Accommodating rising population in rural areas: the case of Loudoun County, Virginia.
Owens, Raymond E. ; Sarte, Pierre-Daniel G.
Washington, D.C., and Richmond, Virginia, are cities that share
rich pasts in histories and politics. And although their centers lie 100
miles apart, the two areas also share something else--an approximately
12-mile-long border. According to the 2000 U.S. Census, the Washington,
D.C., metropolitan statistical area (MSA) and the Richmond MSA literally
bump into one another.
Although no one is likely to mistake the shared boundary area of
the two MSAs for either city's downtown, MSAs have come to be the
standard measure of a city's reach. That the two cities defined in
this manner stretch well over 100 miles demonstrates the magnitude of
population growth that has occurred in both urban areas. This growth is
all the more impressive when one considers that much of it occurred in
the last 30 years.
The rapid growth of suburban areas around Washington, D.C., and
Richmond, Virginia (and of many cities like them), poses substantial
challenges for both local elected officials and residents of those
areas. These challenges include providing for housing, roads, sewers,
schools, and the myriad requirements of a population spilling into
formerly rural areas. Furthermore, because the Commonwealth of Virginia
provides limited guidance to localities concerning growth, these
questions often must be addressed by local officials.
The inability of localities to address growth in a more aggressive
manner is guided by the so-called Dillon rule. (1) The Dillon rule is a
legal principle--used in Virginia--that addresses whether certain powers
lie with local governments. The rule possesses two features. The first
states that local governments have three types of powers: in
layman's terms, those granted expressly by the state, those
strongly implied by the state, and those that are essential to
localities. The second part of the Dillon rule states that if there is
any reasonable doubt whether a power has been conferred on a local
government, then the power has not been conferred. This second feature
effectively limits the fiscal tools available to localities to those
strictly allowed by the state.
Attempts by officials of some counties to gain additional fiscal
powers to fund the infrastructure required for an increasing population
have had limited success at the statehouse in Richmond. As a result, the
"toolkit" available to localities is often lacking in
mechanisms that could prove useful in designing efficient growth
policies. Perhaps because their tools are limited by law, localities
have had to rely on available approaches such as taxes on real property,
zoning, and cash proffers from residential and commercial
developers--policies they can utilize--to stem the pressures from a
rising population.
Although property taxes and zoning are generally well understood
policies, proffers are lesser known. In short, proffers are payments
made by developers to local governments as a part of a zoning or
rezoning process. State law dictates that proffers are voluntary. The
payments of the proffers may assist in gaining local government approval
of the zoning action, but the law is clear that a zoning decision cannot
be denied solely because a developer refused to pay a specified proffer amount. State law also specifies that proffers are not impact fees,
though in practice they effectively approximate the latter. That said,
development already zoned without proffers cannot legally be required to
offset any impacts and, even in zoning cases where proffers are
involved, the amount may not correspond to impact costs.
Zoning and cash proffers policies are not always popular with
residents and developers in suburban counties. For example, in Loudoun
County, Virginia, a largely rural county west of Washington, D.C., local
policies to address population growth have occasionally reached a fever
pitch. At a 1999 public hearing on Loudoun's growth policies held
at the county courthouse, newspaper accounts described a near riot,
noting that police officers had to be brought in to control the crowd.
The episode prompted Thomas Sowell, a noted economic columnist, to
devote a column to the issues facing Loudoun that ran in newspapers
across the nation. But the vigorous debate over increasing population in
the county has also been closely watched by a number of groups
interested in growth issues and by surrounding counties, all of whom
view Loudoun's debate as a guide to the likely direction of policy
in general.
The Loudoun debate over population growth and how to address it is
not surprising. Between 1990 and 2002, the county's population grew
at a 7.5 percent annual rate, the second highest in the nation. But the
rapid increase in the number of residents has not been welcomed by many
in the county. County officials contend that the costs of infrastructure
required to serve the population inflow exceeds the revenues generated,
thus threatening the county's fiscal soundness (Meeting with
Loudoun County Officials). In addition, incumbent residents complain
that growth leads to more congestion. Yet there is less agreement as to
the appropriate local policies to address the problems. Given the
limited alternatives available, Loudoun officials have primarily adopted
a zoning approach. Specifically, the county's board of supervisors
has zoned the easternmost one-third of the county nearest Washington,
D.C., (with the greatest population density) as residential, and it is
available to accommodate additional population growth. In contrast, the
westernmost two-thirds of the county (farthest from the downtown D.C.
area) has been zoned for low-density development only, with allowable
densities ranging from one household per 10 acres to one household per
50 acres (see Figure 1). These densities are so low that they
effectively "shut the door" to new residential development in
these areas of the county.
