Banking and commerce: tear down this wall?(laws prohibiting banking
Walter, John R.
Many U.S. firms include both commercial and nonbank financial
units. For example, General Motors Corporation encompasses not only
units that manufacture automobiles but also those, such as General
Motors Acceptance Corporation, that gather funding and make loans to
individuals and businesses. Firms that handle both commercial and
financial activities appear to reap significant benefits that create the
appeal of such combinations. One byproduct of a commercial firm's
activities may be information about its customers' financial
situation. The financial affiliate might then use this information to
inexpensively target products to particular customers, benefiting both
the financial firm and its customers.
While finance/commerce combinations are widespread, combinations
between banks and commercial firms are typically prohibited under
various U.S. laws. Banks are distinguished from other financial firms by
their ability to gather funding by issuing government-insured deposits
such as checking and savings deposits. Despite prohibitions of
banking/commerce combinations, firms have managed to find loopholes.
Until recently the unitary thrift loophole was a popular means of
circumventing the banking/commerce wall. The loophole allowed commercial
companies to start or buy one, and only one, thrift (i.e., a savings
bank or savings and loan association, both of which issue
government-insured deposits), using the thrift as a conduit for
providing financial services.
The unitary thrift loophole was closed in 1999, but another
loophole remains open. Federal banking law allows commercial firms to
own industrial loan corporations--essentially banks with somewhat
restricted deposit-taking powers. (For additional discussion of the
unitary thrift and industrial loan corporation loopholes, see the
Appendix.)
Given the apparent benefits of combinations, why prohibit or
restrict them? What hazards result from banking/commerce combinations?
Traditionally, discussions of the threats focused on conflicts of
interest and diminished competition. More recently, observers have been
concerned that combinations might increase deposit insurance claims and
expand the universe of economic activities protected by the government
safety net. As will be discussed presently, the traditional concerns
seem less relevant given the level of competition banks face in
today's banking market. Over the last twenty-five years,
competition has expanded as restrictions were eliminated on banks'
ability to operate across state lines and to offer market rates on
deposits. Also, new nonbank firms have arisen offering financial
products competitive with most banking products. The concerns over
increased deposit insurance claims and expansion of the safety net
remain quite relevant. Nevertheless, over the last decade a number of
legislators have a rgued for removal of the banking/commerce wall. I
will analyze the threats and suggest some restrictions that would be
necessary if the wall were removed.
1. THE STATUTES FORMING THE WALL
The building blocks of the wall between banking and commerce are
various federal and state laws. The laws prevent banks from engaging in
commercial activities. They also prevent banks from owning subsidiary
commercial companies and from being owned by companies conducting
commercial activities. Specifically, the building blocks are the
National Bank Act of 1864, state banking laws, the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991, and the Bank Holding
Company Act of 1956. (For a detailed review of these statutes and their
motivations see the Appendix.)
The National Bank Act limits the powers of national banks and their
subsidiaries. National banks are those chartered and regulated by the
U.S. Treasury Department's Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency. The Act states that "a national banking association
shall... have power to... exercise... all such incidental powers as
shall be necessary to carry on the business of banking" (12 U.S.C.
24). While over the years the courts and the Comptroller have wrangled
over the meaning of the phrase "business of banking," national
banks have been allowed to engage in businesses similar to traditional
banking services but not other commercial activities. This restriction
of powers extends not only to activities of banks, but to activities
conducted by subsidiaries owned by banks.
State banking statutes typically set limits on the nonbank
activities of state banks and their subsidiaries, similar to the limits
on national banks. Yet, over the years, a number of states have
authorized activities well beyond those allowed national banks, some of
which typically would be considered commercial powers. Concerns that
these new powers might endanger state-chartered banks, and thereby the
taxpayer-backed deposit insurance fund, led Congress to restrict state
legislatures' ability to grant powers to state-chartered banks.
Specifically, under the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
Improvement Act of 1991 (FDICIA), insured state-chartered banks are
prohibited from engaging in any activities impermissible for national
banks unless the FDIC rules that such activities pose no threat to the
deposit insurance fund.
Those who advocate removing the banking/commerce wall typically do
not argue for allowing banks to conduct commercial activities or own
commercial firms. Instead, they focus on allowing companies that own
banks--that is, bank holding companies--to own commercial companies,
too. In other words, they do not condone direct bank involvement in
commerce but find it acceptable for bank holding companies to own
commercial companies, allowing banks to affiliate with commercial
companies.
The banking/commerce restrictions in the Bank Holding Company Act
of 1956 were based on the view that "bank holding companies ought
to confine their activities to the management and control of
banks." The Act restricted bank holding companies such that they
"would no longer be authorized to manage or control nonbanking
assets unrelated to the banking business" (U.S. Code: Congressional
and Administrative News [1956, 2482, 2484]).
To enforce this restriction, the Act defines a bank holding company
as any company that owns a bank. (1) It prohibits bank holding companies
from engaging in nonbanking activities. The Act allows an exception to
the nonbanking prohibition in cases in which the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System determines the nonbanking activity "to
be so closely related to banking as to be a proper incident
thereto" (12 U.S.C. 1843c). Typically the Board defines activities
closely related to banking as only those activities traditionally
performed by banks. Certain additional activities also have been
allowed, however, in cases in which they are tied to banking. For
example, the Board has determined that a bank holding company may own a
data-processing firm if it is primarily engaged in processing financial,
banking, or economic data (Spong [2000, 156]).
The Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, enacted in 1999, added securities
underwriting and dealing, as well as insurance, to the list of
activities in which banks--through bank-owned subsidiaries-and bank
holding companies could engage. Those bank holding companies choosing to
engage in securities or insurance activities are called financial
holding companies. The Act also expanded the activities of bank-owning
companies to include most financial activities, those determined by the
Board and the Treasury Department to be "financial in nature,"
"incidental to a financial activity," or "complementary
to a financial activity." Nonetheless, while authorizing a wide
range of financial activities, the Act leaves in place the wall between
banking and commerce.
Deciding whether an activity is commercial instead of banking or
financial and whether it can be conducted by a banking company is often
not simple. The decision was difficult under the old Bank Holding
Company Act standard of being closely related and remains so under the
new standard of being financial in nature, incidental to a financial
activity, or complementary to a financial activity. The placement of an
activity on one side or the other of the banking/commerce wall can be
controversial and contentious. For example, in December 2000 the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the Secretary of the
Treasury jointly released for comments a proposal to permit bank
subsidiaries and financial holding companies to engage in real estate
brokerage and management. Real estate industry trade groups quickly
objected to the proposal, arguing that it would amount to an illegal
mixture of banking and commerce. Banking trade groups argued in favor of the proposal. Beyond the real estate industry's objecti ons,
legislators introduced bills in both the U.S. House of Representatives
and the Senate to prohibit these real estate activities in financial
holding companies. In April 2002 the Secretary of the Treasury announced
plans to put off a decision on the proposal until 2003.
2. RATIONALES FOR THE WALL
Three reasons are typically cited for maintaining a wall that
prohibits banking/commerce combinations: conflicts of interest, monopoly
power, and risk to the taxpayer-backed deposit insurance fund. (2) These
three justifications will be examined below. As it turns out, because
banking markets appear fairly competitive, the first two seem of
relatively minor import. The third remains quite significant.
