO below 620 (%) 0.05 0.06
FICO below 660 (%) 0.15 0.16
Median household income ($) 74,000 83,000
Median home value ($) 204,000 248,000
Median value-to-income ratio 2.92 3.11
Median mortgage amount ($) 158,650 189,900
Median loan-to-value (LTV) ratio 79.89 79.70
Fixed-rate mortgages (%) 0.74 0.71
Adjustable-rate mortgages (%) 0.12 0.04
Hybrid adjustable-rate mortgages (%) 0.04 0.06
Non-amortizing mortgages (%) 0.10 0.19
Prepayment penalties (%) 0.10 0.08
Less-than-full documentation (%) 0.28 0.29
12-month securitization rate 90.3 90.2
12-month default rate 0.5 2.7
24-month default rate 1.5 7.2
12-month default rate (FICO < 660) 2.3 10.0
24-month default rate (FICO < 660) 6.0 23.1
12-month default rate (FICO > 660) 0.2 1.3
24-month default rate (FICO > 660) 0.7 4.2
Source: LPS Applied Analytics.
TABLE 2
Multivariate analysis of loan performance
Default in the Default in the
first 12 months first 24 months
Year of origination 2001-08 2001-08
Builder-affiliate indicator -0.74 -1.24
(-10.0) ** (-2.4) *
Change in market interest rate 0.63 2.48
since origination (11.7) ** (15.2) **
MSA home price growth since -6.19 -12.43
origination (-4.2) ** (-7.5) **
Change in MSA unemployment rate -0.45 -0.89
since origination (-4.2) ** (-7.0) **
FICO score at origination -0.02 -0.04
(-36.9) ** (-45.1) **
Loan-to-value ratio at 0.04 0.11
origination (28.2) ** (19.3) **
Log income ($1,000s) -0.52 -1.06
(-4.8) ** (-5.5) **
Not primary occupancy 0.37 0.16
(1.6) (0.3)
Log loan amount 0.71 0.89
(5.6) ** (2.9) **
First observed interest rate 0.63 1.16
(24.4) ** (13.9) **
Non-amortizing mortgage 1.00 2.51
(16.0) ** (23.0) **
Amortizing adjustable-rate -0.17 -0.7
mortgage, non-hybrid (-1.8) (-2.8) **
Amortizing adjustable-rate 0.86 2.14
mortgage, hybrid (11.3) ** (8.8) **
Prepayment penalty -0.08 0.36
(-0.6) (1.1)
Less-than-full documentation 0.32 0.67
(12.4) ** (7.8) **
Observations 3,917,801 3,917,801
Pseudo R-squared 0.279 0.320
Failure rate (percentage points) 1.64 4.46
Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. Logit analysis, 1 = 90
days or more past due within 12 (24) months. The sample includes
purchase, conventional, first-lien mortgages for single-family homes.
All regressions include state and year of origination fixed effects.
The change in macro variables is from the quarter of origination to
the earliest of the following dates: first default, the last time the
loan is observed in the sample, or four (eight) quarters following
origination. The displayed coefficients represent marginal effects in
percentage points. Z-statistics based on robust standard errors
clustered at the state level are in parentheses; **, * indicate
significance at the 1 percent and 5 percent level, respectively.
Sources: LPS Applied Analytics and authors' calculations.