The situation in Loudoun raises many interesting questions
concerning the effects of population growth on localities in the United
States and in other industrial counties. Among the questions are, what
kinds of impacts does population growth generate on county
residents' welfare? Of the policies available to assist with the
cost of population growth, which are used and why? And perhaps most
important, are commonly used policies efficient in an economic sense?
The debate over these questions in Loudoun County, as in the
broader debate, has been hampered by the lack of a formal model that
identifies the likely relevant factors and traces out how they
simultaneously affect residents' welfare. As a result, discussions
between residents and local officials often isolate different arguments
in an ad hoc manner, without providing a single coherent framework. The
intent of this paper is to advance the debate by proposing a more formal
treatment.
An examination of Loudoun's policies within a more formal
setting may serve as a useful benchmark in analyzing the impact of
rising population on counties. In particular, we will consider three
responses to a rising population: zoning, raising the tax rate on real
property, and using unrestricted proffers. We will discuss why these
policies arise and explore whether they are efficient.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
To provide a framework in which these issues can be more
systematically examined, this article presents a simple model of county
agglomeration, inspired by Henderson (1987), where increases in
population density lead to local congestion and higher prices for
housing services. The model recognizes that opening a new area of a
county to development entails substantial fixed costs linked to
infrastructure construction and maintenance, such as sewage and water
systems, highways, and schools, that are financed almost exclusively by
local property taxes. Costs are fixed in the sense that opening an area
to development requires a fixed amount of resources that is independent
of the degree of residential development that takes place. Thus, an
infrastructure network must typically be in place when an area is
opened, irrespective of how many households actually move in. Under
these conditions, we argue that localities' desire to maintain
fiscal soundness combined with state legislated restrictions on their
ability to raise revenues leaves them with little recourse outside
zoning restrictions.
Since housing prices in a given region generally rise with
population density, all else equal, opening new areas to residential
development lowers the average price of housing services as population
spreads out across a larger area. The model then suggests that
consumption of housing services generally rises but that the overall
share of income devoted to housing remains unchanged, a result verified
by data from Loudoun County. Hence, without sufficiently strong
population growth, revenues from property taxes will fail to cover the
additional cost of infrastructure associated with new residential
developments. Indeed, Milligan (2003) argues that "one reason the
Loudoun board used the blunt instrument of rezoning is because state
lawmakers have resolutely refused to give localities other tools to
manage growth." In other words, without the ability to acquire
additional funds by raising property tax rates, the fixed costs
associated with infrastructure construction and maintenance naturally
lead to inertia in the creation of new residential developments. (2)
Because our model contains both property taxes and congestion
externalities, the decentralized equilibrium is potentially inefficient.
Even so, we show that in so far as congestion externalities are mainly
local in nature, the decentralized distribution of individuals across
locations is socially optimal. The presence of property taxes, however,
does distort the consumption of housing services relative to other types
of consumption. We argue that the policy of charging a proffer per
housing unit to developers, which some localities have effectively
followed in Virginia, constitutes a less distortional means of financing
the costs of public infrastructure. In our framework, the use of
proffers can actually help implement the first best solution in a
decentralized setting.
1. A MODEL OF COUNTY AGGLOMERATION
Consider a county that encompasses S > 0 areas, where S = {1, 2,
... S}, can be thought of as a group of Census tracts. We let M = {1, 2,
... M} [??] S denote the set of areas open to residential housing. To be
equipped for residential settlement, a region i [member of] M with land
area [A.sub.i] > 0 requires that a complete infrastructure network be
provided and maintained. Examples of infrastructure include roads, sewer
and water systems, schools, and public transportation, which in
aggregate is assumed to carry a fixed resource cost, [PHI]([A.sub.i]),
with [PHI](0) = 0, and [PHI]'([A.sub.i]) > 0.
For now, we assume a fixed county population N, with [N.sub.i]
individuals living in location i [member of] M. Each individual is
endowed with one unit of labor, which he provides inelastically in a
core city located outside the county. The distance from any area i
[member of] S to the city varies depending on its location within the
county. In Loudoun, for example, the relatively large area of the county
means that some residents live as close as 25 miles from the center of
Washington, D.C., while other residents may live as far away as 50
miles.
Production
Individuals are employed in the production of a county-wide traded
good summarized by,
y = [lambda][M.summation over (i=1)][N.sub.i], [lambda] > 0, (1)
where y denotes the quantity of traded good output. These goods are
produced competitively by firms that operate in the city center. Profit
maximization by these firms immediately implies that
[w.sub.i] = [lambda] = w [for all]i, (2)
where [w.sub.i] is the wage paid to individuals living in area i.