Conflicts of Interest
Observers have at times raised concerns over conflicts of interest
that might arise if banks and commercial firms are owned by the same
firm. They argue that such concerns justify keeping banking and commerce
separate. Three conflicts have been described. First, a bank affiliated
with a commercial firm would tend to deny loans to the affiliate's
competitors. Second, a bank might use access to insured deposits to
provide below-market-rate funding to its affiliates while charging
higher interest rates to unaffiliated borrowers. Third, in the
legislative history of the Bank Holding Company Act, legislators noted
that a bank with a commercial affiliate might deny loans to individuals
who do not purchase goods from the affiliate.
It seems natural that removing the banking/commerce wall would
allow the first conflict to arise, since a bank with a commercial
affiliate, say a restaurant, would not wish to provide funding to
competing restaurants. Helping the competitor would tend to lower the
profits of the affiliated restaurant. Yet, if competition is reasonably
strong, denying loans to competitors only lowers overall profits of the
consolidated banking/restaurant firm. If there are alternative lenders
over which the affiliated bank has no price advantage, the competing
restaurant would get a loan anyway and at the same interest rate the
affiliated bank would offer. So, by failing to make the loan, the bank
loses any profit it might have made on that loan, hurting the bank. Yet
the affiliated restaurant suffers a loss in profits regardless. (3)
Therefore, if competition is strong, this potential conflict of interest
is unlikely to present a problem and cannot justify maintaining the
banking/commerce wall.
But is banking competition strong? Since the 1970s, restrictions on
bank-versus-bank competition have been greatly reduced. Restrictions on
banks' ability to compete for deposits outside of their local
markets, or at least outside of their home states, were severe before
the late 1970s. While these restrictions did not apply to bank lending,
banks generate a good bit of their lending in the same markets in which
they gather loans. Consequently, these restrictions likely limited loan
competition as well. Banks' ability to open branches statewide was
greatly enhanced in the 1 980s as many states removed branching
restrictions. Restrictions on operating across state lines began to fall
in the mid-1980s and were almost completely removed by the Riegle-Neal
Interstate Banking Act of 1994. As a result, banks that had been
protected from competition because of branching restrictions became
subject to competitive pressure from nonlocal banks by the mid-1980s.
While the elimination of branching restrictions opened local
banking markets to greater competition, other market and technological
developments have expanded competition further. Consequently, if a bank
denies a loan to a business firm because it competes with the
bank's affiliate, that firm can find numerous alternative sources
of funding in today's more competitive loan markets.
Competition among those who would lend to business borrowers has
expanded along several dimensions. For large business borrowers, banks
faced growing competition from the debt markets as commercial paper and
bond issues increased significantly relative to bank lending over the
last twenty-five years. While small businesses cannot issue commercial
paper or bonds, today's small businesses have access to loans from
a wide range of lenders. The largest banks aggressively court small
business borrowers throughout the country via their Web sites and
toll-free phone lines. Further, small businesses enjoy a range of
choices of nonbank lenders, including finance companies and leasing
companies. Clearly, today's borrowers, both large and small, have a
plethora of borrowing opportunities because of the competitive loan
market.
If, in spite of these factors, some banking markets remain
uncompetitive, policymakers can address the problem directly by removing
any remaining barriers to entry. Alternatively, they might tackle
monopoly power through antitrust enforcement. Maintaining a wall that
separates banking and commerce at best addresses a symptom of an
uncompetitive market rather than the lack of competition itself.
Still, using the restaurant example, one might argue that the bank
with an affiliated restaurant may for some reason have a cost advantage
over its bank competitors that lack such an affiliation. One reason for
a cost advantage is that the bank acquires information about the
restaurant business through its affiliation. While prohibiting
affiliations might eliminate the advantage this bank (and its
affiliates) has over competitors, the restriction would diminish
economic efficiency because the least costly and most efficient means of
producing banking services--through restaurant affiliation--would be
denied.
Additionally, if bank/restaurant affiliations are allowed, banks
that lack a restaurant affiliate can simply overcome the cost
disadvantage by affiliating. This is just what the banking industry did
when banks established branches in grocery and discount stores, though
they did it through leasing agreements rather than affiliation. After
perceiving the advantage gained by the innovative bank that first placed
branches in such stores, other banks followed suit to achieve the same
advantage. Soon the advantage was dissipated by competition.
Aside from the situation whereby a bank might deny loans to its
affiliate's competitors, some observers note a second conflict of
interest. They argue that banks may have access to inexpensive funding
because of underpriced deposit insurance, and that this funding might be
granted to banks' affiliates but not to other borrowers. Such
funding would give affiliates an advantage over firms not so
affiliated.4 As long as the banking market is competitive, however,
every firm that borrows from a bank gets equivalent access to low-cost
funding whether affiliated with a bank or not. Access is equivalent
because a bank only hurts itself (i.e., lowers its revenues) by not
lending to its affiliate's competitors on equivalent terms to those
offered its affiliate. If the bank with an affiliate does not lend to
its affiliate's competitors, other banks would take those customers
and profit from doing so. Further, Section 23A of the Federal Reserve
Act, applicable to all banks, restricts the amount of such affiliate
funding to at most 10 percent of the bank's capital. Section 23B of
the Act requires such funding be on market terms.
In the legislative history of the Bank Holding Company Act, members
of Congress describe a third possible conflict of interest.
Specifically, they argue that a bank with a commercial affiliate might
deny loans to individuals who do not purchase goods from the affiliate.
The Senate Banking Committee's report that analyzes the features of
the bill that later became the Bank Holding Company Act describes the
concern as follows:
The committee was informed of the danger to a bank within a bank
holding company controlling nonbanking assets, should the company unduly
favor its nonbanking operations by requiring the bank's customers
to make use of such nonbanking enterprises as a condition to doing
business with the bank. The bill's divestment provisions should
prevent this fear from becoming a reality. (U.S. Code: Congressional and
Administrative News [1956, 2486], as cited in Halpert [1988, 500])
Tying a loan (or other service) to the purchase of another product
can only benefit a bank if the bank has monopoly power in its loan
market. If it faces competition, denying loans to individuals who are
not its affiliate's customers only hurts the bank, and so would not
be undertaken. The bank is hurt because it forfeits revenues and helps
its bank competitors who would make the loans (Owens [1994]). As noted
earlier, when the Bank Holding Company Act was passed in 1956, banking
markets were heavily regulated. Entry was restricted and prices were
controlled. Monopoly power may have been significant, but most such
restrictions have been removed. Additionally, even if banks maintain
monopoly power in credit markets, the commercial affiliate must also
have market power in order for tying to make consumers worse off. In the
case in which the combined firm has market power in the banking and
commercial markets, only under limited circumstances are consumers
actually made worse off. In other cases consumers are un hurt by tying
(Weinberg [1996]). Regardless, current statutes make tying by banking
companies illegal. (5)
Proliferation of Monopoly
Some observers argue that, in addition to conflicts of interest,
preventing the exercise of monopoly power is another reason for the
banking/commerce separation. The legislative history of the Bank Holding
Company Act makes it clear that Congress intended the Act to guard
against the proliferation of monopoly. For example, the Senate Banking
Committee report on the conference bill notes that the Act was to
provide "safeguards... against undue concentration of control of
banking activities. The dangers accompanying monopoly in this field are
particularly undesirable in view of the significant part played by
banking in our present national economy" (U.S. Code: Congressional
and Administrative News [1956, 2482-83]). Because such language is
vague, it is difficult to determine whether the undue concentration
discussed refers to horizontal or conglomerate concentration. As a
result, it is uncertain whether proliferation of monopoly was behind the
Bank Holding Company Act's banking/commerce restrictions.
