Which price index should a central bank employ?
Webb, Roy H.
In the 1970s the United States experienced inflation rates that
were high relative to any other decade in the nation's peacetime
experience. During that decade the consumer price index doubled, rising
at a 7.4 percent average annual rate. At one point in the early 1980s,
the CPI inflation rate exceeded 14 percent for a full year. When
inflation was that high, the choice of which price index to employ to
calculate inflation was a secondary concern for policymakers. As Figures
1 and 2 will indicate later in this article, commonly used price indexes
gave the same message: inflation in the 1970s and early 1980s was
relatively high.
The situation now is different. At low rates of inflation,
differences among price indexes become more important. While it is
difficult to imagine the difference between 10.0 and 10.5 percent
inflation affecting monetary policy, the difference between 1.0 and 1.5
percent inflation could lead to different policy choices. Yet different
price indexes can easily yield inflation rates that differ by that 50
basis-point magnitude. Thus in this period of low inflation, the choice
of which price index to use has become an important issue for monetary
policy analysis.
This article begins with the premise that a central bank places a
high weight on keeping inflation low. Several central banks have adopted
a formal inflation target by making a public commitment to achieving a
particular goal for inflation, as discussed in Bernanke et al. (1999),
for example. Central banks in other countries, including the United
States, while not setting formal inflation targets, have nonetheless
made it clear that low inflation is an important policy concern.
Based on that premise, this article explores several considerations
that lead to the choice of which price index to employ for setting
monetary policy. Several widely used price indexes are discussed, and
the author presents evidence that favors one particular index.
1. WHICH PRICE INDEX?
First Choices
Several grounds are given that could be used to choose which price
index to employ. As this article progresses, the set of possible choices
will be narrowed until one remains.
Credibility
A central bank seeking to maintain low inflation must at some point
acquire credibility for being willing and able to take the actions
necessary to achieve its goals. As part of a strategy for low inflation,
then, that central bank must also employ a price index that itself has
credibility. That is, the price index should be the result of a
well-grounded statistical program that is not subject to political
manipulation. The United States has many credible price indexes produced
by the Bureau of Labor Statistics and the Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Breadth
The next choice is between a narrow price index, which includes
prices of only a few items, or a broad price index with many items. Some
analysts have advocated a narrow index of prices of a few raw materials
on the grounds that those prices can respond rapidly to changes in
monetary conditions. Well-known examples include commodity price indexes
that have been published by the Commodity Research Bureau and the
Journal of Commerce. An important drawback is that those prices can also
respond rapidly to supply shifts of individual items, and as a result,
movements in the index can reflect relative price changes rather than
general price changes. Thus central banks have long given more
prominence to broad price indexes in their policy deliberations and have
chosen broad price indexes for inflation targets.
Sector
A wide variety of broad price indexes are published, including
producer price indexes, price indexes for GDP and its components, and
consumer price indexes. Looking at the major broadly based indexes, it
is clear that they are highly correlated. Figure 1 shows inflation rates
from two indexes that cover different sets of prices. The GDP price
index covers goods and services produced in the United States, whereas
the price index for personal consumption expenditure (PCEPI) covers
consumer spending in the GDP accounts. Since inflation rates calculated
from those indexes are very similar, the choice can be based on the need
to acquire and maintain credibility with the public. It is probable that
members of the public are more likely to accept a monetary strategy for
low inflation if they can relate it to their everyday experience. Thus a
measure of consumer prices that is believed to be relevant to individual
households would be a natural choice. Consequently, every central bank
that has an explicit inflation target has chosen a measure of consumer
prices.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
2. THE CHOICE BETWEEN TWO CONSUMER INDEXES
In the United States, the best-known measure of consumer prices is
the Consumer Price Index (CPI) (1) published by the Bureau of Labor
Statistics. It has a long track record and is widely used as an
inflation index in government spending and taxing programs as well as in
private contracts. The CPI's credibility has been enhanced by
efforts of its producers to make a wealth of technical information
readily available to the public on the details of constructing the
index. The Bureau of Labor Statistics conducts an active research
program that has helped the index adapt to changes in the economy and
improve over time.
