Closing troubled banks: how the process works.
Walter, John R.
Business failure typically occurs when a financially weak firm can
no longer pay its creditors. Failure generally involves a series of
steps. First, the firm suffers losses. Second, when the firm's
creditors learn of the losses, they increase their estimate of the
firm's probability of default. To compensate themselves for this
increased risk, creditors demand higher interest rates or require debt
repayment. Third, the firm finds itself unable to raise or generate
additional funds to meet those demands and defaults. Creditors then
either force the firm into bankruptcy, in which case a bankruptcy court decides how to best allocate the firm's assets to meet its debts,
or the firm privately arranges with creditors for a payout of firm
assets. In either case, the assets can be redeployed in more valuable
uses. While business failure is often exceptionally disruptive for the
firm's managers and employees, it is beneficial for society since
it ensures that business resources are not devoted to ineffectual
enterprises.
But what about banks? How does their failure ensue? A high
proportion of bank liabilities are government-insured deposits. Deposit
insurance primarily exists to prevent inappropriate bank runs that may
occur when many of a bank's depositors seek to withdraw funds even
though the bank is healthy. While it solves one problem--inappropriate
runs--deposit insurance can create another. Insured depositors have no
incentive to demand higher interest rates or debt repayment when their
bank is troubled. While uninsured bank creditors will likely demand
repayment, the bank can often raise funds to meet these demands by
gathering new insured deposits at little extra cost. As a result, the
market-driven process of failure and subsequent reallocation of assets
is short-circuited for banks, and its societal benefits are muted.
Because market forces are unlikely to bring about the timely
closure of troubled banks, the government agencies that charter and
supervise banks are typically left to decide when a bank is no longer
viable and should be closed. Mistakes by the agencies can create
significant inefficiencies. For example, during the 1980s many insured
depository institutions remained open long after they became insolvent.
As a result, financial resources were tied up in inefficient operations
for extended periods. Legislators recognized the problem and in 1991
enacted the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act
(FDICIA). The Act required bank supervisors to step in and close
depository institutions more quickly and reformed the process by which
the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation disposed of failed
depositories. All of which raise the crucial question: How do these
agencies decide when to step in under rules established by the FDICIA?
Further, how do the agencies proceed following intervention? This
article seeks to answer these questions.
Supervision of healthy banks is intended to ensure that the
government safety net does not provide incentives for banks to undertake
inefficient risks. Supervision of banks includes propagating and
enforcing restrictions on risky activities, setting deposit insurance
premia and insurance coverage levels, and establishing minimum capital
requirements as well as examining banks to ensure that capital
requirements are met. The supervisory treatment of failing banks,
however, is likewise important if the safety net is to be prevented from
inducing excessively risky behaviors.
This article provides an overview of the process by which troubled
banks are closed. It not only points out the beneficial changes to the
FDICIA's closure process, but also indicates some areas of
remaining weakness. One example involves the opportunities for uninsured
depositors to escape losses by withdrawing their deposits immediately
prior to bank failure. The FDICIA addresses one avenue of escape by
restricting Federal Reserve discount window lending to troubled banks.
As will be shown, even if the Act prevented all such lending, many
uninsured depositors would be likely to escape losses nevertheless.
Likewise, the oft-discussed systemic risk provisions of the FDICIA can
provide incentives for excessive risk-taking.
Creditors of troubled nonbank firms have every incentive to require
their prompt closure and to ensure that the assets of such firms are
redirected. Typically bank supervisors must perform these roles for
troubled banks. The FDICIA attempts to ensure that supervisors have
incentives to close banks promptly and to dispose of their assets
efficiently. This article is intended as an aid to those who would like
to understand and perhaps improve the bank closure process.
1. NONBANK FAILURE VERSUS BANK FAILURE
In broad terms, failure occurs when a firm becomes unable to
produce a market rate of return on its owners' capital investment.
In other words, earnings from operations are insufficient to meet
expenses, including interest payments to debtholders, and to pay owners
a market return. The unproductive firm's assets might simply be
sold off, debts repaid, and the business closed. In such an example,
losses are borne only by owners, with debtholders escaping any loss.
While closure can occur without great losses, frequently firm
closure occurs under less favorable circumstances. Severe losses may
rapidly overwhelm the firm. Alternatively, owners may not realize the
severity of the earnings decline, or they may choose to hold out, hoping
for a recovery. In such a situation losses can become large enough to
consume a significant portion of the firm's assets. Owners are
likely to seek additional funding from lenders or new investors. These
providers will attempt to ascertain the likelihood that the firm can
recover and produce a market return. If a recovery is deemed probable,
perhaps including reorganization, then creditors advance new funds.
Alternatively, if lenders or investors view the firm's troubles as
long-lasting they will be unwilling to lend. The firm then is unable to
meet payment demands from its creditors. These creditors can then force
the closure of the firm in bankruptcy or by foreclosing on its assets.
