2+2 tier banded frameworks of interconnectedness: industry structure determinants.
Shin, SeungJae ; Tucci, Jack ; Weiss, Martin B.H. 等
ABSTRACT
The Internet industry is generally considered to be vertically
structured with the Internet Backbone Provider (IBP- long distance
service carrier) in the upstream and Internet Service Providers (ISP) in
the downstream. Although there are many ISPs and IBPs in each stream,
both markets are considered independent oligopolies in that there are a
few dominant providers for both ISPs and IBPs. The market leaders in
each market create their own hierarchical tier and it is generally
accepted that the Internet industry structure has evolved into a
four-tier hierarchical structure. To understand the Internet industry,
it is necessary to understand interconnection between ISPs and IBPs. The
key element as an industry structural determinant is peering
interconnection and the relationship created by that interconnectedness.
Peering interconnection occurs within the same tier and the transit
interconnection between the different tiers. This paper examines the
internet industry structure using market share and interconnection
strategies.
INTRODUCTION
The Internet industry is dynamic. It consists of millions of
computers and switching devices. The number of Internet Service
Providers (ISPs) increased rapidly from the mid 90' and the
structure of the industry continues to change. It is widely accepted
that today's Internet industry has vertical structure: over 40
Internet Backbone Providers (IBPs) including 5 top-tier backbones
constitute the upstream industry (Kende, 2000) and over 10,000 ISPs for
accessing the Internet make up the downstream industry (Weinberg, 2000).
A backbone provider service is critical for any ISPs desiring to connect
to the Internet. There are manifold interconnections between ISPs and
IBPs. Moving data from one interconnection (tier-to-tier (IBP-to-ISP),
or IBP-to-IBP, ISP-to-ISP) to another is the catalyst changing the
Internet market structure. Compounding this is when users change mode of
access from narrowband (dial-up) to broadband (DSL or Cable Modem).
Narrowband dial-up access has been a major way to connect the internet,
but in the summer of 2004, the number of broadband internet users
surpassed the number of narrowband dial-up users. In this paper, we
analyze the dynamic internet industry (both IBP and ISP) using market
share and Internet interconnection strategies and dissect its
complicated industry structure.
VERTICAL INDUSTRY STRUCTURE
Overview of Internet Industry
The Internet industry integrates the equipment, software, and
organizational infrastructure required for Internet communications. As a
rough approximation it can be said it is divided into two components:
IBPs that transfer communications in bulk among network exchange points,
and ISPs that (1) receive communications from individuals or
institutions and transfer them to an IBP's network, and (2) receive
communications from a IBP and transfer them to their destination. ISPs
are used to refer to any company who can offer Internet connectivity.
Some people use ISPs as a general term including IBPs. Some people argue
that ISPs can be differentiated from other types of online information
services, such as CompuServe or American On Line, because ISPs do not
provide content but they focus only on providing Internet connectivity.
Generally speaking, the Internet industry has a vertical structure:
Upstream IBPs provide an intermediate good and downstream ISPs using
this input sell connectivity to their customers. Simplified, we suggest
the analogy that the relationship between IBPs and ISPs is very much
like that of "wholesalers and retailers."
In reality the internet is much more complex. The ISPs themselves
are networks of users that may directly exchange information among each
other. In addition, the IBPs may provide services directly to users and
also may interconnect with other IBPs. A gestalt perspective gives the
understanding that the internet is a network of networks that is
accessible in many parts of the world. Since the telephone industry is
tightly intertwined with the Internet industry, we begin by with its
examination.
Telephone Industry and its Relationship with Internet Industry
Public Switched Telephone Network (PSTN) was designed and optimized
for the transmission of the human voice. In the United States, telephone
service is divided into two industries: (1) local telephone service
provided by Local Exchange Carriers (LECs) and (2) long distance
telephone service provided by Interexchange Carriers (IXCs). This
structure creates a vertical hierarchy: Upstream IXCs provide the
connection between LECs, and the downstream LECs have direct access to
telephone users. The hierarchical structure of telephone industry has a
strong impact on the Internet industry. This is due to the fact that
many of these companies provide some type of service to either or both
the ISP and IBP and/or the end user. End users in this case can be
either public, private, or governmental users.