Setting the index apart from similar indexes in most other
countries, the Commissioner of Labor Statistics has made a public
commitment to using economic theory to guide important decisions that
are made in constructing the index (Abraham 1997). Specifically, the
concept of a cost-of-living index is now used as an organizing principle
for making decisions concerning the production of the CPI. A
cost-of-living index can be defined as the minimum expenditure required
in a particular period to attain the same standard of living as was
achieved in a reference period, divided by actual expenditure in the
reference period. Economic theory tells how a cost-of-living index can
be calculated from a consumer's preferences (for example, Diewert
1987), and the resulting index will correctly convert nominal income to
real income. Statistical agencies in other countries have apparently
shied away from employing cost-of-living methodology because it can be
difficult to apply in real-world situations. The alternative, though, is
that indexes constructed without that discipline can be hard to
interpret. For example, the price of owner-occupied housing is the
largest single component, by far, in the CPI; yet the price of
owner-occupied housing is totally omitted in consumer price indexes in
several other countries. That omission could not be defended in a
cost-of-living framework. (2)
Although the cost-of-living concept helps its producers answer
practical questions that arise as the index is produced, the CPI is not
a cost-of-living index. The Bureau of Labor Statistics did not scrap the
existing CPI when it decided to use the cost-of-living index as a
benchmark. Instead, there have been incremental improvements to the
index since then. In comparing the current CPI with an ideal
cost-of-living index, the single most important difference is the
formula that is used to construct the CPI. That formula does not account
for the possibility of consumers responding to changing relative prices
by changing their expenditure patterns. Later in this article there will
be a more detailed discussion of the CPI's formula, and the
appendix contains a numerical example that may help illustrate why the
CPI is not a cost-of-living index.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The CPI thus has many positive attributes. If it were the only
index of consumer prices available, it could be the basis for a
successful monetary strategy aiming for low inflation. However, another
index has some advantages over the CPI. The PCEPI attempts to cover the
prices of all items consumed by residents of the United States. As
Figure 2 indicates, while broad movements in the two indexes are
similar, at times the differences have been substantial.
One source for the differences in Figure 2 is the changing
methodology that has been used in constructing the CPI. The PCEPI uses a
consistent methodology for its entire history; whenever that methodology
has been changed, past numbers were accordingly revised. But values of
the CPI are not changed after being published. (3) Thus in the late
1970s and early 1980s, housing prices were overstated in the CPI, and
inflation rates calculated using the CPI for that period were
consequently overstated (Blinder 1980). (4)
More relevant for current monetary policy, there are other
differences between the two indexes that affect current values of the
indexes. Most important is that while both indexes are weighted averages
of prices, two different formulas are used to calculate those averages.
The CPI, a Laspeyres index, uses weights for individual prices that
represent an item's importance in consumer expenditure at a fixed
point in time (in 2003, the weights were based on average spending in
the years 1999 and 2000). In symbols, the exact formula is
CP[I.sub.t] = [[[summation].sub.i] [q.sub.i,b]
[p.sub.i,t]]/[[[summation].sub.i] [q.sub.i,b] [p.sub.i,t]], (1)
where CP[I.sub.t] is the value of the consumer price index at time
t, [q.sub.i,b] is the quantity of item i consumed in the base period b
(b [not equal to] t), [p.sub.i,t] is the price of item i in period t,
and [p.sub.i,b] is the price of item i in the base period. In contrast,
the PCEPI is a Fisher Ideal index, the geometric average of a Laspeyres
index like the CPI and an index that uses current values of spending for
the weights on prices. In symbols,
PCEP[I.sub.t] = [square root of ([[[[summation].sub.i]
[q.sub.i,t-1] [p.sub.i,t]]/[[[summation].sub.i] [q.sub.i,t-1]
[p.sub.i,t-1]]] [[[summation].sub.i] [q.sub.i,t]
[p.sub.i,t]]/[[[summation].sub.i] [q.sub.i,t] [p.sub.i,t-1]])], (2)
where [q.sub.i,t] is the quantity of item i consumed in period t.