In some cases, banks may follow the first discussed pattern of
closure. Specifically, bank owners may find that their operation is no
longer producing a market rate of return and that their investment can
earn a higher return employed elsewhere. In such a case, the owners may
simply liquidate the bank. Between 1991 and 2001, 38 banks were
liquidated without the supervisors stepping in and requiring closure
(FDIC 2003). (1) More typically, owners may sell their assets and
liabilities to another bank. While bank supervisors do not classify such
outcomes as failures, these outcomes are driven by the realization by
bank owners that returns are insufficient. So liquidations and some
mergers meet the definition of an economic failure.
Thus, while a bank failure can be similar to the failure of a
nonbank firm so that market players--specifically the bank's
owners--close the bank without supervisory intervention, in general a
bank failure producing losses beyond those suffered by equity holders
will be very different. The reason is that deposit insurance allows a
bank with weak earnings to continue to raise funds sufficient to cover
its losses. Imagine a bank that has suffered a string of losses, such
that it would be clear to outsiders that the bank is unlikely to be able
to repay out of earnings any additional debts it undertakes. A nonbank
firm in such a situation would be unable to convince investors to extend
funds to cover future operations. But depositors, protected against loss
by a government guarantee of repayment, are quite willing to provide the
bank with additional funding. As a result, insured-troubled banks can
frequently remain open long past the time they would be closed absent
deposit insurance.
This distinction between investors' treatment of nonbanks and
depositors' treatment of banks points out why banks are special,
and why bank supervisors must be especially vigilant to quickly close
troubled banks. Once any firm, whether bank or nonbank, suffers losses
great enough to consume all of its owners' investment, its owners
have a strong incentive to undertake very risky investments, since at
that point they have no more investment to lose. Risky investments will
be attractive because they might produce a large enough return to save
the firm. While investors will be unwilling to extend to nonbanks the
funds needed for such risky investments, because of deposit insurance,
banks can gather funding. Consequently, the failure to close a troubled
bank quickly, affords bank owners and managers the ability and incentive
to undertake risky, high-loss investments.
2. WHO LOSES WHEN BANKS FAIL?
When nonbank firms fail, creditors often are not repaid in full and
can suffer large losses as a proportion of their investment. When banks
fail, insured depositors, who provide the largest portion of the typical
banks' liabilities, are protected against losses by the FDIC. Bank
shareholders are not insured by the FDIC and will normally suffer
losses, and uninsured depositors, to be discussed in more detail later,
also may lose.
The FDIC promises to insure deposits up to $100,000 per account.
Backing the promise is the FDIC's reserve fund, which, as of the
end of 2002, summed to $32 billion, or 1.27 percent of all insured
deposits in banks. The fund was accumulated and is maintained from
insurance premiums charged banks and from the interest earned on the
reserves. A separate reserve is maintained by the FDIC for savings
associations. Relative to insured deposits, it is of a similar size to
the bank fund and is also funded by premiums charged these associations.
If the bank reserve fund falls below a specified minimum relative to
insured deposits--1.25 percent of insured deposits--banks are required
to rebuild the fund through higher premiums, as are savings
associations.
But what if payments necessary to protect depositors grow so large
that they deplete the entire fund? In this case the FDIC can draw on a
$30 billion line of credit from the U.S. Treasury, to be repaid by
future premiums. Beyond this amount, taxpayers would make up the
difference. During the savings and loan crisis of the 1980s, the
reserves backing savings association deposit insurance were depleted. In
1987, a statute was enacted promising Treasury backing, and therefore
taxpayer backing, for insured deposits. Over the next several years
taxpayers provided over $100 billion to protect depositors in savings
associations from any losses.
3. WHO CLOSES BANKS?
So, if deposit insurance gives creditors little incentive to
foreclose on a troubled bank or force it into bankruptcy, who does force
its closure? The answer is that a troubled bank is closed by the agency
which granted the bank a charter to operate. The agency appoints an
entity, typically the FDIC, to act as a receiver or conservator. This
entity then takes control of the bank's assets and liabilities and
ultimately divides the assets among liability holders. For national
banks, charters are granted and the closure decision made by the Office
of the Comptroller of the Currency--a bureau of the U.S. Department of
the Treasury--which also supervises national banks. For state-chartered
banks, charters are granted, and supervision is provided, including the
decision to close troubled banks, by an agency of the state government.
Similarly, some savings associations have a federal government-granted
charter and are supervised and closed by the Office of Thrift
Supervision, also a bureau of the Treasury; others have state charters.
In the case of national banks and federally chartered savings
associations, federal law requires that the receiver be the FDIC (12
U.S. Code 1821c). Most states also require their banking agencies to
name the FDIC as receiver (FDIC 1998b, 69).
While state banks are typically placed in receivership by a state
banking agency, in some cases a federal bank supervisor can make the
decision to appoint a receiver for a state-chartered bank. The Federal
Reserve or the FDIC, neither of which grant bank charters, share with
state banking agencies the duty of supervising state-chartered banks,
including the authority, under federal law (discussed below), to appoint
a receiver. The backup authority granted the federal agencies could be
attributed to the fact that only the federal agencies answer to the
federal legislature, which must appropriate the funds to protect
depositors should the reserve funds be depleted. On occasion the FDIC
has used its authority. For example, over the decade from 1993 through
2003, out of a total of 54 state-chartered bank failures, the FDIC
closed three state-chartered banks without the concurrence of the state
banking agency. Such closures can imply a disagreement between the state
agency and the FDIC concerning the severity of the troubled bank's
problems; the state agency concludes that the bank is viable, while the
FDIC concludes that the bank is not.