Traditionally, a LEC was a monopoly that served a specific
geographic region without competition. Even after deregulation, LECs are
still considered by many to be a local monopoly, especially for
residential customers. In the U.S., the local telephone services
provided flat-rate billing, that is, a telephone user can originate
local calls as many times and as long as he wishes with only monthly
flat rate. This type of billing system has been a great influence on the
growth of Internet access market. This is not true for foreign countries
where consumers often pay for time and distance for each call, whether
it is local or long distance. Although not the topic of this paper, it
is a good example why the internet is so expensive in countries where
time and distance charges are levied against each call as compared to
local telephone rates in the U.S.
The long distance market is now generally considered to be a very
competitive market, though it too was a monopoly less than thirty years
ago. Users can make a long distance call with pre-selected IXC through
their LEC. Any IXC that wishes to handle calls originating in a local
service area can build a switching office, called a Point of Presence
(POP). The function of the POP is to interconnect networks so that any
site where networks interconnect may be referred to as a POP.
Dial-up access using PSTN is the most universal form of Internet
access. In the U.S., a modem call is typically a local call without a
per-minute charge. ISP's lines are treated as a business telephone
user not as a carrier, so they are not required to pay the measured
Common Carrier Line Charge (CCLC) for originating and terminating calls,
which recovers part of the cost of the local loop. The switching system
in LEC's POP connects calls between Internet users and ISP's
modem pool so the LECs' facilities support dial-up Internet
communications. In addition, IBPs and large ISPs often construct their
backbone networks by leasing lines from IXCs and LECs. As a result, we
can say that telephone industry provides the basic infrastructure for
the Internet industry.
INTERNET INTERCONNECTION STRATEGY
Background of Internet Interconnection
There are two types of Internet interconnection among ISPs and
IBPs: peering and transit. The only difference among theses types is in
the financial rights and obligation that they generate to their
customers (Weiss & Shin, 2004). To understand the relationship
between peering and transit, it is necessary to recall the
non-commercial origin of the Internet. During the Internet's early
development, there was only one backbone and only one customer, the
military, so interconnection was not an issue. In the 1980s, as the
Internet was opened to academic and research institutions, the National
Science Foundation (NSF) funded the NSFNET as an Internet backbone.
Around that time, the Federal Internet Exchange (FIX) served as a first
point of interconnection between federal and academic networks. At the
time that commercial networks began appearing, general commercial
activity on the Internet was restricted by Acceptable Use Policy (AUP),
which prevented the commercial networks from exchanging traffic with one
another using the NSFNET as the backbone (Kende, 2000). In the early
1990s, a number of commercial backbone operators including PSINet,
UUNET, and CerfNET established the Commercial Internet Exchange (CIX)
for the purpose of interconnecting theses backbones and exchanging their
end users' traffic. The NSF decided to stop operating the NSF
backbone which was replaced by four Network Access Points (NAPs) (Minoli
and Schmidt, 1998). NAPs are public interconnection points where major
providers interconnect their network and these connections consist of
high-speed switchs or a network of switches to which a number of routers
can be connected for the purpose of traffic exchange. The function of
NAPs is similar to major airport hubs; all ISPs and IBPs are gathered at
the NAPs to connect each other. The NSF required that any ISP receiving
government contracts or receiving money from public universities must
connect to all of the NAPs. After the advent of CIX and NAPs, commercial
backbones developed and a system of interconnection known as peering
quickly evolved.
Peering Interconnection Strategy
The term "peering" is sometimes used generically to refer
to Internet interconnection with no financial settlement, known as a
"Sender Keeps All (SKA)" or "Bill and Keep," which
can be thought of as payments or financial transfers between ISPs in
return for interconnection and interoperability (Cawley, 1997). Peering
can be divided into several categories: (1) according to its openness,
it can be private peering or public peering, (2) according to the
numbers of peering partners it can be Bilateral Peering Arrangement
(BLPA) or Multilateral Peering Arrangement (MLPA), and (3) according to
the market in which it occurs, it can be primary peering in the backbone
market or secondary peering in the downstream market (Weiss and Shin,
2004). A peering arrangement is based on equality, that is, ISPs of
equal size would peer. The measures of size could be (i) geographic
coverage, (ii) network capacity, (iii) traffic volume, (iv) size of
customer base, or (v) a position in the market. The ISPs would peer when
they perceive equal benefit from peering based on their own subjective
terms (Kende, 2000).