Horizontal concentration means combining a number of banks under one
bank holding company such that this holding company controls a high
percentage of banks. Conglomerate concentration means combining both
banks and nonbanks under one holding company so that one conglomerate
controls a significant percentage of business firms in banking and a
nonbanking industry, or in several nonbanking industries.
Observers since have argued that Congress was indeed concerned with
conglomerate concentration. A case in point was a 1974 Federal
Reserve's denial, under the Bank Holding Company Act, of an
application by BankAmerica Corporation to form an overseas joint venture
with Allstate Insurance. Here the Fed said that "close working
relationships abroad between large U.S. banking organizations and large
U.S. insurance companies could in time weave a matrix of relationships.
. . that could lead to an undue concentration of economic resources in
the domestic and foreign commerce of the United States... not. . .
consistent with the purposes of the Bank Holding Company Act." (6)
Frequently, when advocating the separation of banks from nonbanks
on the basis of monopoly, proponents have argued that the combination
would allow the monopoly power that banks hold in their product markets
to be used by combined firms to raise prices in other areas. (7) But as
discussed earlier, while in 1956 concerns about monopoly may have
motivated Congress, during the 1970s and 1 980s competition expanded
greatly, among banks and between banks and nonbanks. Expanded
competition significantly reduced any opportunity banks might have had
to exercise monopoly power in banking services and to expand it to other
businesses with which they might combine. Congress seems to have been
cognizant of these changes. When Congress passed the Gramm-Leach-Bliley
Act in 1999, it allowed combinations of large banks with large insurance
and large securities firms. These were exactly the types of
combinations--that is, large banks with large nonbanks--denied earlier
by regulators based on undue concentration language in th e Bank Holding
Company Act.
Safety Net Concerns
For the reasons discussed above, conflicts of interest and fears of
expanding monopoly power alone are probably insufficient reasons to
maintain the current wall separating banking and commerce and deny firms
the opportunity to benefit from combinations. Nevertheless, there is
another set of hazards that could justify the continued presence of the
wall separating banking and commerce or at least require that
significant precautions be taken if the wall is removed. The hazards
come in three forms, discussed in the following paragraphs, and each
involves an increased chance of bank failures and a subsequent bailout financed by taxpayers. If bailouts occur, the government safety net,
meant to protect bank depositors, could be extended to creditors of
commercial companies. If extended, too many resources might flow to
bank-affiliated commercial companies, and economic efficiency would be
diminished. The threat to the safety net could arise because (1) losses
might be shifted to banks to protect a combined firm's reputation
with investors, (2) losses might be shifted to banks to take advantage
of shareholder limited liability, and (3) the combined firm's
riskiest assets might be shifted to the bank. Of the three hazards, the
first two could justify continued banking/commerce separation. The third
cannot justify separation but is discussed below because it is often
mentioned as a hazard of bank/nonbank affiliations.
Loss Shifts that Protect Reputation
If banking/commerce combinations are allowed, a combined company
can be expected under certain circumstances to withdraw resources from
its bank to hide problems in its commercial subsidiary, damaging bank
safety. The holding company is likely to choose this course when it can
hide commercial subsidiary losses from investors and analysts by
shifting commercial subsidiary losses to the bank. The holding company
would benefit by hiding the loss, which if revealed would likely be
perceived as negative information about the ability of the firm's
management and the riskiness of its operations; that is, it would damage
the firm's reputation. Such negative information would lead
creditors to demand higher interest rates, lowering future profits. Yet,
as discussed presently, while shifts to hide losses can be detrimental to banks, they can just as easily be beneficial: holding companies could
choose to shift bank losses to commercial subsidiaries. Consequently, a
concern that bank holding companies might engage in lo ss shifts is no
reason to prohibit banking/commerce combinations. Instead, if one is to
argue that the danger of shifts can justify the banking/commerce wall,
one must believe that loss shifts are more likely to flow toward bank
than commercial subsidiaries.
Reputation-protecting shifts that can work to the detriment of bank
health are likely to occur when two conditions are met. First, the
commercial subsidiary suffers a loss large enough to create its
insolvency. Second, the loss, if shifter to the bank subsidiary, would
avert the bank's insolvency. The second condition would generally
be met if the bank's net worth is considerably larger than that of
the commercial subsidiary (before and after the shift). Under these
conditions, a shift of a commercial subsidiary's loss to the bank
would protect the holding company's reputation. An insolvency is
certain to draw negative outsider attention, since it will likely
involve either debt renegotiation or bankruptcy. In contrast, a mere
loss or perhaps just an increase in the bank's reported expenses
can be expected to draw far less attention. Even so, a loss shift
necessarily weakens the bank.
Even if the commercial subsidiary experiences a loss that does not
lead to its insolvency but is still significant, such a loss could still
shift to a larger bank subsidiary. The bank holding company might choose
to shift the loss because it might be less noticeable on the books of a
large firm than on those of a smaller one. In addition, observers have
traditionally argued that banks may have more opaque balance sheets than
do commercial firms, so that losses can be better hidden in a bank
subsidiary. Some recent research appears to support this view of bank
opacity. (8) If banks are indeed more opaque, then losses are more
likely to go unnoticed if shifted to the bank.
Nevertheless, the existence of this incentive to shift losses in
order to hide them does not imply that commercial and banking firms
should be kept separate. Under one set of circumstances already
discussed--when the bank's net worth (meaning its capital) is
larger than the commercial subsidiary's--a bank holding company can
hide the loss by shifting it to the bank. However, under an equally
likely set of circumstances--when the commercial subsidiary's
capital exceeds the bank's capital--there is no benefit from
shifting commercial subsidiary losses to the bank. Instead, if the bank
produces losses, the bank holding company can benefit by shifting bank
losses into the commercial firm. Therefore, prohibiting
banking/commercial affiliations will not necessarily improve bank safety
or protect taxpayers and the EDIC from losses.
Further, creditors of banks as well as commercial firms affiliated
with banks are likely to be well aware of the incentive to shift losses
in order to hide them. By charging higher interest rates, both types of
creditors will penalize affiliations that might shift losses to the
detriment of their debtor (either commercial firm or bank). For example,
a bank's creditors would be likely to view a combination with a
risky commercial firm--that is, one that might produce shiftable
losses--as dangerous. They would demand the bank pay an increased
interest rate if such an affiliation were undertaken. Moreover, if the
affiliated commercial firm's riskiness increased, the bank's
creditors would impose an additional risk premium to account for the
increased risk of a loss shift. If the risk became large, the increased
premium might be sufficient to cause the holding company to divest either the commercial firm or the bank. The affiliated commercial
firm's creditors would do the same.