Note that the formula for the PCEPI includes data on current period
quantities [q.sub.i,t] that are omitted from the formula for the CPI.
Also, the PCEPI does not have a fixed base period; instead, the index
values are calculated using data from the current period and the
previous period. Since there is not a designated base period, the index
number for one particular period will be set to 100. The formula in (2)
is then used to link adjacent periods together.
The difference in formulas is important because the CPI does not
routinely allow for changing expenditure patterns in response to
relative price changes. This could be particularly important when
technical progress results in falling prices of goods such as computers,
cellular phones, and television sets. Failure to account for increasing
spending on items with falling prices would create a bias in the index
that would lead it to rise more rapidly than the true cost of living.
The Fisher Ideal index, however, allows for changing expenditure
patterns in a manner that allows it to approximate a cost-of-living
index especially well and is thus known as a superlative index (Diewert
1987). The appendix illustrates the construction of a Laspeyres index
and a Fisher index in a simple case with a large change in the pattern
of expenditure.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
It may seem that the difference in formulas would be an example of
esoteric trivia; however, at low inflation rates, the magnitude of the
difference can be large when compared with the absolute rate of
inflation. In order to focus on the difference between a superlative
index and a Laspeyres index, it is helpful to consider briefly a new
index from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The Chained-CPI (C-CPI) uses
exactly the same price information as the CPI but is based on another
type of superlative index, a Tornquist index. (5) Like the Fisher index,
the Tornquist index includes information on current period quantities
and thereby allows for changing expenditure patterns. Figure 3 shows
inflation rates calculated using the CPI, the C-CPI, and the PCEPI.
There is a noticeable difference between the CPI and the other two
indexes. Over this period (the entire period for which the C-CPI is
available), the average difference between the CPI and C-CPI was 44
basis points, which is entirely attributable to the different formulas.
The average difference between the two superlative indexes was only 5
basis points.
In addition to the different aggregating formulas, the prices and
relative importance of various items can differ between the CPI and
PCEPI. Most of the individual prices in the PCEPI are identical to those
in the CPI. The most notable exception is spending for medical services,
where the PCEPI uses information from producer price indexes. Moreover,
a few items are covered in one index but not another. Also, the relative
importance of a particular item can differ considerably between the two
indexes, since completely different sources of information are used to
determine relative importance. The PCEPI uses information to construct
GDP, such as economic census data and industry trade data. The CPI uses
information from periodic Consumer Expenditure Surveys. Some analysts
(such as Lebow and Rudd 2001) have viewed the weights in the PCEPI as
likely to be more accurate. In the survey data used for the CPI, a
member of a household is asked to give information on spending of all
members of the household. If items accounting for a small portion of
spending tend to be missed or forgotten in the household survey, then
the fraction of spending for big-ticket items would tend to be biased
upward. Not surprisingly, then, owner-occupied housing has a much larger
weight in the CPI than in the PCEPI. To quantify the effect of different
weights, Lebow and Rudd compared the published CPI with an alternative
CPI using PCE weights. From 1987 to 2000, the average inflation rate was
10 basis points lower when using the PCE weights.
Accordingly, due to the clearly superior formula for computing the
index and the probably superior item weights, changes in the PCEPI
should provide a better estimate of the true cost of living.
Limitations of Price Indexes
It is important to consider some limitations of both indexes. In a
dynamic economy, the items available for purchase are constantly
changing, with new items being introduced continuously, some old items
being improved, and other old items disappearing from the market.
Accounting for new items is a challenge for producers of price indexes.