The original four NAPs were points for public peering. As the
Internet traffic grew, the NAPs suffered from congestion. Therefore,
direct circuit interconnection between two large IBPs was introduced
(called bilateral private peering) which takes place at a mutually
agreed place of interconnection. This private peering is opposed to
public peering that takes place at the NAPs. It is estimated that 80
percent of Internet traffic is exchanged via private peering (Kende,
2000).
Before the Internet privatization, the NSF was responsible for the
operation of the Internet. There are probably around 50 major NAPs
world-wide in the internet, most of which are located in the U.S.
(Moulton, 2001). As the Internet continues to grow, NAPs suffer
congestion because of the enormous traffic loads. Because of the
resulting poor performance, private direct interconnections between big
IBPs were introduced, called peering points.
From the interconnection perspective, NAPs are the place for public
peering. Anyone who is a member of NAP can exchange traffic based on the
equal cost sharing. Members pay for their own router to connect to the
NAP plus the connectivity fee charged by the NAP. Historically, in
public peering, there was no discrimination for interconnection among
the service providers (no priority given or taken based on usage). On
the other hand, the direct interconnection between two equal sized IBPs
is bilateral private peering, which takes place at the mutually agreed
place of interconnection.
According to Block (Cukier, 1999), there are two conditions
necessary for the SKA peering, that is, peering with no settlement, to
be viable: (1) The traffic flows should be roughly balanced between
interconnecting networks; and (2) the cost of terminating traffic should
be low in relation to the cost of measuring and billing for traffic. The
conclusion drawn from the above observations is that peering is
sustainable under the assumption of mutual benefits and avoidance of
costly, unnecessary traffic measuring. Nevertheless, peering partners
would make a peering arrangement if they each perceive that they have
more benefits than costs from the peering arrangement. Most ISPs in the
U.S. historically have not metered traffic flows and accordingly have
not erected a pricing mechanism based on usage. Unlimited access with a
flat rate is a general form of pricing structure in the Internet
industry. Finally, peering makes billing simple: no metering and no
financial settlement.
Peering benefits come mainly from the network externality. Network
externalities arise when the value or utility that a customer derives
from a product or service increases as a function of other customers of
the same or compatible products or services; that is, the more users
there are, the more valuable the network is (Kende, 2000). There are two
kinds of network externalities in the internet. One is direct network
externality: the more E-mail users, the more valuable the internet. The
other is indirect network externality: the more internet users there
are, more web content will be developed which makes the internet even
more valuable for its users. The ability to provide direct and indirect
network externalities to customers provides an almost overpowering
incentive for ISPs to cooperate with one another by interconnecting
their networks (Kende, 2000). Contributing to the motivation for peering
is lower latency because cooperation makes it necessary for only one hop
to exchange traffic between peering partners.
Transit Interconnection Strategy
Transit is an alternative arrangement between ISPs, in which one
pays another to deliver traffic between its customers and the customers
of other provider. The relationship of transit arrangement is
hierarchical: a provider-customer relationship. Unlike a peering
relationship, a transit provider will route traffic from the transit
customer to its peering partners. With transit agreements, usually small
IBPs are able to receive and send communications using the facilities of
large IBPs, and must pay a fee for these services. A concern related to
transit is that while small IBPs do not have to pay in the case of
peering through NAPs, they must pay a transit fee if they directly
connect to one of the large IBPs. Before the commercialization of the
Internet, carriers interconnected without a settlement fee, regardless
of their size. However, after the Internet's commercialization, the
large IBPs announced their requirements for a peering arrangement, and
any carrier who could not meet those terms would be required to pay a
transit fee in addition to the interconnection costs. An IBP with many
transit customers has a better position when negotiating a peering
arrangement with other IBPs. Another difference between peering and
transit is existence of a Service Level Agreement (SLA), which describes
outage and service objectives, and the financial repercussion for
failure to perform. In a peering arrangement, there is no SLA to
guarantee rapid resolution of problems. In case of an outage, both
peering partners may try to resolve the problem, but it is not
mandatory. This is one of the reasons peering agreements with a company
short on competent technical staff are broken. In a transit arrangement
it is a contract and customers could ask the transit provider to meet
the SLA. Many e-commerce companies prefer transit to peering for this
reason. A one minute outage cause the IBP, ISP, and the customer losses,
hence, rapid recovery is critical to their business. Furthermore, in the
case of transit, there is no threat to quit the relationship while in
the case of peering a non-renewal of the peering agreement is a threat.