Since individuals living in different regions of the county are perfect
substitutes in production, they all earn the same wage. In the model
below, the distribution of individuals across county areas derives from
a tradeoff between commuting costs and the cost of housing services. To
the degree that different individuals have different incomes, this
tradeoff would involve net commuting costs instead. In a setting with
net commuting costs, however, the substance of our analysis would remain
largely unchanged.
Individuals living in different areas of the county open to
development also consume housing which we treat as a location-specific
good. As in Chatterjee and Carlino (2001), this good is produced using a
technology that is linear in the traded good. Specifically, we have that
[G.sub.i] = ([gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]])[.sup.-1] [x.sub.i],
[gamma] > 0, [eta] > 0, (3)
where [x.sub.i] represents the quantity of the traded good required
to produce [G.sub.i] units of the local good in region i. The variable
[d.sub.i] denotes population density in location i, [N.sub.i]/[A.sub.i].
Thus, the factor [gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]] in equation (3) captures the
notion that higher population density reduces the efficiency of local
good production.
Local good producers, interpreted here as providers of housing
services, operate in a competitive market and maximize profits,
max [p.sub.i][G.sub.i] - [x.sub.i], (4)
where [p.sub.i] is the price of the local good in region i in units
of the traded good. These producers take population density in each
county area as given. Substituting for [x.sub.i] in equation (4), and
maximizing with respect to [G.sub.i], the price of the local good in
county area i will then reflect its marginal cost,
[p.sub.i] = [gamma]([N.sub.i]/[A.sub.i])[.sup.[eta]]. (5)
Therefore, as population increases in location i, so does the price
of housing services in that area.
Preferences
Individuals that live in county location i have linear preferences
over an aggregate good, [C.sub.i], given by
[C.sub.i] = [(1 -
[[delta].sub.i])[g.sub.i]][.sup.[theta]][c.sub.i.sup.1-[theta]], (6)
where 0 < [theta] < 1 and 0 < [[delta].sub.i] < 1 [for
all]i. In equation (6), [c.sub.i] and [g.sub.i] represent consumption of
the traded and local good, respectively. Since [g.sub.i] represents
housing services, individuals consuming [g.sub.i] can be thought of as
renters. The parameter [[delta].sub.i] captures the reduction in utility
imposed by commuting between home and work. We can think of this
reduction in the following way. Suppose two identical houses differ only
in how far they are located from the workplace at the city center. A
resident living at the more distant house spends more time commuting and
correspondingly spends less time at home, thus getting less satisfaction
(i.e., a higher [[delta].sub.i]) from a given amount of housing
services. It is worth noting, though, that distance from the city center
is not the only source of differences in commuting times. In practice,
the location of roads, bridges, mountains, and physical features
generally affect commuting times. Thus, it is entirely possible to find
locations nearer to the city center that actually have longer commuting
times to the city core. As a general rule, however, we expect that
differences in housing services consumption will reflect the distance
from the city center and the associated commute costs.
Each individual living in location i faces the following budget
constraint,
[p.sub.i][g.sub.i] + [c.sub.i] [less than or equal to] w -
[tau][p.sub.i][g.sub.i], (7)
where [tau] is a county-wide property tax that helps cover the cost
of public infrastructure in areas open to development. In Loudoun
County, the total real property and personal taxes collected each year
amounts to $400 million, the approximate cost of operating the
county's school system. Utility maximization subject to constraint
(7) implies that a mobile individual residing in location i chooses
[g.sub.i] = [theta]w/(1 + [tau])[p.sub.i] (8)
and
[c.sub.i] = (1 - [theta])w. (9)
Equilibrium
We focus on equilibria where the distribution of individuals across
county locations leaves no region open to development unoccupied. From
equations (3) and (9), the indirect utility achieved by an individual
living in location i is,
[V.sub.i] = [[theta].sup.[theta]] (1 - [theta])[.sup.[theta]] (1 -
[[delta].sub.i])[.sup.[theta]](1 +
[tau])[.sup.-[theta]][p.sub.i.sup.-[theta]] w, (10)
or, substituting for [p.sub.i] and w,
[V.sub.i] = [[theta].sup.[theta]] (1 - [theta])[.sup.[theta]] (1 -
[[delta].sub.i])[.sup.[theta]](1 + [tau])[.sup.-[theta]]
[[gamma].sup.-[theta]]([N.sub.i]/[A.sub.i])[.sup.-[theta][eta]]
[lambda]. (11)
Equilibrium with free movement of individuals requires that utility
be equalized across all locations, [V.sub.i] = [bar.V][for all]i [member
of] M. If there were a pair of locations i and j with [V.sub.i] >
[V.sub.j], individuals would seek to move from j to i. This would raise
congestion in i and lower it in j until [V.sub.i] and [V.sub.j] were
equalized. In addition, the sum of individuals across locations open to
development must equal the exogenous county-wide population,
[M.summation over (i=1)] [N.sub.i] = N. (12)
Finally, the county must cover the fixed costs associated with
providing and maintaining public infrastructure in the developed areas,
[M.summation over (i=1)] [N.sub.i][tau][p.sub.i][g.sub.i] =
[M.summation over (i=1)] [PHI]([A.sub.i]), (13)
where the left-hand side of the above expression denotes tax
revenues from property taxes.