For example, the Boskin Commission Report (1996) noted that although
there were 36 million cellular phones in use at the time of the report,
there was no price of cell phones in the CPI. Compounding the problem is
the typical product cycle, in which a new good initially sells for a
relatively high price, but as economies of scale are realized and new
competitors enter the market, the price falls rapidly before eventually
leveling out. If the price of a new item does not enter a price index
promptly, then the interval of a rapidly falling price can be missed
entirely, and the price index would therefore overstate inflation. Since
the Boskin report was written, the Bureau of Labor Statistics has
reduced--but not eliminated--the time it takes for a new item to enter
the CPI.
A related difficulty is accounting for quality change. If the
greater durability or improved functionality of a product is not taken
into account, then a price index will overstate the cost of living. And
if quality improvements routinely outweigh quality deterioration,
inflation can be overstated. Some detailed studies of particular
products have found that accounting for quality change would have made a
sizeable difference in recorded prices. Based on many of these studies,
the Boskin Commission Report estimated that there was a 60 basis-point
upward bias in CPI inflation rates at that time, due to new products and
quality change. A more recent estimate by Lebow and Rudd puts the bias
at 37 basis points. It should be emphasized that these estimates are
subject to a large amount of imprecision. If it were easy for analysts
to disentangle the portion of price changes that reflect quality change,
it would probably be part of routine price index calculation already. At
this time, improving estimates of quality change is an ongoing challenge
for statistical agencies.
3. CORE INDEXES
A final choice is between the PCEPI and a measure of core
inflation. For purposes of monetary policy, it would not be desirable to
respond to temporary changes in measured inflation that are likely to be
reversed. Thus policy makers in many countries pay particular attention
to a core price index that excludes some items that account for a
significant amount of short-run volatility in the index but do not have
much effect on the long-run trend. For several decades, inflation
analysts in the United States have focused on a core price index that
excludes food and energy prices. As illustrated in Figure 4, the core
PCEPI is less volatile than the overall index; using the core index
reduces the variance of inflation rates in that figure by 31 percent.
Most importantly, the core index omits some significant fluctuations in
the overall index that were soon reversed but could have led to
inappropriate monetary policy actions. For example, the core index did
not decline significantly in 1986 and did not rise significantly in
2002-2003. In 1986, crude oil prices fell sharply and led to lower
retail energy prices. In the latter episode, as energy prices increased
sharply in response to the approach of war in Iraq, the overall index
signaled rising inflation, but the core index signaled low, falling
inflation. Finally, removal of energy and food prices has had a small
effect on the long-run trend. Over the 40-year period illustrated in
Figure 4, the PCEPI increased at a 4.05 percent annual rate, whereas the
core PCE index increased at a 3.95 percent rate.
Most of the countries with full inflation targets have taken a
similar approach and employed a core index that omits a few items.
Besides food and energy prices, several countries omit indirect taxes.
These widely used core indexes were not derived from economic or
statistical theory, but were instead based on the judgment that their
use would result in better choices of monetary policy actions.
Researchers have also examined alternatives that use more elaborate
statistical methods for determining core inflation (see, for example,
the survey by Johnson 1999). At this point, though, this is only
research in progress that has not resulted in a new standard for
determining core inflation. The major hurdle for these studies will be
to demonstrate that using a proposed method would lead to better
monetary policy decisions.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
This point can be illustrated with a particular alternative
estimate of core inflation. A median CPI (Bryan and Cecchetti 1993) is
based on the statistical property that a median is not influenced by
extreme observations, unlike the arithmetic average used for the CPI and
the PCEPI. The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland accordingly calculates
a median CPI as an alternative measure of core inflation and posts
recent and historical values on their web site. Despite that prominence,
however, their median CPI has not supplanted the traditional core index.