4. CLOSURE POLICIES
Policy guiding regulators' approach to troubled banks is
established by the Prompt Corrective Action (PCA) rules, found in
Section 131 of the FDICIA. The rules primarily focus on the level of
bank capital, meaning the dollar amount by which assets exceed
liabilities, i.e., the net worth or solvency of the bank. According to the PCA rules, the federal bank regulatory agencies are required to
appoint a receiver or conservator for the bank within 90 days of the
time the bank's capital-to-assets ratio falls below two percent (12
U.S. Code 1831o). In other words, if a bank becomes insolvent, or close
to it, a receiver must be appointed. Alternatively, the federal agencies
can choose another course, such as granting the bank additional time or
injecting funds to prop up the troubled bank, but such a decision must
be reviewed every 90 days until the bank has recovered. After 270 days,
if the bank remains undercapitalized, a receiver must be appointed
unless the bank has positive net worth and its financial health is
clearly improving.
Other provisions of federal law provide additional grounds by which
agencies may step in. For example, a banking agency may appoint a
receiver even though the bank may not currently have weak capital if the
agency determines that the bank is likely to incur losses that will
deplete substantially all of its capital. Outside of capital
considerations, a receiver may be appointed if the bank has willfully violated a cease and desist order (12 U.S. Code 1821c).
5. CLOSURE IN PRACTICE
But how do the state or federal regulators learn of declining
health of banks, and what steps do they typically take on the way to
determining that the bank is no longer viable? Two means are typically
employed by banking agency examiners to measure the health of a bank,
namely off-site monitoring and on-site examination. Off-site monitoring
involves analyzing data assembled both from financial statements
produced by the bank and from information gathered in the most recent
on-site examination. Further, information on local economic conditions,
the health of industries to which the bank lends, and market indicators
of the bank's own well-being are reviewed. For example, the review
may include investigation of local indicators such as bankruptcies,
unemployment, housing prices, and vacancy rates (OCC 2001, 6). The
review typically involves computer programs that tabulate and produce
ratios based on financial data. By providing warning of a bank's
declining health prior to a regularly scheduled on-site examination,
off-site monitoring can point up the need to quickly conduct an on-site
examination. Data from off-site monitoring can also guide examiners to
problem areas during an on-site examination.
In principle, the combination of off-site and on-site reviews will
reveal a bank's condition. However, in practice, declining bank
health is often difficult to assess and involves subjective judgements
by examiners. These judgements must be discussed with bank managers and
directors, who might be unduly optimistic about the bank's
viability. Further, examiner decisions can later be contested in
lawsuits. The difficulties of correctly identifying problems were
illustrated by the 1999 failure of First National Bank of Keystone, West
Virginia. Reportedly, Keystone's management hid the bank's
insolvency from banking agency examiners for an extended period directly
before examiners closed the bank (Office of Inspector General 2000).
When off-site monitoring or initial indicators from an on-site
review raise suspicions that a bank's health may be deteriorating,
on-site examiners focus especially on certain indicators or red flags of
declining health. These red flags include especially rapid asset growth,
risk management deficiencies, asset quality deterioration, liquidity
difficulties, and the bank's unwillingness to cooperate with
examiners (OCC 2001, 3-18). During the on-site review of a bank thought
to be experiencing trouble, special emphasis will be placed on careful
valuation of the bank's assets. For banks that later fail, the
valuation often reveals that the bank was unrealistically optimistic
when valuing assets in its financial statements.
Following the examination of a seriously troubled bank, examiners
will meet with the bank's management and its board of directors,
notifying them of negative findings from the examination. Other
regulators are also typically notified. For example, state bank
examiners are likely to notify the FDIC, or the Federal Reserve if the
bank is a Federal Reserve member bank (since the Fed supervises state
member banks along with state agencies). If the asset valuation proves
that the bank is undercapitalized (capital-to-assets ratio less than 4
percent), and especially if it is found to be critically
undercapitalized (ratio below 2 percent), examiners will inform bank
management and directors, in writing, of the amount of capital that must
be injected to recapitalize the bank. The bank is given the opportunity
to produce a plan to gather the necessary capital, and if critically
undercapitalized, is warned that it will probably have no more than 90
days in which to gather the needed capital. During this meeting with the
bank's board of directors and its management, representatives of
the FDIC may be present. They are there to obtain the board's
authorization for the FDIC to begin seeking bidders for the bank (OCC
2001, 61-62).
If the bank is successful in raising additional capital, it can
continue to operate and avoids closure. On the other hand, if investors
are unwilling to provide the needed equity, the bank will be closed and
placed into receivership.
6. TREATMENT OF CLOSED BANKS
Since the FDIC not only is receiver, but also deposit insurer, its
responsibility surpasses a typical receiver; it must make insured
depositors whole. It does so either by repaying depositors out of its
insurance reserves or, far more frequently, by transferring the deposits
to another bank. The bank that acquires the deposits must be compensated
since deposits are simply liabilities representing future payments to be
made by the bank acquiring the deposits. Such compensation also is drawn
from the FDIC's reserves. The FDIC collects the failed bank's
assets by selling them to a healthy bank or other investor, or by
holding them and collecting them as they mature. The proceeds of the
asset collection are retained by the FDIC, offsetting its insurance
losses, and are used to repay other creditors of the failed bank.