ISPs are not permitted to form transit relationship over public NAPs
because these are designed as a neutral meeting place for peering. When
purchasing transit service, ISPs will consider other factors beside low
cost: performance of the transit provider's backbone, location of
access nodes, number of directly connected customers, and a market
position.
ANALYSIS OF BACKBONE AND ACCESS MARKETS
Internet Backbone Market
With some simplification, it can be said that the IBPs receive
communications in bulk from POPs or NAPs and distribute them to other
POPs or NAPs close to the destination. To make the Internet a seamless
network, the IBPs have multiple POPs distributed over the whole world.
Most frequently they are located in large urban centers. These POPs are
connected to each other with owned or leased optical carrier lines.
Typically, these lines are 622 Mbps (OC-12) or 2.488 Gbps (OC-48)
circuits or more, as defined by the SONET hierarchy, a standard for
connecting fiber-optic transmission systems. These POPs and optical
carrier lines make up the IBP backbone network. The IBP's POPs, are
also connected with the POPs of many ISPs. The relationship between an
ISP's POP and IBP's is the same as that of ISPs and IBPs.
According to Erickson (2001), the North American backbone market
had around 36 IBPs in the first quarter of 2001. However, these numbers
misinterpret the Internet backbone market structure because this market
is highly concentrated. There were 11,888 transit interconnections
between backbone and access markets in April 2000 (McCarthy, 2000).
Counting by the number of connections to downstream market, MCI/Worldcom
is a dominant player in the backbone market with 3,145 connections and
Sprint is the second largest backbone provider with 1,690 connections
and AT&T (934 connections) and C&W (851 connections) are the
third and the fourth.
Several of the large IBPs are subsidiaries of large telephone
companies such as AT&T, MCI/WorldCom, Sprint, etc. Since these
companies own the infrastructure needed for telephone services, they are
very favorably positioned to provide the facilities and equipment
required by the IBPs. In addition, due to their economies scale, they
are able to offer large volume discount rates or bundling agreements of
both telephone and Internet lines for the services they provide. This is
possible because the Internet industry is lightly, if at all, regulated.
In particular, there are no regulations with respect to the tariffs that
can be charged for the services provided. From these observations it
follows that the large IBPs, supported by the large telephone companies,
are in a position to capture large shares of the upstream market.
According to the Carlton and Perloff (1999), the most common
measure of concentration in an industry is the share of sales by the
four largest firms, called the 'C4' ratio. Generally speaking,
if the C4 ratio is over 60, the market is considered a tight oligopoly.
For the upstream backbone market this ratio based on the 1999 U.S.
backbone revenue (Worldcom 38%, Genuity 15%, AT&T 11%, Sprint 9%) is
73, which shows high concentration in the market. The entry barrier is
also high because there is a large sunk cost for nationwide backbone
lines and switching equipment. The number of IBPs for the past three
years shows just how high the entry barrier in the backbone market is:
43 (1999), 41(2000), and 36 (2001) (Erickson, 2001). The slight
reduction for last three years is caused by mergers and acquisitions and
reclassification. According to the number of players, we conclude that
the overall backbone market is stable although oligarchic. In addition
there are significant economies of scale and the rapid pace of
technological change generates a large amount of uncertainty about the
future return on investments. It is not easy to enter this market
without large investments and advanced technology.
The interconnection price is usually determined by the
provider's relative strength and level of investment in a
particular area (Halabi, 2000). It is certain T-1 transit price has been
decreasing continuously. In 1996, the internet connectivity for T-1 was
$3,000 per month with $1000 setup fee (Halabi, 1997). According to
Martin (2001), the average price of T-1 connection in 1999 was $1,729.
In 2000, it was $1,348. In 2001, it was $1,228. One of reasons for
decreasing T-1 interconnection price is advent of substitute services
for T-1 line, such as wireless Internet access technology (LMDS,
Satellite), digital subscriber line (DSL) technology, and cable-modem
technology, which exerts a downward pressure on T-1 prices. As
technology continues to improve and data transmission rates increase,
pressure will continue to maintain a cap on service.
Internet Access Market
An ISP's product is public access to the Internet, which
includes login authorization, e-mail services, some storage space, and
possibly personal web pages. The ISP's coverage area is usually
determined by the existence of an ISP's POP within the local
telephone area. ISPs are classified as local, regional, and national
according to the scope of their service coverage. The distribution of
ISPs is presented in the Table 2.