Two observations may explain why. First, due to the large weight placed
on housing expenditure in the CPI, the median CPI often simply picks up
the behavior of housing prices, as is illustrated in Figure 5. Thus the
correlation between the 12-month change in the shelter component of the
CPI and the median CPI was 0.90 since 1985 and was even higher before
then. In contrast, the correlation between the nonshelter component of
the CPI and the median CPI was only 0.48 since 1985. Also, note that
from January 2000 to November 2001, the inflation rate calculated from
the median CPI increased from 2.4 to 4.0 percent, which at face value
would indicate an excessively easy monetary policy stance and might
signal the need to raise the federal funds rate target. Over that
period, however, the economy weakened in 2000 and moved into recession
in 2001. Thus it appears that at that time the traditional core price
indexes gave a better guide for monetary policy. Accordingly, the
12-month change in the core PCEPI remained below 2.2 percent in 2000 and
2001.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Although the traditional core index has not been supplanted by an
alternative, there is a strong case for continued research on
alternative measures of core inflation. Given the imperfect nature of
macroeconomic statistics, one should always wonder if any particular
statistic is giving misleading signals, and the core PCEPI is no
exception. Having well-studied alternatives could thus be valuable to
policymakers if at any time the traditional core index were to be in
doubt.
4. CONCLUSION
This article studies which price index to use for determining
monetary policy actions. The best choice for the United States is
currently the core price index for personal consumption expenditure.
From 1996 to the end of 2003, the four-quarter change in that index
remained within a narrow range, 0.9 to 2.1 percent. Like other
macroeconomic statistics, price indexes are not precision tools.
Allowing for about a half percentage point of upward bias in the
reported inflation rate, the true cost of living has been rising very
slowly for several years.
APPENDIX
A numerical example may help clarify the effects of different index
formulas. Assume that there are two goods, apples and bananas, denoted
with superscripts a and b. There are two time periods, 0 and 1. Money
income is y, and utility is u. I assume, [y.sub.0] = $12.00,
[p.sub.0.sup.a] = [p.sub.0.sup.b] = $1 and u = [square root of
([q.sup.a] [q.sup.b])], where p represents a price and q is a quantity.
Given the initial conditions, utility is maximized at a level of 6.0
when 6 apples and 6 bananas are consumed. Using the equations in the
text, both a Laspeyres index L and a Fisher index F will have values of
1.00 in period 0.
Now, let [y.sub.1] = $12.00, [p.sub.1.sup.a] = $1.50,
[p.sub.1.sup.b] = $0.50, and we can ask if real income has risen,
fallen, or remained unchanged. If we divide money income by a
cost-of-living index, the real income rises if and only if utility
rises. Given the utility function and new prices, the optimal quantities
are [q.sub.1.sup.a] = 4 and [q.sub.1.sup.b] = 12, and utility rises to
approximately 6.93. In other words, the price changes have allowed
utility to increase significantly once quantities are allowed to adjust.
Consider first the Laspeyres formula given in equation 1;
substituting the values above gives [L.sub.1] = [6X1.5+6X0.5]/[6X1+6X1]
= 1.00, and, therefore, real income in period 1 is $12.00. Although
utility rose, real income, calculated by using a Laspeyres index, did
not change. Now use the Fisher formula of equation 2: [F.sub.1] =
[square root of ([[6X1.5+6X0.5]/[6X1+6X1]] X
[[4X1.5+12X0.5]/[4X1+12X1]])] = [square root of (3/4)], and real income
is approximately $13.86. Thus the latter index correctly leads to rising
real income with rising utility.
Finally, for comparison we can construct a cost-of-living index. We
can define the value as exactly 1.00 in period 0. The utility function
has the property that utility is maximized when exactly half of income
is spent on each item. Using that knowledge, the minimum expenditure in
period 1 that achieves the utility level of 6 is 3 [square root of 12],
or approximately $10.39, which purchases approximately 3.46 apples and
10.39 bananas. Thus the cost-of-living index for period 1 is [3[square
root of 12]]/12, which in this case is exactly equal to the Fisher
index. In both cases, a utility-maximizing consumer would buy more
bananas, which became less expensive and, correspondingly, fewer apples,
which became more expensive. Both the cost-of-living index and the
Fisher index correctly captured that changing expenditure pattern.