Proposition:
Under the maintained hypotheses, there exists a unique distribution
of individuals across open locations, [N.sub.i], i = 1,..., M, with
common utility, [bar.V] > 0.
Proof:
Observe that the conditions [V.sub.i] = [bar.V] [for all]i [member
of] M and [[summation].sub.i=1.sup.M] [N.sub.i] = N make up M + 1
equations in M + 1 unknowns, namely [N.sub.i], i = 1,..., M, and
[bar.V]. Thus, rewrite equation (11) as
[N.sub.i] = [[bar.V]/[[[theta].sup.[theta]] (1 -
[theta])[.sup.[theta]] (1 - [[delta].sub.i])[.sup.[theta]] (1 +
[tau])[.sup.-[theta]] [[gamma].sup.-[theta]]
[lambda]]][.sup.-[1/[theta][eta]]][A.sub.i].
Substituting this expression into equation (12), it follows that
[bar.V] must solve
[M.summation over (i=1)] [[bar.V]/[[[theta].sup.[theta]] (1 -
[theta])[.sup.[theta]] (1 - [[delta].sub.i])[.sup.[theta]] (1 +
[tau])[.sup.-[theta]] [[gamma].sup.-[theta]]
[lambda]]][.sup.-[1/[theta][eta]]][A.sub.i] = N.
Define the left-hand side of the above expression as F([bar.V]),
and note that [lim.sub.[bar.V][right arrow]0] F([bar.V]) = [infinity]
while [lim.sub.[bar.V][right arrow][infinity]] F([bar.V]) = 0. Since
F([bar.V]) is continuous, by the Intermediate Value Theorem, there
exists [bar.V] > 0 such that F([bar.V]) = N. In addition, because
F([bar.V]) is strictly decreasing in [bar.V] on [0, [infinity]), this
solution is unique.
Given the solution for [bar.V], one can then simply solve for the
distribution of individuals across location using (11).
The model of county agglomeration we have just presented possesses
two important features that emerge as equilibrium outcomes.
First, the relative price of housing services between any two
county areas reflects differences in commuting costs. In particular,
from equation (10), the condition that [V.sub.i] = [V.sub.j] for any two
areas open to residential housing implies that
[p.sub.i] = [p.sub.j] ([1 - [[delta].sub.i]]/[1 - [[delta].sub.j]])
[for all]i and j [member of] M. (14)
In other words, in choosing where to live within the county,
individuals will trade off the price of housing services against
commuting costs. In particular, county locations that involve a shorter
commute to work will tend to have higher-priced housing services. In
fact, this result appears to hold in Loudoun, though the heterogeneity of the housing stock makes a precise measure difficult. According to
county officials, identical houses in areas with lower commuting costs
generally command higher prices (and thus rents) than similar houses in
areas of the county with higher commuting costs.
Second, because prices of housing services reflect congestion
externalities driven by higher density, county areas with higher
commuting costs will also have lower densities. In (14), [[delta].sub.i]
< [[delta].sub.j] implies that [p.sub.i] > [p.sub.j]. By equation
(5), we then also have that [d.sub.i] > [d.sub.j].
At this stage, we find it useful to introduce a numerical example
to better highlight key features of our model as the economic
environment changes. Specifically, given the debate surrounding Loudoun
County, we focus on the effects of a rising county population as well as
those of a change in the number of areas open to residential housing. We
shall also use this numerical example below in making comparisons with
the efficient solution.
Calibration to Current Loudoun County Benchmarks
According to our model, differences in commuting costs,
[[delta].sub.i], lead to varying densities in different regions.
Therefore, as shown in Figure 1, we partition the developed eastern
region of Loudoun County (i.e., the region unaffected by zoning
restrictions) into density quintiles and set [[delta].sub.i] to match
the density of each of the five areas. The associated five land areas
have sizes, in square miles, 116.4, 27.3, 13.2, 8.2, and 5.7, and we
calibrate [A.sub.i] to match each of these land areas. The population
density in these five areas are, in people per square mile, 208.21,
1,072.71, 1,909.00, 3,563.51, and 5,613.52. Observe in Figure 1 that
low-density areas tend to be farther away from Fairfax County and
Washington, D.C., where Loudoun County residents typically commute to
work.