Among 307 telephone area codes in U.S., the largest ISP covers 282
area codes and the smallest covers only 1 area code. The ISPs with 1 to
10 area codes constitute 79.81% of the total number of ISPs. This
explains that most of ISPs in the downstream market are small, local
companies. Some of these small ISPs are subsidiaries or affiliates of
CLECs (Competitive Local Exchange Carriers), which are small telephone
companies established in the 1990s as a result of telephone industry
deregulation.
AOL-Time Warner is a dominant player in the dial-up access market.
According to Goldman (2004), AOL-Time Warner had 22.8 million
subscribers in the 3rd Quarter of 2004. AOL-Time Warner's
subscribers are 22.8 million (24%) out of 81.1 million U.S. subscribers
(Goldman, 2004). The Table 2 shows top 10 dial-up ISPs ranked by the
number of subscribers.
In the downstream access market the C4 ratio is 43 and would be
defined as relatively concentrated. However, the entry barrier in the
downstream market is much lower than in the backbone market. Since
subscribers can utilize the PSTN line to connect ISPs' modems and
ISPs purchase business telephone lines from a LEC, ISPs for dial-up
service do not have to invest in access lines to individual subscribers.
They can build POPs to link to the PSTN and other ISPs. Since a T-1
lines prices and telecom equipment prices are currently dropping
quickly, a large number of small ISPs are possible, especially in the
less densely populated areas. The number of North American ISPs for the
past several years is an evidence of low entry barrier in the downstream
market: 1447 (February 1996), 3640 (February 1997), 4470 (February
1998), 5078 (March 1999), 7463 (April 2000), and 7288 (March 2001)
(Erickson, 2001).
Most ISPs provide unlimited Internet access with a monthly flat
rate. For major national ISPs, the price ranges generally from $0 to $25
per month dependent on the level of service. Some ISPs provide Internet
access service with zero monthly subscription fees to their customers;
their revenues depend completely on Internet advertising income. Some
base their service on speed, while others on memory usage as an upgrade
to their standard service.
ISPs are free to make local peering arrangements with other ISPs.
Cremer and Tirole (2000, p445) call this local secondary peering. The
Pittsburgh Internet Exchange (PITX) is an example of local peering
arrangement. Without this local peering, all network traffic passing
from one Pittsburgh network to another had to be sent through
Washington, D.C., Chicago, or New York City. The sending and receiving
networks pay an unnecessary cost for this inefficient handling of data
that should have remained local. Participants in this local exchange
point reduce their costs and improve performance and reliability for
their local Internet traffic with the equal basis of cost recovery.
However, this kind of peering is confined to local internet traffic.
Outbound traffic (connected to other networks through an IBP) to other
areas still has to depend on the IBP's transit service.
Broadband Internet Market
The Internet access technologies are roughly divided into two
categories: narrow band access using dial-up modem technology and
broadband access such as Cable-Modem, DSL, and wireless broadband access
technology. Among the above broadband access technologies, DSL and
Cable-Modem are the two dominant broadband access methods. According to
Vara (2004), in July of 2004, more than half of U.S. internet users
connected to the internet using a broadband service. It was the first
time high-speed broadband internet connection had more market share than
dial-up connection. The broadband service providers usually confine
their business to high density regions because broadband service
requires large investments in "advanced" (read expensive)
technologies. Internet users in the rural area rarely have a chance to
enjoy the benefit of the higher speed access that broadband services
offer.
According to Leichtman Research Group, the twenty largest cable and
DSL providers in the US account for about 95% of the market in high
speed internet access. The top broadband providers now account for over
30.9 million high-speed Internet subscribers, with cable having nearly
18.8 million broadband subscribers, and DSL trailing behind at 12.2
million subscribers. If we confine the access market into the broadband
technology, the C4 ratio in this market is 55% which is considered
oligarchic. The following table shows the top 10 broadband access
providers in the U.S.
DE-PEERING AND FOUR-TIER HIERARCHICAL STRUCTURE
In 1996, AGIS was the first IBP to unilaterally terminate peering
arrangements. After that, a series of IBPs announced that they were
ending peering with many of their previous peering partners and were no
longer accepting peering arrangements from other networks whose
infrastructure would not allow the exchange of similar levels of traffic
access. Instead of peering, they would charge those smaller ISPs for
transit. Finally, the large IBPs moved away from public NAPs to private
peering or maintained relatively small capacities like T3 in the NAPs
and then placed themselves in a new hierarchy, so called top-tier IBPs
(Jew and Nicolls, 1999). Most top-tier IBPs are subsidiaries or
affiliates of the major facilities-based telecommunication carriers.