The FDIC as Receiver
The FDIC typically employs one of two techniques when acting as the
receiver for a failing bank: deposit payoff or purchase and assumption.
A deposit payoff involves 1) repaying insured depositors, 2) liquidating
assets of the bank, and 3) dividing the proceeds from asset liquidation between itself and uninsured bank creditors. In a purchase and
assumption transaction "a healthy institution purchases some or all
of the assets of a failed bank ... and assumes some or all of the
liabilities" (FDIC 1998b, 19). When deciding which of these
techniques to employ, the FDIC is guided by the least-cost requirement
of the FDICIA. The requirement states that whenever it is named
receiver, the FDIC must choose the option that was least costly in terms
of the FDIC expenditures. The rule was a prominent feature of the
FDICIA. (2)
The FDIC's Analysis
The FDIC's role begins when a bank chartering agency
determines that the bank is no longer viable and notifies the FDIC. The
FDIC then begins a multistep process generally lasting 90 to 100 days,
but which can proceed much more quickly. While technically the FDIC is
named receiver at the end of the process--on the day the bank is
closed--it begins performing many of the activities one expects of a
receiver long before this date. (3)
Immediately following the agency's notification of the FDIC,
the FDIC performs a careful analysis of the bank's assets and
liabilities to estimate the cost the FDIC will incur implementing a
deposit payoff. The process involves estimating the market value of the
assets. Since there is no secondary market for many loans, the asset
valuation is based in part on likely cash flows, discounted to the
present, minus costs of holding or selling the loans.
The FDIC also determines the amount of insured deposits, since it
is this amount that the FDIC is responsible for repaying. One might
imagine then that if the value of assets is smaller than the value of
insured deposits, the FDIC simply subtracts the market value of assets
from the amount of insured deposits, and the difference is the cost to
the FDIC of a deposit payoff. Instead the calculation is somewhat more
complicated. The FDIC must divide the proceeds of the asset sale between
itself and uninsured depositors. The division is based on the share of
total deposits held by insured and uninsured depositors. For example, if
insured deposits account for 75 percent of total deposits, then the FDIC
receives 75 percent of the ultimate proceeds of collecting the assets.
Uninsured depositors receive 25 percent (Thomson 1994).
If the value of assets exceeds the amount of total deposits, then
the bank's general creditors are next in line to receive payments,
followed by subordinated debt holders. (4) Last in line are equity
holders. Payments to general creditors, subordinated debt holders, and
equity holders only occur if the FDIC and uninsured depositors suffer no
losses. Therefore, payments to these creditors and to equity
shareholders do not raise the FDIC's cost. (5)
Whether a deposit payoff or purchase and assumption is ultimately
chosen, this estimation of the FDIC's cost of deposit payoff gives
the FDIC a required baseline as it prepares to sell the bank. No bids
can be accepted at a price that yields a closure cost to the FDIC higher
than the cost of a deposit payoff because of the least-cost rule.
Bidding
Next the FDIC draws up a detailed description of the assets and
liabilities of the troubled bank. Once completed, the FDIC offers the
bank for sale, providing the description, known as the information
package, to interested bidders. Interested bidders are allowed the
opportunity to perform a due diligence analysis on the troubled bank,
involving on-site review of the bank's books.
Following due diligence, each interested party submits a bid. The
bid includes two figures. The first figure is the bidder's estimate
of the collectable value of the troubled bank's assets or that
portion of the assets that the bidder plans to acquire. When calculating
this figure, the bidder deducts his expected collection expenses. The
second, the intangible asset portion of the bid, is the bidder's
estimate of what is often called the bank's franchise value. Here
the bidder is attempting to estimate the future earnings flows that
might emanate from the long-term deposit and loan relationships
developed with the failed bank's customers. The bid is based on
this estimate (FDIC 1998b, 13-17).
Several factors are important when estimating franchise value. One
such factor is the proportion of core deposits in the failed bank's
liability portfolio. Core deposits--checking and savings accounts held
by individuals and small businesses--tend to pay below-market interest
rates. Further, the depositors holding these core deposits are often
deemed unlikely to withdraw their funds when a new bank takes over
because of the inconvenience and costs of doing so. Acquirers are
willing to pay more for a bank with a high proportion of this long-term
source of low-cost funding. Another factor likely to be an important
determinant of franchise value is the expected economic growth of the
bank's market area. The relationships established by a bank with
its retail and business customers, whether the bank is healthy or
failing, are far more valuable in a vibrant local economy than in one in
decline.
While the potential acquirers' bids are made up of two
figures, one for the value of assets acquired and one for the franchise
value acquired, another figure also plays an important role in the bid
amount. Winning bidders typically assume the failing bank's insured
deposits, and these deposits often exceed the value of assets purchased.