According to the U.S. Census, the population in the developed areas
of Loudoun County currently stands at 139,873, and we set N to match
this value. We choose [lambda] to reflect an individual's yearly
earnings in the county, $50,238. This number reflects a weighted average
of male and female full-time workers. From the Census, the share of
income spent on housing and property taxes, [theta], is approximately
0.25. It is difficult to get an accurate housing price per square foot
corresponding to each region, where we think of square footage as a
proxy for housing services. However, data from the Loudoun County Office
of Mapping and Geographic Information suggests that $143 per square foot
is a reasonable upper bound for that county. We then choose [gamma] to
match this upper bound in equilibrium, [gamma] = 93.41, and set [eta]
assuming a 15 percent gradient in housing prices from the most to the
least dense area.
Finally, because individuals spend [p.sub.i][g.sub.i] of their
yearly disposable income on housing services, current housing values, V,
for the typical individual are given by
V = [phi]([p.sub.i][g.sub.i]), (15)
[phi] = [1/r][[(1 + r)[.sup.T + 1] - 1]/[(1 + r)[.sup.T]]],
where [phi] is a factor that captures the present value of a one
dollar annuity discounted over the number of years that a house provides
services, T, and rate, r. In particular, given that the typical
household contains 2.7 individuals in Loudoun County, our model suggests
that the representative house is worth approximately $435,000 when T =
30 and r = 0.05. Property tax rates in Loudoun County are currently set
to 1.08 percent of housing values. Since the property tax in (7) applies
to [p.sub.i][g.sub.i] rather than [phi] (n[p.sub.i][g.sub.i]), where n
is the number of individuals per household, we let [tau] = 0.0108[phi]n,
or 0.18. This tax generates about $4,700 per household yearly. The
parameters that achieve our calibration targets are summarized in Table
1.
Table 2 reports the model-generated population and density
distribution in each of the five areas depicted in Figure 1. As shown in
the table, the model, although stylized, does well in reproducing actual
Loudoun County statistics. In addition, we are also able to approximate
statistics we had not explicitly targeted. For instance, both average
housing prices and yearly property taxes collected per household conform
relatively well to the data.
Zoning Restrictions in the Face of Increasing Population
The model above implies that in a given year, approximately $243
million are collected in property taxes in the developed region of
Loudoun County. (3) Since this revenue is used exclusively to finance
the provision and maintenance of public infrastructure, the
corresponding fixed costs come to slightly more than $1.42 million per
square mile.
Suppose that local authorities were to consider lifting zoning
restrictions on 10 additional square miles adjacent to the already
developed part of the county. Because we assume this area to be
immediately adjacent to the least dense populated region, we posit
similar commuting costs, [delta] = 0.23. Residents of the new area,
therefore, would incur commuting costs equivalent to a 23 percent
reduction in housing services. Moreover, according to our calculations,
opening this region to development would require an additional $14.2
million in property taxes.
With no population growth and no adjustment in property tax rates,
our model implies that total property taxes collected would also remain
unchanged. The existing population would spread out across a larger area
thus lowering density and, by equation (5), local goods' prices.
However, by equation (8), individuals would then increase their
consumption of housing services so as to leave the share of income they
spend on housing exactly unchanged. In practice, the share of income
devoted to housing services is indeed nearly constant over time, not
only in Loudoun County and Virginia, but nationally. Since this amount
helps determine housing values in equation (15), it follows that these
values would then remain unaffected and so would the resulting property
taxes. Hence, opening a new area to residential housing is feasible only
if the rate of net migration into the county is sufficient to generate
tax revenues equal to the additional fixed costs incurred.
In our hypothetical example, the existing county population would
have to increase by approximately 5.9 percent to yield an increase in
the tax base large enough to generate an additional $14.2 million. This
represents an increase of around 8,250 individuals or 3,050 households.
Thus, given that installing and maintaining infrastructure entails
substantial fixed costs, our analysis implies inertia in the creation of
new developments. That is, the population residing in areas already open
to development has to reach a high enough threshold that the tax base
can cover the additional cost of new infrastructure. Therefore, with
legislated and/or political limits on a county's ability to raise
property tax rates, local authorities have little practical recourse
other than to appeal to low-density zoning restrictions. Note that while
population grows to meet a threshold that would allow the county to open
a new area, density increases, local goods prices rise, and consumption
of housing services fall. Consumption of the aggregate good, [C.sub.i],
in equation (6), therefore, decreases for the representative individual.
(4) It is no surprise, therefore, that some county residents complain of
congestion and exert pressure on Loudoun County's board of
supervisors to lift zoning restrictions.