TABLE 3
Multivariate analysis of loan performance, different subperiods
Default in the
first 12 months
Year of origination 2001-04 2005-08
Builder-affiliate indicator -0.48 -0.71
(-5.6) ** (-3.8) **
Change in market interest 0.05 1.33
rate since origination (2.0) (9.5) **
MSA home price growth -9.07 -6.48
since origination (-9.7) ** (-2.3) *
Change in MSA unemployment 0.03 -0.8
rate since origination (0.6) (-4.4) **
FICO score at origination -0.01 -0.03
(-46.0) ** (-34.3) **
Loan-to-value ratio at 0.02 0.06
origination (17.6) ** (16.0) **
Log income ($1,000s) -0.29 -0.79
(-10.6) ** (-4.0) **
Not primary occupancy 0.04 0.54
(0.9) (1.1)
Log loan amount 0.20 1.24
(2.9) ** (5.1) **
First observed interest rate 0.13 1.13
(11.4) ** (22.8) **
Non-amortizing mortgage 0.33 1.65
(6.8) ** (17.9) **
Amortizing adjustable-rate -0.13 -0.03
mortgage, non-hybrid (-4.2) ** (-0.1)
Amortizing adjustable-rate 0.15 1.47
mortgage, hybrid (4.8) ** (8.2) **
Prepayment penalty -0.01 -0.11
(-0.2) (-0.5)
Less-than-full documentation 0.15 0.38
(5.3) ** (8.3) **
Observations 1,946,958 1,970,843
Pseudo R-squared 0.231 0.254
Failure rate 0.513 2.74
Default in the
first 24 months
Year of origination 2001-04 2005-08
Builder-affiliate indicator -1.34 0.40
(-6.0) ** (1.0)
Change in market interest -0.14 4.67
rate since origination (-1.4) (12.9) **
MSA home price growth -12.64 -12.47
since origination (-9.5) ** (-5.3) **
Change in MSA unemployment 0.15 -1.34
rate since origination (0.9) (-8.7) **
FICO score at origination -0.02 -0.07
(-44.9) ** (-48.1) **
Loan-to-value ratio at 0.04 0.18
origination (22.4) ** (11.6) **
Log income ($1,000s) -0.58 -1.79
(-10.6) ** (-5.0) **
Not primary occupancy -0.59 0.95
(-4.7) ** (1.0)
Log loan amount 0.15 1.78
(1.0) (2.7) **
First observed interest rate 0.25 1.96
(10.0) ** (8.7) **
Non-amortizing mortgage 0.76 3.91
(7.9) ** (24.4) **
Amortizing adjustable-rate -0.38 0.20
mortgage, non-hybrid (-6.3) ** (0.4)
Amortizing adjustable-rate 0.43 3.44
mortgage, hybrid (9.0) ** (5.9) **
Prepayment penalty 0.13 0.85
(1.4) (1.5)
Less-than-full documentation 0.13 1.01
(1.9) (7.8) **
Observations 1,946,958 1,970,843
Pseudo R-squared 0.247 0.299
Failure rate 1.43 7.45
Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. Logit analysis, 1 = 90
days or more past due within 12 months. The sample includes purchase,
conventional, first-lien mortgages for single-family homes. All
regressions include state and year of origination fixed effects. The
change in macro variables is from the quarter of origination to the
earliest of the following dates: first default, the last time the
loan is observed in the sample, or four quarters following
origination. The displayed coefficients represent marginal effects in
percentage points. Z-statistics based on robust standard errors
clustered at the state level are in parentheses; **, * indicate
significance at the 1 percent and 5 percent level, respectively.
Sources: LPS Applied Analytics and authors' calculations.
TABLE 4
Multivariate analysis of loan performance by contract type
Default in the first 12 months
Year of origination 2001-08 2001-04 2005-08
Panel A. Non-amortizing mortgages only
Builder-affiliate -1.48 -0.52 -1.86
indicator (-9.8) ** (-1.3) (-10.1) **
Macro, loan, and Yes Yes Yes
borrower controls
Observations 600,315 209,605 390,358
Pseudo R-squared 0.234 0.296 0.200
Failure rate 3.18 0.865 4.43
Panel B. Fixed-rate amortizing mortgages only
Builder-affiliate -0.5 -0.25 -0.29
indicator (-5.0) ** (-3.4) ** (-2.6) **
Macro, loan, and Yes Yes Yes
borrower controls
Observations 2,807,941 1,409,667 1,398,274
Pseudo R-squared 0.260 0.228 0.251
Failure rate 0.96 0.404 1.52
Default in the first 24 months
Year of origination 2001-08 2001-04 2005-08
Panel A. Non-amortizing mortgages only
Builder-affiliate 0.69 -1.81 1.52
indicator (1.0) (-2.6) ** (1.8)
Macro, loan, and Yes Yes Yes
borrower controls
Observations 600,315 209,656 390,358
Pseudo R-squared 0.282 0.288 0.245
Failure rate 8.92 2.33 12.5
Panel B. Fixed-rate amortizing mortgages only
Builder-affiliate -0.8 -0.51 0.27
indicator (-2.5) * (-2.9) ** (0.7)
Macro, loan, and Yes Yes Yes
borrower controls
Observations 2,807,941 1,409,667 1,398,274
Pseudo R-squared 0.290 0.233 0.287
Failure rate 2.88 1.19 4.59
Notes: Logit analysis, 1 = 90 days or more past due within 12 (24)
months. The sample includes non-amortizing purchase, conventional,
first-lien mortgages for single-family homes. All regressions include
state and year of origination fixed effects, as well as the full set
of covariates utilized in tables 2 and 3. The displayed coefficients
represent marginal effects in percentage points. Z-statistics based
on robust standard errors clustered at the state level are in
parentheses; **, * indicate significance at the 1 percent and 5
percent level, respectively.
Sources: LPS Applied Analytics and authors' calculations.