They are UUNET (Worldcom), C&W, Genuity, AT&T WorldNet, and
Sprint, the 'so called' Big 5. They don't need transit
service from others and they make peering arrangement with each other.
Over 80% of the U.S. backbone traffic is estimated to pass through their
systems and switches (Weinberg, 2000). Other non Big 5 IBPs make peering
arrangements among themselves and simultaneously purchase transit
services from the Big 5.
There are two cases for which peering is generally refused: (1)
Regional IBPs which do not have a national backbone network and (2)
content providers or web hosting companies, so called web farms. The
main reason for this refusal is a free-rider issue. Peering partners
generally meet in a number of geographically dispersed locations. In
order to decide where to pass traffic to another, they have adopted what
is known as "hot-potato routing," where an ISP will pass
traffic to another backbone at the earliest point of exchange. Under the
hot-potato routing rule, someone who does not have a national backbone
network must transport its traffic on the others' backbone
networks. In addition to that, asymmetric traffic patterns, which occur
in file transfer or web surfing, result in increased capacity costs
without commensurate revenues.
Some of the Big 5 recently disclosed their policy for peering but
some of them still do not. There is an unwritten rule shared by the Big
5 about their peering standard: (i) A coast to coast national backbone
with a certain level of bandwidth requirement, (ii) a number of
presences in the major exchange points, (iii) 7 days by 24 hours Network
Operation Center (NOC) and highly experienced technical staffs, and (iv)
a certain level of traffic ratio between inbound and outbound, usually
1:4. It is indeterminate what the exact requirements for the private
peering are since peering agreements are under non-disclosure. Without a
doubt, these requirements could be a significant entry barrier for any
new entrant.
PSINet, which was one of the large IBPs, used a peering standard
called "open peering policy", that was different from the Big
5. It would peer with any ISP including local, regional, and national
except for companies whose primary business was web hosting or content
collection. Some of the Big 5 did not want to peer with PSINet, because
some of PSINet's private peering partners are transit customers of
the Big 5. Whenever the Big 5 upgrade their networks, they upgrade their
peering policy. From the tier-2 IBP's point of view, peering
requirements are getting tougher and tougher. Nobody can enter into the
top tier group without their approval. This cartel-like behavior has
been an important issue in the Internet industry for several years and
will eventually be a sticking point with the Federal Trade Commission in
the future.
After being refused peering in the backbone market, ISPs in the
downstream access market, usually operating in a limited geographic
region, tried to peer among themselves. Cremer and Tirole (2000) in
their paper call this kind of peering "local secondary
peering." This is a major factor in proliferation of local and
regional Internet exchange points. These smaller exchange points
(compared to NAPs) referred to as Metropolitan Exchange Points (MXPs)
(OECD, 1998).
Most of Internet exchange points, or POPs of major IBPs are located
near the metropolitan areas, which are far from the rural areas. The
local ISPs in a rural area have to lease long expensive lines to reach
an interconnection point. The long distance from private or public
peering points is an additional obstacle to overcome for the rural ISPs.
Through de-peering in one tier and peering in lower tier in both
markets, the four-tier hierarchical structure has emerged; in the
backbone market, tier-1 IBPs with their nationwide backbones
interconnect each other and make a core network in the Internet and
tier-2 IBPs with their regional backbones interconnect each other and
pay tier-1 IBPs for connectivity to rest of internet, which mean they
are customers of tier-1 providers. A few of nationwide big ISPs are also
a member of tier-2 group. In the access market, tier-3 regional ISPs are
customers of tier-1 or tier-2 connecting them to the rest of internet.
Local, small ISPs are tier-4 providers and they are customers of higher
tier providers. However, the demarcation between the tiers is not clear.
In the following section we explain how peering decisions are made.
PEERING DECISION-MAKING PROCESS
An interconnection strategy may be different according to its
priority. If expense of interconnection is the number one issue, ISPs
will try to find as many peering partners as they can and try to choose
minimum combination costs among them. Or if performance is the top
priority, they may prefer private peering or transit to public peering.