It is important to note that given a fixed county population, N,
opening a new area of the county to residential development in our
framework does not necessarily increase welfare. On the one hand, the
new area would allow for lower population density and lower congestion
in existing regions of the county. This effect induces individuals to
consume more housing services which increases welfare. On the other
hand, to the degree that the cost of additional infrastructure raises
property tax rates, consumption of housing services would fall. On net,
it is not clear that consumption of housing services would increase if
an additional region of the county were zoned for residential
settlement. Furthermore, from (6), commuting costs associated with the
new area would also play a direct role in the evaluation of welfare.
In Loudoun County, rates of increase in the county's
population are fore-cast to remain high, though not as high as in the
1990s. Loudoun's Department of Economic Development projects that
the county's population will rise at an average annual rate of 4.7
percent over the next nine years, about triple the rate of population
growth expected in the United States over the same period. Thus, it is
likely that an imbalance between population growth, revenues, and
infrastructure adequacy will continue to face the county.
2. THE SOCIAL PLANNER'S PROBLEM
We now show that the outcomes in the decentralized county economy
are not Pareto optimal. Specifically, we can assess Pareto optimality by
comparing our results above with the results from the same problem for a
hypothetical social planner. Contrary to most models in regional
economics, the source of inefficiency in our framework does not stem
from the congestion externalities linked to density. In our model, these
externalities are local in nature and, therefore, directly reflected in
the price of housing services in the concerned region. In essence, the
technology in (3) assumes that greater density in region i congests the
production of housing services in that region, and not in another region
that is further away. (5) The population density distribution,
therefore, replicates that which emerges in the decentralized
equilibrium. The presence of county taxes, however, does distort the
consumption of housing services relative to other types of consumption.
We argue that local government should finance infrastructure by charging
developers a lump sum proffer per housing unit rather than relying on
property taxes. Some localities in Virginia charge proffers. We show
that their approach can actually help implement the first best solution
in the decentralized setting.
The social planner looks to maximize the utility of households in
the county, as given by
[M.summation over (i=1)][N.sub.i][(1 -
[[delta].sub.i])[g.sub.i]][.sup.[theta]][c.sub.i.sup.1-[theta]]. (16)
The only constraints faced by the planner are the county's
resource constraint,
[M.summation over (i=1)][N.sub.i][c.sub.i] + [M.summation over
(i=1)][N.sub.i][x.sub.i] + [M.summation over (i=1)][PHI]([A.sub.i]) =
[lambda][M.summation over (i=1)][N.sub.i], (17)
and the requirement that population in regions open to development
add up to county population, (12). The middle term on the left-hand side
of (17) captures the resource costs, in units of the traded good,
associated with the county-wide provision of housing services, where
[x.sub.i] is implicitly defined by the technology in (3).
The planner's optimal choice of regional traded good
consumption, [c.sub.i], local good consumption, [g.sub.i], and regional
population, [N.sub.i], are respectively given by
(1 - [theta])[(1 -
[[delta].sub.i])[g.sub.i]][.sup.[theta]][c.sub.i.sup.-[theta]] =
[[mu].sub.2], (18)
[theta][(1 - [[delta].sub.i])[g.sub.i]][.sup.[theta]-1](1 -
[[delta].sub.i])[c.sub.i.sup.1-[theta]] =
[[mu].sub.2][gamma]([N.sub.i]/[A.sub.i])[.sup.[eta]], (19)
and
[(1 - [[delta].sub.i])[g.sub.i]][.sup.[theta]][c.sub.i.sup.1-[theta]] + [[mu].sub.2][[lambda] - [c.sub.i] - [gamma](1 +
[eta])([N.sub.i]/[A.sub.i])[.sup.[eta]][g.sub.i]] - [[mu].sub.1] = 0,
(20)
where [[mu].sub.1] [greater than or equal to] 0 and [[mu].sub.2]
[greater than or equal to] 0 are the Lagrange multipliers associated
with constraints (12) and (17).