Yet there is reason to think that shifts would tend more frequently
to deplete bank resources rather than commercial firm resources. While
creditors of commercial subsidiaries of bank holding companies would
demand higher risk premia for affiliations likely to produce losses that
can be shifted to the commercial affiliate, bank creditors have a
reduced incentive to do so. Many of a bank's creditors--those
holding insured deposits in the bank--would demand no additional
compensation when the bank affiliates with a risky commercial firm. If
losses are shifted to the bank, weakening it, its government-insured
deposits are no less likely to be repaid. Therefore, while the creditors
of commercial affiliates penalize risky combinations, those of banks do
not. Consequently, combinations that could lead to loss shifts toward
banks are likely to be more common than combinations that could produce
loss shifts toward commercial firms.
Note that if bank deposit insurance premia were closely tied to
individual bank riskiness and accounted for the risk of loss shifts,
higher premia would discourage affiliations that could be risky to
banks. As discussed in more detail below, observers typically argue that
deposit insurance premia are not closely tied to bank risk.
Loss Shifts that Take Advantage of Limited Liability
While the previous section discusses a set of incentives that could
lead a bank holding company to shift losses from a less capitalized
subsidiary to a more capitalized one, another set of incentives can
produce the opposite result. Under certain circumstances, by shifting
losses from a more capitalized subsidiary to a less capitalized one, the
bank holding company can reduce losses. The strategy, discussed below,
is beneficial because of the protections offered shareholders by the
principle of limited liability. In some cases it could work to the
detriment of the FDIC, and ultimately, to the detriment of taxpayers. As
in the case of reputation-protecting shifts, shifts that take advantage
of limited liability seem at first to be just as likely to enhance bank
safety as diminish it, suggesting that this argument cannot be used as a
justification for maintaining the separation between banking and
commerce. On further analysis, however, it is clear that limited
liability shifts would more likely work to the detriment of banks and
therefore to the detriment of the FDIC and taxpayers. Therefore,
maintaining the banking/commerce wall might be justified as a means of
preventing these shifts.
The following example shows that with limited liability, a bank
holding company can avoid losses if it shifts them. Suppose a holding
company--Alpha Conglomerate Inc.--owns two subsidiaries, Bravo Dry
Cleaners and Echo National Bank. Bravo has a net worth of $100 million,
while Echo's net worth is $5 million. Alpha's only assets are
its investments in the stock of Bravo and Echo, and it is the sole owner
of both. Consequently, Alpha's net worth is $105 million, the sum
of Bravo's and Echo's net worth. If Bravo suffers a $10
million loss (say it has bankrupt commercial customers to which it has
made $10 million in loans), Bravo's net worth falls to $90 million.
Also as a consequence of Bravo's loss, Alpha's stockholders
suffer a $10 million loss since Alpha's net worth falls to $95
million (the sum of Bravo's $90 million net worth and Echo's
$5 million).
Suppose instead that Alpha could arrange to have Echo take the
loss. Echo could take the loss by purchasing the loans made to
Bravo's bankrupt commercial customers for $10 million, even though
the loans are worthless. (9) The shift of the $10 million loss to Echo,
which had only $5 million in net worth before the shift, drives it into
insolvency. Bravo has a net worth of $100 million after the shift, and
Echo has a net worth of negative $5 million. Based on the principle of
limited liability of shareholders, however, Alpha can suffer a loss of
no more than its investment in Echo, or $5 million. The shift has saved
Alpha's shareholders $5 million. In this case the FDIC, which
insures Echo, suffers the remaining $5 million loss. In summary, a
holding company can benefit by shifting a loss when that loss is smaller
than the loss-producing subsidiary's capital, but greater than the
other subsidiary's capital.
Alpha's incentive to protect its reputation, as discussed in
the previous section, will tend to work to prevent it from employing a
shift that will produce an insolvency. Echo's insolvency is certain
to damage Alpha's reputation and raise its future borrowing costs.
Further, such shifts could be illegal. Nevertheless, when the benefit
from shifting losses is large, the shift might be undertaken regardless
of reputation or legality.
While this incentive to shift losses could endanger bank health,
and in fact such a shift led to a bank failure in 1953, holding
companies owning bank and commercial affiliates initially seem no more
likely to shift losses into banks than away from them. (10) In other
words, combinations of banking and commerce are just as likely to
enhance bank safety as reduce it. However, there is a greater chance
that shifts will work against banks; for while banks' major
creditors--insured depositors--are largely indifferent about the risks
that affiliations with nonbanks might impose, commercial
affiliates' creditors are very interested. Creditors of commercial
affiliates will penalize, with demands of higher interest rates,
affiliations that increase the likelihood of an affiliate failure.
Since commercial firm losses tend to be shifted toward banks,
undermining bank health, banking/commerce affiliations increase the
likelihood of FDIC payouts and ultimately of taxpayer bailouts of the
FDIC. Consequently, a limited liability motive for loss shifts could
provide a reason to favor prohibiting banking/commerce combinations.
Beyond the cost to the FDIC and perhaps to taxpayers, who provide
the backstop for FDIC insurance, there is an additional cost of loss
shifts (motivated by limited liability as well as reputation
protection). If creditors of bank-affiliated commercial firms believe
that these firms' losses can be shifted to banks and ultimately to
the FDIC, then creditors will charge bank-affiliated commercial firms
lower interest rates than they would absent the perceived ability to
shift. As a result of this reduced cost of capital, affiliated firms
would regard projects as viable that without this taxpayer-provided
subsidy would be unprofitable. In sum, too much investment capital would
flow to affiliated firms, and the economy's resources would be
wasted. (11) This potential for resource waste may provide further
reason to prohibit banking/commerce combinations, or at least to
regulate combined firms to discourage shifts.
Risk Shifts
At first blush there appears to be one additional reason to
maintain the separation between banking and commerce: combinations would
allow risky assets to be shifted from the commercial firm to the bank.
Doing so increases the bank's riskiness, putting taxpayer funds at
risk. This possibility has caused some observers to raise concerns about
affiliations between banks and nonbanks. As a justification for
maintaining the banking/commerce separation, however, the argument is
unconvincing.
To lower its total funding costs, a bank holding company with a
commercial subsidiary can shift the commercial firm's riskiest
assets to the bank. The commercial firm must borrow using uninsured
debt, while the bank can gather funds by issuing insured deposits. As a
result, funding costs are lowered and holding company profits are
increased when the commercial firm's riskiest assets are shifted to
the bank. (Note that risk shifts differ from loss shifts, discussed
earlier. Loss shifts occur when the bank purchases the assets from the
commercial firm at a price that produces a loss for the bank. Risk
shifts occur when the bank pays a price that produces no loss for the
bank, since it is insensitive to risk.) For banks' costs to be less
sensitive, deposit insurance premia and other supervisor-imposed costs
must be imperfectly sensitive to bank riskiness. Observers argue that
this could be the case for many banks. (12)
Risk shifts, however, do not justify the banking/commerce wall
because affiliation creates no more incentive to shift risks than would
exist without affiliation. If the penalty for holding risky assets is
lower for banks than for commercial firms (or, for that matter, for any
uninsured firm), then risky assets would flow into banks even if they
have no affiliates. Banks would be willing to pay more for risky assets
than would other firms and would bid them away from others.