All interconnection decisions start from the analysis of their own
traffic. An ISP should try to find the available options and negotiate
with their interconnection partners for interconnection methodology,
interconnection line capacity, interconnection settlement, etc. This
process will be explained below in detail. (Norton, 1999)
Phase I: Identification of ISP's Traffic
The costs of peering and transit vary according to the distance of
the ISPs' POP and interconnection point. Generally, the cost of
transit is more expensive than that of peering. Before deciding on a
transit or peering arrangement, the ISP may systematically sample
inbound and outbound traffic flows and then map these flows to the
originating Autonomous System (AS), which is defined as a collection of
networks that are under the administrative control of a single
organization and that share a common routing strategy. Calculations are
made to determine where to reduce the load on the expensive transit
paths.
Phase II: Finding Potential Interconnection Partners
Based on the traffic map and the aforementioned analysis, ISPs try
to find interconnection partners. Because peering policies are often
exposed only under Non-Disclosure Agreements (NDA), it is not easy to
know them in advance of negotiations. It is reasonable for an ISP to
find its peering partners in its own level of Internet industry
hierarchy. If a top-tier IBPs makes a peering arrangement with a second
tier IBP, then the latter could be the formers' competitor.
Therefore, a higher tier ISP would prefer selling transit service to
lower tier ISPs and have an incentive to reduce the number of their own
competitors. Many ISPs, except for top tier IBPs, have adopted a hybrid
approach to interconnection, peering with a number of ISPs and paying
for transit from one or more IBPs in order to have access to the transit
provider as well as the peering partners of the transit provider.
Phase III: Implementing Interconnection Methodology
Since peering is seen as being of mutual benefit, both parties
explore the interconnection methods that will most effectively exchange
traffic. Both parties decide (1) how many interconnection points they
have, (2) where to locate the interconnection points, (3) how they
interconnect, private peering or public peering, (4) what line capacity
they will use, (5) settlement free or settlement involved, etc.
Table 6 illustrates comparison of per Mega-bit cost of transit,
private peering, and public peering. If we compare cost per Mbps shipped
(CPMS) per month of OC3 capacity, the order from the cheapest is public
peering ($30), private peering ($64~$129), and transit ($464).
CONCLUSION
The Internet has become an important social and business tool.
Furthermore, the market has become even more dynamic since it was
privatized. Peering has emerged as a phenomenon that can at one time be
beneficial to both parties while simultaneously discriminate against one
of the peering partners. Professor Frieden calls it a
"balkanization" in the Internet. If a new technology was
introduced in this market, the internet providers with this technology
would have a tendency from past practices to create their own peer
groups to make money against the provider without this technology. On
the other hand, ISPs are competitors and cooperators simultaneously:
competitors for market share and cooperators for global connectivity.
One ISP's decision has an influence on other ISP's decisions.
Thus, they have a strong dependence on each other beyond just
competitive factors.
In our paper, we believe that the two-tier, two layer market
structure of both backbone and access is oligopolistic. This means, if a
new technology is developed lowering costs, or increasing speed, or if
some of them reach an agreement they could exercise their market power,
maybe for the better for the consumer, maybe not. A policy maker's
goal for the Internet industry is continuing growth and innovation. To
achieve this goal, regulators need to continue to encourage competition
and to give incentives for ongoing investment and in the development and
deploying of new technologies, which will benefit consumers in the
internet market. Therefore, it is a role of internet policy makers to
make socially desirable competitive environments between higher tier
ISBs and lower tier ISPs in the Internet industry.
REFERENCES
Carlton, D. & J. Perloff, (1999). Modern Industrial
Organization, 3rd Edition. New York:Addison Wesley Longman.
Cawley, R.A. (1997). Interconnection, pricing, and settlements:
Some healthy jostling in the growth of the Internet. In Kahin, B. &
J. Keller (1997). Coordinating the Internet (pp. 346-376). Boston,
Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Cremer, J., P. Rey, & J. Tiroel, (2000). Connectivity in the
Commercial Internet. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 40(8),
433-472.
Erickson, T., (2001). Introduction to the Directory of Internet
Service Providers, 13th Edition. Boardwatch Magazine, from
http://www.ispworld.com/isp.
Frieden, R. (1998). Without public peer: The potential regulatory
and universal service consequences of Internet Balkanization. 3 Virginia
Journal of Law & Technology 8, from http:
//vjolt.student.virginia.edu/.
Goldman, A., (2004). Top 23 U.S. ISPs by Subscriber: Q3 2004.