Therefore, the acquirer will not pay the FDIC to buy the bank but
instead must, on net, be compensated to take over the failing bank. As a
result, one might assume that in total an acquirer's bid would be a
negative dollar amount. But by convention, bids are calculated as if the
FDIC were to pay the winning bidder dollar-for-dollar to assume insured
deposits. For example, consider the case of Comatose National Bank. At
the time of its failure the book value of its assets was $200 million,
and it had $220 million in insured deposits. The amount bid by the
winning bidder, Acquisitive National, was $130 million, its estimate of
the collectable value of the assets, and $10 million for franchise
value.
Though Acquisitive's bids together summed to $140 million, it
did not pay this amount to the FDIC at consummation. Instead, the FDIC
paid Acquisitive $80 million ($220 million minus $140 million), since
Acquisitive had to be compensated for assuming $220 million in Comatose
deposits.
Once the bidding closes, the FDIC accepts the bid that produces the
least cost to the FDIC. As long as one of the bids exceeds the
FDIC's estimate of the cost of liquidating assets and repaying
insured depositors--the deposit payoff method of disposing of the
troubled bank--then the FDIC will employ the purchase and assumption
method.
Uninsured Depositors Often Lose
Under either the deposit payoff or purchase and assumption method,
uninsured depositors and other bank creditors stand to suffer losses.
Losses have not always been imposed on such depositors. Prior to the
FDICIA the FDIC could choose any resolution with a cost below the cost
of a deposit payoff. As a result, the FDIC had the leeway to make
uninsured depositors whole even if doing so was not least cost, allowing
it to protect the majority of these depositors from loss. The least-cost
rule makes covering uninsured depositors much less likely, so that since
the FDICIA, most have suffered losses. Even today, when the least-cost
bidder wishes to take the uninsured deposits, uninsured depositors can
be protected.
Frequency with Which the Disposition Methods Have Been Used
The FDIC employs three methods to handle failing banks. The first,
purchase and assumption transactions, have predominated throughout the
FDIC's history, accounting for 66 percent of all transactions since
the FDIC was formed (FDIC 2003). During the 1980s, in exchange for
taking on certain failing banks, purchasers often benefited from relaxed
regulatory treatment. For example, the Garn-St. Germain Act of 1982
authorized the FDIC to sell failing banks to banks located outside the
failing bank's home state. At the time, interstate banking was
largely prohibited, so the opportunity to move into an attractive state
by purchasing a failing bank in that state was especially appealing to
acquisitive banks. Acquirers, in turn, were willing to pay more,
diminishing the failed bank's drain on the FDIC's reserves,
bank insurance premiums, and the chance that taxpayers would be called
on to bailout deposit insurance. The second, deposit payoff
transactions, have amounted to 20 percent of all FDIC transactions. A
third transaction type, open bank assistance, accounts for 6 percent of
all FDIC transactions. (6) In an assistance transaction, the FDIC
provides cash or loans to an insolvent bank to return it to solvency,
thereby preventing its failure.
Congress authorized the FDIC to engage in open bank assistance in
1950, but only if the troubled institution was deemed essential to its
community (FDIC 1998b, 48). The FDIC assisted only six banks from 1950
until 1982, when the Garn-St. Germain Depository Institutions Act
dropped the essentiality test. Instead, Garn-St. Germain authorized the
FDIC to provide open bank assistance as long as doing so was less
expensive than a deposit payoff. A payoff is usually quite costly to the
FDIC, especially when the failing bank is large, since the FDIC must
manage payouts to all insured depositors and affect either the sale or
collection of all of the bank's assets, a process that can proceed
for years. Between 1982 and 1992 the FDIC provided assistance to 120
banks. But in 1991, the FDICIA restricted the ability of the FDIC to
choose to assist banks. The Act required that the FDIC always choose the
transaction that was least costly in terms of the FDIC expenditures and,
should FDIC reserves be depleted, least costly to taxpayers. Further, in
1993 the Resolution Trust Corporation Completion Act (Public Law
103-204) prohibited the use of any FDIC funds to provide assistance if
such assistance would benefit shareholders of the troubled institution.
The combination of FDICIA's restriction and the Completion
Act's prohibition meant that (except in a special case discussed
later) the FDIC could no longer provide open bank assistance.
Ultimately, this change meant that Congress reduced the FDIC's
discretion to use funds from reserves built by bank-paid premiums or
taxpayers' dollars for objectives other than closing banks at
minimum cost.
Since 1993, therefore, the FDIC has used only purchase and
assumption and depositor payout to dispose of failed bank assets and
liabilities. Purchase and assumption dominates since it is typically the
least-cost method. It is least costly because a purchaser is normally
willing to pay more for assets (or equivalently, require lower
compensation to assume liabilities) if they are delivered together with
associated liabilities. When a significant portion of a failed
bank's assets and liabilities are sold as a bundle, the buyer
acquires the benefits of continuing relationships with the failed
bank's customers. Developing these relationships could only be
accomplished at a significant cost otherwise.
7. WHAT DID THE IMPROVEMENT ACT IMPROVE?
The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act was
intended to ensure that 1) bank closures be accomplished at the minimum
cost possible to the deposit insurance fund, and 2) that bank
supervisors quickly close banks that are no longer viable. Closure
policies whereby uninsured depositors were protected from loss came to
be viewed as unacceptably expensive to the insurance fund as well as
damping any incentive these depositors might have to monitor their
banks. During the 1980s, bank supervisors had been slow to close banks
and thrifts that were in serious trouble, betting that the institution
would recover if given time. Such delay was viewed by many observers as
contributing to considerably higher closure costs and to excessive
risk-taking by the troubled banks. Further, acting slowly meant that
financial resources were locked away in poorly run operations.