For example, imagine that a commercial firm, Juliet Tool and Die,
Inc., is currently paying its creditors 15 percent in annual interest
payments to raise $100,000. It uses this $100,000 to make trade credit
(i.e., a loan from a seller to its customer used by the customer to
purchase the seller's goods) available to its customer, Kilo Millwork. Juliet's creditors charge this high rate because they
view Kilo as risky, such that Juliet's loan to Kilo heightens the
chance that Juliet will itself fall; in other words, the trade credit is
a risky asset. Alternatively, Lima National Bank, which pays depositors
only 10 percent, can raise the $100,000 from depositors with which it
can provide funds to Kilo. Because of FDIC insurance, its depositors
care little about the riskiness of Lima's assets. In such a case,
Lima National can be expected to approach Juliet and offer to buy its
asset, the trade credit to Kilo. Lima would be willing to pay more than
the asset is worth to Juliet since Lima can fund the asset less ex
pensively than can Juliet. (13)
A holding company with a bank subsidiary and a commercial
subsidiary may well benefit from having its commercial firm sell its
risky assets to the bank subsidiary because of underpriced deposit
insurance. But a commercial firm with no affiliated bank would find that
banks would want to buy their risky assets just as well. So, if deposit
insurance is underpriced, whereby it is less expensive for banks than
for commercial firms to hold risky assets, preventing affiliation would
not prevent risky assets from being shifted to banks.
3. PROTECTIONS NEEDED IF THE WALL COMES DOWN
The previous section describes the hazard from corporate
combinations between banks and commercial firms, and argues that the
pertinent hazards arise from (1) loss shifts to protect bank holding
company reputation, that is, shifts meant to hide the loss; and (2) loss
shifts that take advantage of limited liability, allowing shareholders
to avoid the loss by imposing them instead on creditors or on the FDIC.
In either case, economic efficiency can be diminished and the loss can
end up with taxpayers. One means of addressing the hazards is to
prohibit banking/commerce combinations; in other words, maintain the
legislative status quo. Alternatively, legislators may decide that the
benefits of combinations are worth bearing some danger of loss shifts.
If legislators took this latter view, what types of protections could
they employ to reduce the frequency of loss shifts into banks and
thereby possibly to the FDIC or taxpayers? Already in place are the
firewalls established by Sections 23A and 23B of the Federal R eserve
Act. These statutory provisions limit transactions between banks and
their affiliates. The firewalls are enforced by regular (once every year
or year and a halt) supervisory examination and by the threat of penalty
if violations are discovered.
Beyond these current protections, which apply to any affiliations,
including any commercial affiliations that might be allowed in the
future, supervisors might wish to mimic the types of limitations
uninsured creditors would impose on risky affiliations. As noted
earlier, one can expect uninsured creditors to penalize the firm they
fund (their debtor) and thereby potentially prevent an affiliation that
would tend to lend itself to loss shifts. If supervisors are to mimic
creditors' actions, they will restrict the types of firms that
banks can affiliate with to those least likely to produce loss shifts in
the first place. In other words, supervisors would only allow banks to
affiliate with healthy commercial firms possessing strong capital at the
time of affiliation.
While at the time of acquisition a new commercial affiliate may be
strong, its health could deteriorate or it could take on undue risks. If
uninsured creditors find that their debtor's affiliates are
suffering losses or assuming risky endeavors, thereby increasing the
chance of losses that might be shifted to their debtor, they would
demand higher interest payments to compensate for their added risk. So
creditors can be expected to monitor carefully the health of their
debtor's affiliates. The Federal Reserve mimics private creditors
by performing such monitoring (called umbrella supervision by the Fed)
of holding companies owning a bank and a securities or insurance
company, under provisions specified in the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of
1999. Umbrella oversight might well be desirable for combinations of
banks with commercial firms, but could be more difficult than umbrella
oversight of financial firms, for reasons discussed presently. If
monitoring reveals that the bank's commercial affiliate has
increased its risk, supervisors could impose a monetary cost on the bank
through the current mechanism by which insurance premia are set.
Because umbrella oversight of commercial firms may be more
difficult than oversight of financial firms, any legislation that might
remove the wall could add additional protections beyond those found in
the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act. For example, such legislation could also
limit the size of commercial affiliates to those no larger than a
fraction of the size of the bank. Such a limit could be beneficial
because as noted in an earlier section, shifts large enough to sink the
bank are most likely to derive from commercial affiliates that are large
relative to the size of the bank affiliate.
Firewalls
The 23A and 23B firewalls are intended to stop exactly those loss
shifts that present hazards for bank/commercial firm affiliations. Yet
there have been several cases in which shifts have caused bank failures,
regardless of firewalls. Additionally, the firewalls have not been
tested in a period of widespread affiliations involving nonbanks large
enough to produce dangerous losses. Consequently, while in principle
firewalls should prevent loss shifts, supervisors will probably wish to
take further protective steps if the banking/commerce wall is removed.
Since 1933, banks have been protected against shifts of losses from
affiliates by firewalls. Firewalls are found in Sections 23A and 23B of
the Federal Reserve Act and apply to all banks. (14) They limit and
place controls on transactions between banks and their affiliates. (15)
For example, the 23A firewalls limit transactions, such as loans and
asset purchases, between a bank and any individual affiliate to 10
percent of the bank's capital, and with all of its affiliates in
total to 20 percent of the bank's capital. The firewalls operate
only in one direction--they prevent transactions that might shift
affiliate losses to the bank, but do not prevent transactions that might
shift bank losses to affiliates. For instance, the firewalls prohibit
loans to affiliates beyond 10 percent of bank capital, but not the
reverse-loans to the bank by affiliates. They also require that
purchases of affiliate assets by the bank be on terms at least as
favorable to the bank as market terms. In contrast, the nonbank affiliat
e can purchase assets from the bank on terms unfavorable to the
affiliate. Penalties for firewall violations can be quite severe,
extending to significant monetary penalties imposed on banks and their
managers and directors.
Bank failures caused by the shifts that firewalls were designed to
prevent have been infrequent, but there were at least two, one of which
was quite large. The 1955 Senate Report on the Bank Holding Company Act
noted that "no widespread abuse of this nature [loss shifts] has
been brought to the attention of [Congress]" (U.S. Code:
Congressional and Administrative News [1956, 2486]). The House Report on
the Act did discuss one case, that of the 1953 failure of First State
Bank of Elmwood Park, Illinois, which resulted from shifts of bad loans
from a nonbank loan company to its affiliate bank--apparently to take
advantage of limited liability protections (U.S. House [1955, 18-19]).
(16) Similarly, a 1983 study of the causes of bank failures for the
previous ten years found only one case out of 120 failures caused by
transactions between a bank and its nonbank affiliates. Still, this
case, the failure of Chattanooga-based, $461 million Hamilton National
Bank in 1976, was the third largest in U.S. history up to t hat time
(Walter [1996, 23]).
Historically, then, firewalls have proven less than perfectly
impervious. Further, until recently, affiliations were quite limited,
offering few opportunities to put the firewalls to the test. Bank
holding companies were, for the most part, restricted to owning nonbank
financial firms that conducted activities that were similar to banking.
Until the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act was enacted in 1999, banking companies
were prohibited from broad securities and insurance powers. Because of
the limitations on the types of nonbank firms that bank holding
companies could own, nonbanks have typically been much smaller than
their bank affiliates. Since they were smaller, they were unlikely to be
capable of producing losses large enough to sink affiliated banks.