We now demonstrate that the planner's solution entails the
same distribution of population across regions as that found in the
decentralized equilibrium. To see this, observe first from (14) that the
decentralized allocation of individuals across regions can be summarized
by
(1 - [[delta].sub.j])[[gamma].sup.-1]([N.sub.j]/[A.sub.j])[.sup.-[eta]] = (1 - [[delta].sub.i])[[gamma].sup.-1]([N.sub.i]/[A.sub.i])[.sup.-[eta]] [for all]i and j [member of] M. (21)
Under the optimal solution, we can use equations (18) and (19) to
show that
(1 - [theta])[theta](1 -
[[delta].sub.i])[[gamma].sup.-1]([N.sub.i]/[A.sub.i])[.sup.-[eta]] =
[[mu].sub.2.sup.[1/[theta]]] [for all]i [member of] M. (22)
Since [[mu].sub.2] is constant across regions, equation (22)
implies (21), and the optimal allocation of individuals across locations
replicates that of the decentralized equilibrium. Because in our model,
congestion externalities reduce the production efficiency of housing
services locally, individuals who move and congest a given region have
to pay higher prices for housing services in that region. As in
Chatterjee and Carlino (2001), the formulation of local externalities
seems to us more reasonable than one where a region's density
decreases the production efficiency of housing services in another area
that is potentially much further away. (6)
It remains that in the decentralized equilibrium, the presence of
taxes on housing services distorts the allocation of consumption between
the traded and local good. In our model, this distortion is small and
results only in a 0.2 percent loss in welfare when measured in terms of
the aggregate consumption basket, [C.sub.i]. However, we now argue that
allowing localities to charge developers a lump sum proffer to finance
public infrastructure can help remove the distortion altogether.
Using Lump Sum Proffers as a Means to Finance Infrastructure
The main trouble with county taxes, as depicted in (7), is that
they are proportional to housing services--and thus housing
values--which leads to suboptimal decentralized allocations. In other
words, individuals in every locality are led to consume less housing
services than they otherwise would absent taxes. Historically, however,
localities in Virginia have had the ability to accept voluntary lump sum
cash proffers from residential developers, independent of the quantity
of housing services they provide. (7) The courts in Virginia have held
that the absence of "voluntary" payments cannot be the sole
reason for denying zoning or rezoning. However, many counties, including
Loudoun, publicize the recommended proffers per residential housing unit
constructed. In a setting where a new area is opened to development, all
houses constructed would be subject to a lump sum proffer. In the case
of opening a new area to housing, zoning, or rezoning action would be
necessary so that proffers could apply to all housing.
We now show that, in the decentralized equilibrium, these proffers
would simply be passed on to consumers, provided developers operate in a
competitive market. More importantly, because they are
non-distortionary, using these proffers in lieu of property taxes would
allow the market equilibrium to replicate the social optimum.
Suppose that each county locality charges developers a cash
proffer, [[product].sub.i], per housing unit that is unrelated to the
amount of housing services they sell, [G.sub.i]. (8) In equilibrium,
these cash proffers have to be such that [[summation].sub.i=1.sup.M]
[N.sub.i][[product].sub.i] = [[summation].sub.i=1.sup.M]
[PHI]([A.sub.i]) to maintain the feasibility of areas open to
development. Let R([G.sub.i]) = [p.sub.i][G.sub.i] + [[LAMBDA].sub.i]
denote a developer's revenue from selling [G.sub.i] units of
housing services in locality i. Developers are assumed to operate in a
competitive market, and we allow for any pricing rule that enables firms
to charge both a price per unit of housing services, [p.sub.i], and a
fixed amount, [[LAMBDA].sub.i], that could potentially be zero. (9)
From (3), a developer's profits in terms of the traded good
are given by
R([G.sub.i]) - [gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]][G.sub.i] -
[[product].sub.i]. (23)
It is then easy to see that the pricing rule whereby firms charge
[gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]] per unit of housing services and pass on the
entire cash proffer to consumers constitutes a unique equilibrium
pricing rule. First, to see why it is an equilibrium rule, observe that
a firm with a pricing strategy such that R([G.sub.i]) >
[gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]][G.sub.i] + [[product].sub.i] would have no
customers. Other firms would be able to charge slightly less and capture
the entire demand while still making at least zero profits. On the other
hand, a pricing rule that yielded revenues less than
[gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]][G.sub.i] + [[product].sub.i] would have the
firm make negative profits and is not sustainable. Therefore, in
equilibrium, firm revenues have to be exactly [gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]]
+ [[product].sub.i]. Second, to see why {[p.sub.i], [[LAMBDA].sub.i]} =
{[gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]], [[product].sub.i]} [for all]i [member of] M
represents a unique equilibrium pricing rule, consider any other
strategy, [~.p.sub.i] = [gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]] + [epsilon],
[epsilon] [??] 0 and [~.[LAMBDA].sub.i]. Because total revenue must be
[gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]] + [[product].sub.i] in equilibrium, a firm
that charges [~.p.sub.i] per unit of housing services would have to
adjust the fixed portion of its pricing strategy such that
[~.[LAMBDA].sub.i] = [[product].sub.i] - [epsilon][G.sub.i]. But this
contradicts the notion that [~.[LAMBDA].sub.i] is independent of
[G.sub.i]. Therefore, the rule whereby firms charge marginal cost per
unit of housing services and pass on the entire cash proffer required by
the county to individuals is the only equilibrium pricing rule. (10)
Of course, the main point here is that faced with this pricing
rule, individuals' budget constraint (7) in the decentralized
county economy becomes
([p.sub.i][g.sub.i] + [[LAMBDA].sub.i]) + [c.sub.i] [less than or
equal to] w. (24)
Hence, their consumption of housing services is no longer distorted
relative to other types of consumption, and the decentralized
equilibrium can achieve the first best solution. Observe that while
individuals pay more for housing services relative to the previous
section, they no longer have to pay taxes on housing services. In fact,
since all that matters in terms of providing county-wide infrastructure
and its operation is that its costs be covered by cash proffers
collected from developers, [[summation].sub.i=1.sup.M] [PHI]([A.sub.i])
= [[summation].sub.i=1.sup.M] [N.sub.i] [[product].sub.i], the county
can design a regional distribution of proffers such that the difference
between what individuals now pay for housing services and what they paid
in the previous section exactly equals what they were originally
spending in property taxes, [[LAMBDA].sub.i] = [[product].sub.i] =
[tau][p.sub.i][g.sub.i]. There is no sense, therefore, in which this
proffer-based policy would ultimately end up being more costly to
individuals.