The author gratefully acknowledges helpful comments from Huberto
Ennis, Marvin Good-friend, Andreas Hornstein, and Thomas Humphrey. The
views and opinions expressed in this article are solely those of the
author and should not be attributed to any other person or the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1) Actually two versions of the CPI are published. The CPI-U
covers all urban consumers, whereas the CPI-W covers urban wage and
salary workers. In practice, the two indexes give virtually identical
inflation rates, and thus the two will not be distinguished in the text.
The figures in this article include the CPI-U.
(2) The perennial question of whether to include asset prices in
the CPI can be evaluated in the context of a cost-of-living index. That
approach indicates that the price of services of consumer durables should be in the index and that there are two valid approaches to
estimating the services of consumer durables. One is a Jorgenson (1963)
user-cost formula, and the other estimates an imputed flow of services.
The latter is currently used in the CPI for owner-occupied housing,
which estimates an owner's equivalent rent from rental prices of
similar structures. Importantly, the consumption of the services of a
durable asset is independent of the method of financing the asset's
purchase. That financing decision is thus outside the scope of a
cost-of-living index.
(3) Since the CPI is widely used to index money payments, fixing
previously published values of the index avoids the question of whether
payments that were previously made would need to be recalculated each
time a methodological change was made to the CPI that altered historical
values.
(4) At that time, the CPI attempted to measure an average price of
items purchased by a representative consumer, not the cost of living. It
therefore included the purchase price of owner-occupied housing plus a
measure of mortgage interest rates. By the mid-1980s, after the damage
was done and the index had overstated inflation, the current approach of
pricing the service flow from owner-occupied housing was adopted.
(5) The formula for the Tornquist Index is
[[PI].sub.i]([p.sub.i,t]/[p.sub.i,t-1])[.sup.([[s.sub.i,t-1] +
[s.sub.i,t]]/2)] where [s.sub.i] is the expenditure share of item i,
that is, [[q.sub.i] [p.sub.i]]/[[[summation].sub.j] [q.sub.j]
[p.sub.j]]. Note that current expenditures enter the formula through the
expenditure share term.
REFERENCES
Abraham, Katharine G. 1997. Testimony before the Subcommittee on
Human Resources, House Committee on Government Reform and Oversight,
April 30. Available at
http://www.bls.gov/news.release/cpi.br043097.brief.htm (accessed April
6, 2004).
Bernanke, Ben S., Thomas Laubach, Frederic S. Mishkin, and Adam S.
Posen. 1999. Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the International
Experience. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Blinder, Alan. 1980. "The Consumer Price Index and the
Measurement of Recent Inflation." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 2: 539-65.
Boskin, Michael J., Ellen Dullberger, Robert J. Gordon, Zvi
Griliches, and Dale Jorgenson. 1996. "Toward a More Accurate
Measure of the Cost of Living." Final Report to the Senate Finance
Committee from the Advisory Commission to Study the Consumer Price
Index, December 4. Available at
http://www.ssa.gov/history/reports/boskinrpt.html (accessed April 6,
2004).
Bryan, Michael F., and Stephen G. Cecchetti. 1993. "Measuring
Core Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper
9304.
Diewert, W. E. 1987. "Index Numbers." The New Palgrave: A
Dictionary of Economics. Ed. John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter
Newman. New York: Stockton Press 2: 767-80.
Johnson, Marianne. 1999. "Core Inflation: A Measure of
Inflation for Policy Purposes." Bank for International Settlements
Conference Paper. Available at http://www.bis.org/publ/bisp05_p4.pdf
(accessed April 6, 2004).
Jorgenson, Dale W. 1963. "Capitol Theory and Investment
Behavior." American Economic Review 53 (May): 247-59.
Lebow, David E., and Jeremy B. Rudd. 2001. "Measurement Error
in The Consumer Price Index: Where Do We Stand?" Federal Reserve
Board of Governors, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 2001-61.