Due Diligence prior to Affiliation
Since the effectiveness of firewalls is uncertain, care must be
taken to ensure that bank holding companies do not acquire especially
risky nonbanks. Currently, supervisors evaluate the nonbank's
financial health as part of their review of applications from bank
holding companies to acquire nonbanks. (17) They conduct analyses
similar to due diligence analyses performed by investment companies for
unregulated acquirers. Supervisors look for many of the same signals of
problems that a creditor would, such as excessive debt and weak earnings
performance. Similar analyses would be necessary for bank holding
company acquisitions of commercial firms, should the wall come down.
Still, it might seem that such analysis of commercial firms would
be expensive for bank supervisors, requiring the development of a very
different skill set. Bank supervisors who specialize in application
review are experienced in examining the health of financial firms, not
of commercial firms. Yet other supervisory employees--those who review
banks' loans for their repayment prospects--are practiced in
analyzing commercial firms, since most large bank loans go to such
firms. Today's bank examiners also engage in industrywide analysis
as part of their review of syndicated lending to large commercial firms.
Therefore, these skills might be brought to bear fairly cheaply.
Under current procedures, if the supervisory review of the firm to
be acquired turns up potential risks, the supervisor can deny the
application or require that the risk be ameliorated. An application
review of acquisitions of commercial firms would likely include the same
options.
Beyond these procedures, supervisors might add another requirement,
because analyses of commercial firms could be more difficult than
analyses of financial firms. Shifts of losses large enough to sink the
bank and take advantage of limited liability are most likely to occur
when the commercial firm is large relative to its bank affiliate.
Consequently, supervisors might also limit the size of commercial firms
acquired to a fraction of the size of affiliated banks. Doing so would
reduce the chance of bank-sinking or bank-endangering loss shifts. Such
a requirement is not unprecedented, as relative size limits were imposed
on bank holding company merchant-banking acquisitions under provisions
of Gramm-Leach-Bliley.
Umbrella Supervision
While careful analysis of potential affiliates might prevent bank
holding companies from purchasing troubled or initially risky commercial
firms, problems at a commercial firm could arise well after its
acquisition. Because of concern for this possibility, supervisors may
wish to maintain ongoing oversight of the health of banks'
commercial affiliates. The aim of such oversight is to determine whether
the commercial affiliate has suffered losses or is expanding its
riskiness. If supervisors find losses or heightened riskiness of
commercial affiliates, they could indirectly impose a monetary penalty
on the bank by lowering its supervisory rating. All banks are graded by
supervisors on their financial health, riskiness, and management
expertise. When a bank's grade (supervisory rating) declines, its
insurance premiums can rise. Beyond this monetary penalty, when
commercial affiliates suffer losses or increases in riskiness,
supervisors might also watch more carefully for loss shifts (i.e.,
firewall violations). Further, they might even prohibit all transactions
between the bank and its troubled commercial affiliate. In doing so, the
supervisor mimics the monitoring that bank creditors would be expected
to perform in the absence of deposit insurance.
Oversight of this sort currently occurs under provisions of the
Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, which make the Fed the umbrella supervisor of
all financial holding companies. In this role, the Fed is to ensure that
problems in a securities or insurance affiliate do not endanger the
bank. For, information on the health of securities and insurance
affiliates, the Fed relies on financial reports from the Securities and
Exchange Commission and state insurance commissioners. In some cases the
Fed will participate in examinations of insurance companies performed by
insurance commissioners. One main point of its umbrella oversight is to
ensure that bank resources are not being shifted to nonbank affiliates.
In the extreme, the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act gives the Fed the authority
to require that nonbank affiliates are divested. Divestiture provides
the ultimate prohibition on loss-shifting transactions.
Umbrella oversight of commercial firms may be more difficult than
oversight of securities and insurance firms. Securities and insurance
firms already face strict regulation by agencies with long-standing
experience as supervisors. Moreover, insurance companies receive regular
examinations for financial health. Most commercial firms are less
regulated and are not subject to examination by governmental
supervisors. Developing such processes for commercial firms affiliated
with banks could be quite expensive for an umbrella supervisor of
combined bank/commercial firms and could impose large regulatory costs
on the combined firms themselves.
Nevertheless, public firms--those whose securities trade in public
markets--must release a great deal of financial information. Such
information could provide much of the data necessary to judge financial
health. While publicly available information may be less accurate and
complete than that typically available to bank regulators, who have the
power to require the release of any additional information they may deem
useful, it is the set of information private investors rely upon when
deciding whether to invest. (18) Therefore, for unregulated commercial
firms, umbrella supervisors could rely upon publicly available
information to a significant extent. Additionally, in passing the
Sarbanes-Oxley Act, enacted in July 2002, legislators attempted to
enhance the reliability of disclosures made by publicly traded
companies.
4. CONCLUSION
Clearly, firms benefit from combinations of commercial and
financial units, since for years they have chosen to mix them. Yet many
experts have maintained that banking and commerce should remain
separate. Two predominant reasons for maintaining the separation are
concerns with conflicts of interest and the proliferation of monopoly.
The most credible reason--indeed, one that poses a significant hazard
from combining banking with commerce--is that such affiliations could
provide, at least under certain circumstances, incentives for loss
shifts. While it turns out those circumstances are somewhat limited,
they are not inconsequential.
Loss shifts can impose costs on taxpayers and waste resources. If
losses are shifted from commercial firms to affiliated banks,
taxpayer-funded bailouts may result. If creditors become convinced that
firms affiliated with banks can shift losses to insured banks, then
these firms will enjoy below-market borrowing costs. Below-market
funding means that too many resources will flow to bank-affiliated
firms. If so, productivity and financial market efficiency are
diminished; in other words, scarce resources are wasted.
Nonetheless, since the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of 1999 allowed
securities and insurance firms to affiliate with banks, potentially
producing the same loss shifts that commercial affiliation might
engender, why not also allow commercial affiliations? One reason that
legislators might prefer hot to open that door is that commercial firms
are largely unregulated so the demands on supervisory resources are
likely greater when protecting against shifts from largely unregulated
commercial firms.
On the other hand, if legislators decide that the benefits of
banking/commerce combinations could outweigh the hazards, what means of
protection might they employ to minimize them? Several come to mind,
including (1) careful analysis of the financial condition of commercial
firms that bank holding companies wish to acquire, prior to acquisition;
(2) the maintenance of firewalls to prevent loss shifts; and (3)
umbrella supervision to provide the means of reducing the hazard. In
addition to these means, the requirement that commercial firms be
significantly smaller than any banks they affiliate with offers further
protection. Size limits are likely to be valuable since a commercial
firm is unlikely to produce a loss large enough to threaten a much
larger bank affiliate.