ISP-Planet magazine, from
http://www.isp-planet.com/research/ranking/usa.html
Greene, B.R., (2000). L2 Internet exchange Point (IXP) using a BGP Route Reflector. Draft version 0.4, from
http://www.cisco.com/public/cons/isp/ixp.
Halabi, B., (1997). Internet Routing Architectures. Indianapolis,
IN: Cisco Press.
Halabi, B., (2001). Internet Routing Architectures 2nd Edition.
Indianapolis, IN: Cisco Press.
Jew, B. & Nicholls, R., (1999), Internet Connectivity: Open
Competition In the Face of Commercial Expansion. 1999 Pacific
Telecommunications Conference.
Kende, M., (2000). The Digital Handshake: Connecting Internet
Backbones. FCC-OPP Working Paper No. 32, from
http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/OPP/working_papers/oppwp32.pdf.
Martin, L., (2001). Backbone Web Hosting Measurements. Boardwatch
Magazine, from http://www.ispworld.com/isp/Performance_Test.htm.
Minoli, D. & A. Schmidt, (1999). Internet Architectures. New
York, NY: Wiley.
Moulton, P., (2001). The Telecommunications Survival Guide. Upper
Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Norton, W.B., (1999). Internet Service Providers and Peering, draft
version 1.9, from http://www.nanog.org/mtg-0010/tree.doc.
OECD, (1998). Internet Traffic Exchange: Development and Policy,
from http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/11/26/2091100.pdf
Vara, V., (2004). High-Speed Surpasses Dial-up As Top Home Web
Access in U.S., from http://www.wsj.com.
Weinberg, N., (2000). Backbone Bullies. Forbes, June 12 edition,
236-237.
Weiss, M., & S. Shin, (2004). Internet interconnection economic
model and its analysis: Peering and settlement, Netnomics, 6, 43-57.
SeungJae Shin, Mississippi State University--Meridian
Jack Tucci, Mississippi State University--Meridian
Martin B. H. Weiss, University of Pittsburgh
Hector Correa, University of Pittsburgh *
ENDNOTES
* Dr. Correa, an international scholar and professor in the
Graduate School of Public and International Affairs at the University of
Pittsburgh who passed away in the summer of 2004. We deeply appreciate
his effort in this paper.
Table 1: Distribution of ISPs by their coverage
(Erickson, 2001)
Telephone area codes
covered by ISP Percentage Type
1 35.14% Local
2-10 44.67% Local / Regional
11-24 4.11% Regional
25-282 16.08% National
Table 2: Top 10 U.S. ISPs (Q3 2004)
(Goldman, 2004)
Rank & ISP Subscribers Market Share
(1) AOL 22.8M 24.0%
(2) United Online 6.6M 6.9%
(3) Comcast 6.5M 6.8%
(4) EarthLink 5.2M 5.7%
(5) SBC 4.7M 4.9%
(6) Road Runner 3.9M 4.1%
(7) Verizon 3.3M 3.5%
(8) Coax 2.4M 2.5%
(9) BellSouth 1.9M 2.0%
(10) Charter 1.8M 1.9%
Table 3: Top 10 U.S. Broadband ISPs (Q3 2004)
(Lehichman Research Group, http://www.itfacts.biz)
Rank & ISP Subscriber Market Share
(1) Comcast (Cable) 6.5M 20%
(2) SBC (DSL) 4.7M 14%
(3) Time Warner (Cable) 3.7M 11%
(4) Verizon (DSL) 3.3M 10%
(5) Cox (Cable) 2.4M 7%
(6) Bell South (DSL) 1.9M 6%
(7) Charter (Cable) 1.8M 6%
(8) Adelphia (Cable) 1.3M 4%
(9) Cablevision (Cable) 1.3M 4%
(10) Qwest (DSL) 1.0M 3%
Table 4: Per M-bit Cost Comparison
(AT&T (Transit), Norton (2000, Private Peering), and Chicago
NAP (Public Peering))
Interconnection
Type Capacity Cost / Capacity Per M bit Cost
Transit DS3 $26,000/45M $578/M
OC3 $72,000/155M $464/M
Private Peering OC3 ($10,000~$20,000)/ $64/M ~ $129/M
155M/2
OC12 ($20,000~$30,000)/ $32/M ~$48/M
622M/2
Public Peering DS3 $3,900/45M $87/M
OC3 $4,700/155M $30/M