The Act appears to have gone a long way toward accomplishing these
two goals. First, as mentioned earlier, the FDICIA has meant that
uninsured depositors suffer losses much more frequently. In the years
immediately before implementation of the FDICIA, meaning 1986 through
1992, in 78 percent of bank failures uninsured depositors suffered no
losses. Since the FDICIA became effective, (i.e., from 1993 through
2002), in 76 percent of bank failures uninsured depositors were repaid
less than 100 percent of the value of their deposits (Benston and
Kaufman 1997, Table 3; FDIC Annual Report, various years). As a result,
these depositors now share some of the bank failure costs previously
borne by the FDIC. Uninsured depositors are those with more than the
FDIC coverage limit of $100,000 in an account and depositors with funds
in foreign offices of U.S. banks.
As an additional advantage, because depositors are no longer
protected from loss, those with more than $100,000 in an account or with
funds in a bank's foreign office can be expected to exercise some
market discipline over banks. In other words, these individuals will
make an effort to monitor the health of their banks since they know that
depositors in failed banks have experienced losses. They will demand
higher interest rates or remove their funds if the bank is perceived as
too risky. Bank risk-taking will be reduced, lowering the frequency and
cost of bank failures.
The monitoring benefit may be limited, however. The FDICIA appears
to have increased the likelihood that large banks' uninsured
depositors may suffer losses in a failure, and large banks are the
greatest recipients of uninsured deposits. Prior to the FDICIA, these
depositors were uniformly protected (Benston and Kaufman 1997, 30).
However, in the case of several fairly large banks, depositors have
suffered losses since the FDICIA. Yet, FDICIA contains a provision that
allows supervisors in some cases to protect all depositors in large
banks, a fact which will certainly damp depositors' incentives to
monitor large bank health. Further, uninsured deposits make up a fairly
small fraction of the total deposits of small banks, so for these banks
the significance of depositor monitoring is also limited. As of the end
of the first quarter of 2003, on average, uninsured deposits accounted
for only 23 percent of small banks' deposits. Here a small bank is
defined as one with assets less than $1 billion.
Second, the FDICIA set in place a mechanism to lower the likelihood
that supervisors will forbear, i.e., wait to close a bank that is
clearly no longer viable. Since 1993, when the prompt corrective action
provisions took effect, supervisors generally have had 90 days, and at
most 270 days, to close a critically undercapitalized bank. While the
requirement is straightforward, measuring a bank's capital--meaning
valuing assets and liabilities--often is not. Any failure by supervisors
to quickly force a bank to "write down" the value of
uncollectible assets will diminish the effectiveness of these prompt
corrective action requirements.
Placing a dollar value on assets and liabilities always involves
subjective judgements. One of the primary roles of bank supervision is
measuring this value. If the bank has overstated capital, examiners from
the bank's supervisory agency should require the bank to reduce its
reported level of capital, in some cases enough to indicate that the
bank is insolvent or nearly so. Ensuring that these examiner judgments
are made in an unbiased manner--at times when the management of the
troubled bank and interested parties might bring pressure to be
lenient--is critical to the effectiveness of prompt corrective action.
The FDICIA established a mechanism intended to encourage unbiased
judgments by bank supervisors. If the supervisor does not lower the
value of capital when doing so is appropriate, the troubled bank is
likely to increase its losses, ultimately expanding the FDIC's
losses when the bank is closed. Whenever the FDIC loses an amount equal
to the greater of $25 million or 2 percent of the failed bank's
assets, the inspector general of the failed bank's federal
supervisor must prepare a report on the failure. The report describes
the reasons for the loss and how such losses might be prevented in the
future. These reports, scrutinized by the General Accounting Office, are
available to Congress and to the public. The threat of public scrutiny
and censure provided by an inspector general report is intended to
offset any pressures to be inappropriately lenient.
The inspector general reports appear to have had a positive
influence on banking agency enforcement of the prompt corrective action
portions of the FDICIA. According to Benston and Kaufman (1997, 21, 26)
several critical reports were produced soon after the FDICIA requirement
became effective. As a result, the agencies modified their procedures
and received more favorable reports subsequently.
8. LIMITS ON DISCOUNT WINDOW LENDING
The FDICIA's least-cost requirement successfully changed FDIC
behavior so that uninsured depositors are much less frequently
protected. Yet, these depositors might still avoid losses, and so have
little incentive to monitor. As a bank's financial health
deteriorates, depositors may become aware of this deterioration, and
those with deposits not protected by the FDIC will seek to withdraw
them. The bank might attempt to meet depositors' demands for
repayment by borrowing from the Federal Reserve. If the Fed lends,
depositors can escape and avoid losses. Consequently, if depositors
expect Fed discount window lending to flow, they have a reduced
incentive to monitor bank risk-taking.