APPENDIX: BACKGROUND ON THE STATUTES FORMING THE WALL
National Bank Act of 1864
The National Bank Act restricts the opportunities for national
banks to undertake commercial activities. National banks are those
chartered and regulated by the U.S. Treasury Department's Office of
the Comptroller of the Currency. The Act states that "a national
banking association shall.., have power to... exercise... all such
incidental powers as shall be necessary to carry on the business of
banking; by discounting and negotiating promissory notes, drafts, bills
of exchange, and other evidences of debt; by receiving deposits; by
buying and selling exchange, coin, and bullion; by loaning money on
personal security" (12 U.S.C. 24). While courts and the Comptroller
have, over the years, wrangled over the meaning of the business of
banking clause, courts have generally taken a fairly conservative view
of activities that might qualify. As decided in an influential court
ruling, for example, banks are generally limited to conducting
businesses that are functionally interchangeable with traditional
banking servic es (M&M Leasing Corp. v. Seattle First National Bank,
563 F.2d 1377, 1383 [9th Cir. 1977] as cited by Halpert [1988, 487]). In
sum, under the Act courts have allowed national banks to engage in
businesses similar to banking but not other commercial activities. This
restriction of powers extends not only to activities of banks, but to
activities conducted by subsidiaries owned by banks (Halpert [1988,
486]). (19)
State Laws and FDICIA
For state-chartered banks, the banking/commerce wall is constructed
of a mix of elements from state laws, the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation Improvement Act of 1991 (FDICIA), and the National Bank Act.
State banking statutes typically set limits on the nonbank activities of
state banks and their subsidiaries similar to the limits on national
banks (Spong [2000, 37-41]). Over the years a number of states have
authorized activities beyond those allowed national banks. Yet state
banks' opportunity to expand further than the activities allowed
under the National Bank Act was largely ruled out by the FDICIA.
Specifically, Section 24 of the Federal Deposit Insurance Act as amended
by the FDICIA prohibits insured state-chartered banks from engaging in
any activities impermissible for national banks unless the FDIC rules
that such activities pose no threat to the deposit insurance fund (sec.
303 of Public Law 102-242).
Bank Holding Company Act
Enacted in May 1956, the Bank Holding Company Act was based on the
view that "bank holding companies ought to confine their activities
to the management and control of banks." Legislators appear to have
been motivated by two concerns. First, that conflicts of interest might
arise if one company owned both a bank and a commercial firm. For
example, such a conflict arises when a bank receives a request for a
loan from one of its commercial affiliate's competitors. Second,
though the legislative history is less clear on this point, legislators
appear to have also been worried that combinations might lead to the
growth of monopoly power.
To address these concerns, the Act restricted bank holding
companies such that they "would no longer be authorized to manage
and control nonbanking assets unrelated to the banking business"
(U.S. Code: Congressional and Administrative News [1956, 2484, 2492]).
At the time the Act was passed, banking companies were growing rapidly
through mergers. In a few cases these companies included nonbanking
businesses. The widest-ranging example was found in Transamerica
Corporation. It combined in one firm, banking, insurance, and a
relatively small amount (as a percentage of Transamerica's total
assets) of metals manufacturing and fish processing (Halpert [1988,
498]).
The Act required that companies wishing to purchase a bank first
seek approval from the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Further, the Act prohibited the Board from approving purchases by
companies engaged in activities that were not closely related to
banking, thereby prohibiting commercial companies such as manufacturers
from purchasing banks. Commercial firms like Transamerica that owned
banks were given several years in which to divest either the bank or
alternatively their commercial activities. Through the next forty years
the Board developed a list of activities that would be considered
closely related, excluding activities most observers would consider
commercial.
In 1999, the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act was enacted. It added
securities underwriting and dealing as well as insurance to the list of
activities in which banks--through bank-owned subsidiaries--and bank
holding companies could engage. Until that time, banks and their
subsidiaries and bank holding companies had been prohibited from the
securities business by the 1933 Glass-Steagall Act. (20) Insurance
activities were likewise highly restricted before Gramm-Leach-Bliley by
the Bank Holding Company Act and other laws.
The Glass-Steagall Act's separation of securities activities
from banking was driven by legislators' concerns over conflicts of
interest, excessive stock market speculation by bank-owned securities
firms, and threats to the health of banks from securities activities.
Likewise the Bank Holding Company Act's separation of banking and
insurance was part of that law's general separation of banking from
nonbank activities, driven by concerns over conflicts of interest and
monopoly power. By the time the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act was passed,
legislators and other observers had various reasons for removing the
walls that separated banks from securities and insurance activities.
These reasons fall into three categories. First, there is little
evidence of conflicts of interest or other problems when banks were
combined with nonbank firms. Second, market developments, such as
growing competition in banking markets, had rendered these problems less
important by the 1990s. Third, the concerns could be dealt with
effectively by regulating the combined firms.
Ultimately, the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act specified that only healthy,
fairly low-risk bank holding companies were to be allowed to undertake
this broader array of financial activities. Those that do so are called
financial holding companies. Further, the Act allows these new financial
holding companies to engage in merchant banking, whereby under certain
conditions financial holding companies may purchase the equity of (in
other words, become owners of) any type of corporation, commercial or
otherwise. Financial holding companies' merchant banking
subsidiaries are restricted to holding the equity of firms for a limited
period of time and are prohibited from active management of the firms.
Beyond securities and insurance, Gramm-Leach-Bliley allows the Board of
Governors, in conjunction with the Treasury Department, to also
authorize financial holding companies to undertake additional activities
that are "financial in nature" or "incidental to
financial activities." It also authorizes the Board to approve
activit ies that are "complementary to a financial activity."
So the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act expands the activities of bank-owning
companies beyond those previously allowed by the Bank Holding Company
Act to include most financial activities, but leaves in place the wall
between banking and commerce.
Loopholes in the Bank Holding Company Act Section of the Wall
Loopholes have been employed to allow banking/commerce
combinations, at least to a limited extent. The unitary thrift loophole,
closed by the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act in 1999, was one such opening.
Through it, companies owning only one thrift (thus the phrase unitary
thrift) could also own commercial firms. The loophole existed because
thrift institutions (meaning primarily savings and loans, and savings
banks) are not covered by the Bank Holding Company Act, which prevents
banking/commerce ties. Instead, thrifts are regulated under the Savings
and Loan Holding Company Amendments of 1967, which allow commercial
activities in unitary thrift holding companies (Seidman [1998, 7]).
Gramm-Leach-Bliley closed the loophole though it grandfathered existing
unitary thrift holding companies, allowing them to continue to engage in
commercial activities.
An additional loophole was partially closed in 1987, but remains
open to a limited degree. Before 1987, the Bank Holding Company Act
defined a bank as a firm that both offered demand deposits (a type of
checking account) and made commercial loans. This definition prevented
commercial firms from owning a typical bank, which offers both demand
deposits and commercial loans. Nevertheless, commercial firms could form
a bank that did not offer one or the other. By doing so, commercial
firms could own banks that did not fall within the Bank Holding Company
Act definition of a bank and could circumvent the Act's prohibition
of mixing banking and commerce. These banks, known as nonbank banks, did
not fit the Act's definition of a bank but did offer most banking
services. A number of firms established nonbank banks, both as a means
of combining banking and commerce and as a means of banking across state
lines, which was difficult until the 1990s. In 1987, Congress closed the
loophole by tightening the definition, but allowed states with existing
laws authorizing the chartering of industrial loan corporations (a type
of nonbank bank that funds itself with insured deposits but does not
offer demand deposits) to continue to charter these ILCs. Several states
had such laws as of 1987. This option remains in force as a means of
combining banking and commerce in these states.