Further, uninsured depositors' gain is met by an equivalent
FDIC loss. Fed lending that allows these depositors to escape, increases
FDIC losses because, while uninsured depositors bear losses in a bank
failure, the Fed does not. The Fed bears no losses since it lends only
if the bank provides, as collateral, assets worth more than the Fed
loans. Therefore, funding from depositors who are likely to share some
of the failed bank's losses, is replaced by funding from the Fed,
which is protected against losses. Losses that might have been borne by
depositors are transferred to the FDIC, and the vehicle making this
transfer possible is Fed lending.
Legislators designing the FDICIA saw the danger and placed limits
on Fed lending. In general, the Act allows lending for only 60 days to
banks that are undercapitalized. Even more restrictive is the limitation
on lending to critically undercapitalized banks. For such banks, the Fed
can only lend for five days. So the FDICIA restricts the potential for
Fed lending to allow uninsured depositors to escape.
The Act's limitations may not be perfect, however. For as
Broaddus (2000) and Goodfriend and Lacker (1999) note, depositors may
escape before the limitations are brought to bear. Depositors may have
become aware of financial problems before the bank's reported
capital has fallen. In other words, while the bank's true capital
position may be quite weak, reported capital levels may not have
declined. Examiners may not yet have forced a revaluation of the
bank's assets. If so, Fed lending might occur, allowing uninsured
depositors to escape from a weak bank.
Yet even if FDICIA's limitations prevent Fed lending from
facilitating the escape of depositors, some may still escape. For even
without any Fed loans, the bank could meet the demands of depositors and
creditors by selling the same assets it would otherwise release to the
Fed as collateral. The assets might be sold to other banks or to
secondary market participants. The development during the 1990s of
secondary markets for a number of bank loans improves the opportunities
for such sales. Consequently, regardless of Fed lending, some uninsured
depositors can be expected to escape. (7)
9. AID FOR BANKS THAT MIGHT POSE A SYSTEMIC RISK
Section 141 of the Act requires the FDIC to determine and employ
the least-costly resolution method. Further, this section of the Act
prohibits the FDIC, when acting as receiver for a troubled bank, from
protecting uninsured depositors and the bank's other creditors if
doing so adds to the expense of resolution. Yet, Section 141 grants an
exception to these rules. The Act itself calls this the "systemic
risk" exception, and observers typically refer to it as the
"too-big-to-fail" exception. The least-cost rule can be
bypassed if the FDIC determines that closing the troubled bank without
protecting uninsured depositors or creditors would have serious effects
on economic conditions or financial stability. In other words, an
exception to the rule is allowed if a bank's closure with losses to
uninsured depositors might lead to the spread of financial problems
widely through the banking system.
Only when the FDIC's Board of Directors, the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve, and the Secretary of the Treasury in
consultation with the President agree to the too-big exception is the
latter allowed. Any decision to employ the exception must be reviewed by
the General Accounting Office. If the exception is granted, the FDIC
must recover its losses from a special assessment on insured banks
beyond normal deposit insurance premiums.
Because of the possibility that the exception might be invoked and
all depositors protected, investors in those banks that might be granted
the exception have a reduced incentive to monitor and are likely to
charge less than completely risk-adjusted interest rates. In response,
such banks are likely to engage in an inefficiently high level of
risk-taking, wasting financial resources.
10. CONCLUSION
During the 1980s, regulators were slow to close troubled thrifts,
leaving many such institutions open long after they were clearly
insolvent. Rather than forcing ineffectual institutions to disgorge
their financial assets so that they might be reemployed in more
profitable uses, regulators allowed these assets to remain under the
institutions' control. In 1991, legislators passed the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act. The intention was to
reduce the likelihood that taxpayers would again be called on to bail
out the deposit insurance fund as they had following the thrift failures
of the 1980s. But the Act also established a process more likely to
produce an efficient allocation of financial assets. Under the regime
introduced by FDICIA, a troubled bank's management must either
gather new equity funding or be closed. The requirement that it gather
new funding forces the bank to face a market test similar to that faced
by troubled nonbank firms. If investors can be convinced that the bank
is viable, they will advance new equity, and the bank continues to
control its assets. If not, the bank is taken over by a receiver, and
its assets are sold to others.
The FDICIA cannot guarantee that the mistakes made during the 1980s
will not be repeated, but it has implemented a more market-like set of
closure procedures. Further, the Act places limits on regulator
discretion and establishes disclosure requirements that encourage
regulators to move quickly to force the recapitalization or closure of
troubled banks. As a result, the events of the 1980s in which numerous
insolvent thrifts were allowed to remain open for extended periods are
less likely to be repeated. Still, the Act allows exceptions for certain
banks, those deemed to pose a systemic risk. In such cases the Act
tolerates a process that differs greatly from the one the market imposes
on troubled nonbank firms.
Deposit insurance blunts the default mechanism that disciplines
prompt closure of nonbank firms. Therefore supervisors must play a
critical role ensuring that insolvent banks are closed promptly. Prompt
closure is necessary to minimize distortions to financial markets and to
control the cost of deposit insurance to the banking system and
ultimately to the public.
(1) This figure includes banks that discontinued deposit operations
or otherwise liquidated or closed. It excludes banks that failed or
merged. See "Notes to Users" in FDIC (2003). While the bank
supervisors did not force the closure of these banks, it is likely that
the threat of supervisory intervention may have been important in some
of the closures. Owners may have shunned closure had the threat not been
looming.
(2) An excellent historical review of the FDIC's work as
receiver during the banking and thrift crisis of the 1980s can be found
in Volumes 1 and 2 of FDIC (1998a). For a broad historical review of the
crisis see Volumes 1 and 2 of FDIC (1997).
(3) See Chapter 2 of FDIC (1998b), which provides a thorough,
readable review of the process by which the FDIC closes out the
operation of a troubled bank.
(4) There are two scenarios under which a failed bank's assets
might exceed deposits. First, the FDICIA authorizes bank regulators to
appoint a receiver when a bank's capital falls to 2 percent. In
such a case, total assets exceed total liabilities, so assets will
certainly exceed deposits which can be no greater than total
liabilities. For most banks deposits are significantly smaller than
total liabilities (on average deposits account for about 72 percent of
bank liabilities). Second, the value of the troubled bank's assets
might be smaller than the value of total liabilities, such that the bank
has negative capital and must be closed, yet the value of assets exceed
the value of all deposits.
(5) The priority of payment is based on a provision of federal law
normally referred to as the depositor preference rule, established by
Title III of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993 (Public Law
103-66). Prior to its enactment, general creditors had a claim on the
failed bank's assets equivalent to that of the FDIC and uninsured
depositors. The law placed the FDIC and uninsured depositors ahead of
general creditors. See Thomson 1994 for a review of the changes produced
by the depositor preference law. General creditors are all bank
creditors except those holding 1) bank deposits or 2) subordinated notes
and bonds issued by the bank. Subordinated notes and bonds are bank
debts which contractually specify that they are repaid only after other
bank creditors are repaid.
(6) A fourth type of transaction, the insured deposit transfer, has
also been employed. It is a hybrid between a purchase and assumption and
a deposit payoff, making up 8 percent of all FDIC transactions. The FDIC
began using the deposit transfer in 1983. Under this method a healthy
bank acquires the insured deposits of a failed bank but typically none
of its assets. In return for taking on these liabilities, the bank
receives a payment of cash from the FDIC. The healthy bank benefits from
new deposit customer relationships, and, therefore, the FDIC's
payment to the acquiring bank is lower than the FDIC would otherwise pay
out to depositors (FDIC 1998b, 45).
(7) A troubled bank might also repay uninsured depositors by
raising new insured deposits. Insured depositors will be willing to
provide funding to a troubled bank since they are insensitive to the
bank's financial condition. Raising new deposits may take some
time. The process can be quickened by employing a deposit broker. The
broker can offer a bank's insured CDs to a wide audience of
potential investors. However, Section 301 of FDICIA restricts
financially weak banks' use of brokered deposits.
REFERENCES
Benston, George J., and George G. Kaufman. 1997. "FDICIA after
Five Years: A Review and Evaluation." Working Papers Series. Issues
in Financial Regulation. WP-97-1. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Chicago, IL. (July).
Broaddus, J. Alfred, Jr. 2000. "Market Discipline and Fed
Lending." Remarks before the Bank Structure Conference Sponsored by
the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Chicago, IL. 5 May. Also available
online at http://www.rich.frb.org/media/speeches/show.cfm? SpeechID=21
(accessed November 10, 2003).
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). 1997. History of the
Eighties, Lessons for the Future 1, 2. Washington, D.C.
________________. 1998a. Managing the Crisis: The FDIC and RTC Experience 1, 2. Washington, D.C.
________________. 1998b. "Resolutions Handbook: Methods for
Resolving Troubled Financial Institutions in the United States."
Washington, D.C. Also available online at
http://www.fdic.gov/bank/historical/reshandbook/index.html (accessed
November 10, 2003).
________________. 2003. Historical Statistics on Banking Table
CB02. "Changes in Number of Institutions, FDIC-Insured Commercial
Banks, United States and Other Areas." Washington, D.C. Also
available online at www.2.fdic.gov/hsob (accessed November 10, 2003).
________________. Various years. Annual Report. Washington, D.C.
Goodfriend, Marvin, and Jeffrey M. Lacker. 1999. "Limited
Commitment and Central Bank Lending." Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly 85 (Fall): 1-27.
Thomson, James B. 1994. "The National Depositor Preference
Law." Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary (15
February).
U.S. Department of the Treasury, Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency. (OCC). 2001. "An Examiner's Guide to Problem Bank
Identification, Rehabilitation, and Resolution." Washington, D.C.
(January). Also available online at www.occ.treas.gov/prbbnkgd.pdf
(accessed November 10, 2003).
________________, Office of the Inspector General. 2000.
"Material Loss Review of The First National Bank of Keystone."
Report OIG-00-067. Washington, D.C. March 10. Also available online at
www.treasury.gov/offices/inspector-general/audit-reports/2000/oig00067.pdf (accessed November 10, 2003).
The author benefited greatly from discussions with Kartik Athreya,
Marvin Goodfriend, Tom Humphrey, and John Weinberg. The views expressed
herein are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
or the Federal Reserve System.