The author benefited greatly from discussions with Kartik Athreya,
Tom Humphrey, Ray Owens, and John weinberg. The views expressed herein
are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the
Federal Reserve System.
(1.) The Bank Holding company Act of 1956 applied only to companies
owning two or more banks. Amendments enacted in 1970 extended the
Act's provisions to single-bank holding companies.
(2.) For discussions of these three reasons for maintaining the
wall, see Krainer (2000, 21-23); Halpert (1988, 490-517); and U.S. GAO
(1987, 11-12).
(3.) Owens (1994) makes this argument for bank lending in real
estate.
(4.) For discussions of the argument that access to bank funding
could give bank affiliates an advantage, see Board of Governors (1987,
500) and Macey and Miller (1992, 377).
(5.) See Weinberg (1996) for a review of bank anti-tying statutes
and the economics of tying. See Kramer (2000, 22) for a discussion of
banks denying credit to their commercial affiliates competitors. In 1997
the U.S. General Accounting Office analyzed banks for evidence of tying
bank loans to securities activities. It found little evidence of any
such tying (U.S. GAO [1997]).
(6.) Board of Governors (1974, 519) (italics added for emphasis).
For a similar argument on another application, see Board of Governors
(1981, 451), as cited in Halpert (1988).
(7.) Halpert (1988, 500-505) discusses the argument that banking
monopoly might proliferate into nonbank businesses.
(8.) Morgan (2000) finds that banks and insurance companies are
inherently more opaque than other firms. Morgan checks for opaqueness of
banks and insurance firms versus nonfinancial firms by measuring the
frequency of disagreements between the two major ratings agencies in
their ratings of banks, insurance companies, and other firms. He finds
that the two agencies disagree more frequently over banks (and over
insurance companies) than over commercial firms. Morgan contends that
the cause of the disagreement is the difficulty of evaluating opaque
bank balance sheets.
(9.) As will be discussed presently, federal law restricts a
bank's ability to purchase loans made by its affiliates to a small
percentage of the bank's net worth. Purchases of sufficient
affiliate loans that lead to the bank's insolvency would be illegal
under the restrictions. Nevertheless, in some cases, such purchases have
occurred.
(10.) See Walter (1996, 22) for a discussion of the case in 1953 in
which a bank failure resulted from shifts from a bank holding
company's nonbank subsidiary to its bank subsidiary, apparently
motivated by an attempt to take advantage of limited liability.
(11.) See Walter and Weinberg (2002, 373-75) for a more complete
discussion of the economic costs of government subsidization of private
firms' borrowing costs.
(12.) See Walter (1998, 2-9) for a discussion of the means by which
banks can receive risk-insensitive funding
(13.) Lima would only be willing to pay more for the loan than it
is worth to Juliet if Lima's deposit insurance premia do not
completely account for the risk the loan adds. Still, as already noted,
for many banks, insurance premia may not accurately reflect their
riskiness.
(14.) More specifically, Sections 23A and 23B apply to all insured
banks and savings institutions. They are found at 12 U.S.C. 371c and 12
U.S.C. 371c-1, respectively.
(15.) See Walter (1996) for a discussion of firewalls.
(16.) See FDIC (1953, 7-8) for details of the First State Bank case
beyond those provided in the House Report.
(17.) The Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of 1999 allows financial holding
companies to dispense with applying for supervisors' approval of
many nonbank acquisitions. Financial holding companies simply notify
supervisors of the acquisition, within 30 days of the acquisition (Spong
[2000, 157]). Therefore, acquisitions of nonbanks by financial holding
companies often do not involve a preacquisition review of the
nonbank's financial health. For acquisitions by bank holding
companies that have not chosen, under rules specified by
Gramm-Leach-Bliley, to become financial holding companies, such reviews
still occur.
(18.) Of course, if private investors believe losses suffered by
their bank-affiliated commercial firms can be shifted, then they have
less reason to demand accurate accounting information.
(19.) Halpert (1988, 497) argues that it was of minor significance
to Congress whether banks engaged in nonbank activities when writing
this language of the National Banking Act. He maintains that congress
"never affirmatively required banks to stay out of nonbanking
business," but "[r]ather, subsequent interpretations of the
statute by comptrollers of the currency and various courts provided its
restrictive Cast."
(20.) Bank holding companies began to engage in limited securities
activities starting in 1987 through a loophole in Glass-Steagall.
REFERENCES
Bank Holding Company Act. 1956. U.s. Code. Title 12, sec. 1843c.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 1974. "Order
Denying Investment in Allstate International S.A., Zurich,
Switzerland." Federal Reserve Bulletin 60 (July): 517-19.
-----. 1981. "Order Approving Proposed Bookkeeping and Data
Processing Activities and Denying Proposed Finance, Loan Servicing,
Leasing and Insurance Activities." Federal Reserve Bulletin 67
(May): 449-51.
-----. 1987. "Order Approving Applications to Engage in
Limited Underwriting and Dealing in Certain Securities." Federal
Reserve Bulletin 73 (June): 473-508.
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). 1953. Annual Report.
Washington, D.C.: FDIC.
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA).
1991. U.S. Public Law 102-242, sec. 303. 102nd Cong., 1st sess.
Federal Reserve Act. 1913. U.S. Code. Title 12, secs. 371c, 371c-1.
Halpert, Stephen K. 1988. "The Separation of Banking and
Commerce Reconsidered." Journal of Corporation Law 13 (Winter):
481-533.
Krainer, John. 2000. "The Separation of Banking and
Commerce." Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review:
15-25.
Macey, Jonathan R., and Geoffrey P. Miller. 1992. Banking Law and
Regulation. Boston: Little, Brown and Company.
Morgan, Donald P. 2000. "Rating Banks: Risk and Uncertainty in
an Opaque Industry." Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report
105 (April).
National Bank Act. 1864. U.S. Code. Title 12, sec. 24.
Owens, Raymond E. 1994. "Commercial Real Estate Overbuilding
in the 1980s: Beyond the Hog Cycle." Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Working Paper 94-6 (May).
Seidman, Ellen. 1998. Statement on Financial Modernization before
the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs. U.S. Senate. 105th
Cong., 2nd sess. 25 June.
Spong, Kenneth. 2000. Banking Regulation: Its Purposes,
Implementation, and Effects, 5th ed. Kansas City, Mo.: Federal Reserve
Bank.
U.S. Code: Congressional and Administrative News. 1956. St. Paul,
Minn.: West Publishing Company.
U.S. General Accounting Office. 1987. "Bank Powers: Insulating
Banks from the Potential Risks of Expanded Activities." Washington,
D.C.: U.S. GAO. April.
----------. 1997. "Bank Oversight: Few Cases of Tying Have
Been Detected." Washington, D.C.: U.S. GAO. May.
U.S. House. 1955. Report to Accompany H.R. 6227. 84th Cong., 1st
sess. H.R. 609.
----------.1998. "Can a Safety Net Subsidy Be Contained?"
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 84 (Winter): 1-20.
Walter, John R. "Firewalls." 1996. Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond Economic Quarterly 82 (Fall): 15-39.
Walter, John R., and John A. Weinberg. 2002. "How Large Is the
Federal Financial Safety Net?" The Cato Journal 21 (Winter):
369-93.
Weinberg, John A. 1996. "Tie-in Sales and Banks." Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 82 (Spring): 1-19.