If proffers allow counties to offset the cost of infrastructure and
its operation associated with new housing, why is zoning still used
along with proffers in Loudoun County? The answer lies in the legal
restrictions associated with proffers. Legally, proffers can be used to
offset fully or partially only the capital costs of infrastructure, not
operating costs. In the case of schools, for example, the operating cost
is a substantial portion of the total cost, meaning that proffers will
not overcome the fixed cost problem discussed earlier. Without the
ability to use proffers to offset infrastructure costs fully, counties
resort to zoning to limit the fiscal impact of rising population.
3. SUMMARY REMARKS
Rapidly increasing population in formerly rural counties on the
fringe of urban areas has strained local governments' ability to
provide infrastructure, raising congestion levels. The difficulty in
providing adequate infrastructure lies in the fixed cost nature of
infrastructure production as well as political and legal restrictions on
localities' ability to raise revenue. Using a simple model of
locational choice, we find that local officials could best balance
population and infrastructure through a lump-sum proffer fee on
developers. Provided that the market in which developers operate is
competitive, this impact fee is likely to be passed onto users of
housing services. This approach has the well-known advantage of being
non-distortionary with respect to individuals' consumption
decisions. Alternatively, balancing infrastructure and population can be
achieved through setting an appropriate real property tax, though this
approach introduces distortions into individuals' consumption
decisions, leaving them with less aggregate consumption than with lump
sum fees.
In addition, we find that legal and political restrictions on
county officials' use of proffers and real property taxes have led
them to the use of zoning in practice. Given the substantial fixed costs
associated with infrastructure provision and the use of zoning, rising
population leads to increased congestion before the number of households
reaches a high enough threshold to make it feasible to open up a new
land area. Ultimately, however, zoning remains an inefficient means to
address localities' infrastructure and population issues. A more
efficient solution would be to lessen restrictions on localities'
use of proffers and their ability to raise revenue more generally.
Although Loudoun County, Virginia, has been used as a case study
for calibration of our model, the framework set out in this paper should
be broadly applicable to the problem associated with rising population
in many areas of the United States. Indeed, the fixed cost aspect of
infrastructure provision combined with restrictions on localities'
ability to raise revenue appear to be applicable to localities broadly.
Table 1 Model Parameters
Calibrated Benchmark Value
Parameters
Preferences
[theta] Housing share of
income 0.25%
Technology
[lambda] Per capita income $50,238
[gamma] Scalar in density
congestion 93.41
[eta] Curvature in
density congestion 0.49
Geography
[[delta].sub.i] Commuting costs [0.09, 0.11, 0.14, 0.17,
0.23]
[A.sub.i] Land area (square
miles) [5.7, 8.2, 13.2, 27.3, 116.4]
N Population 139,873
Table 2 Model and Data Statistics
Population Distribution
Loudoun County [24,227; 29,265; 25,226; 29,348; 31,807]
Model [24,231; 29,238; 25,235; 29,375; 31,791]
Density Distribution
Loudoun County [208.21; 1,072.71; 1,909.35; 3,563.51;
5,613.52]
Model [208.24; 1,071.79; 1,910.36; 3,569.32;
5,616.88]
Average Housing Prices
Loudoun County $427,199
Model $435,279
Household Property Taxes
Loudoun County $4,613.00
Model $4,701.00
(1) For a history and more detailed description of the Dillon rule,
see Writ (1989).
(2) Although Loudoun has the legal authority to assess taxes
against real and personal property and to accept proffers on housing
created by new rezoning actions, officials stress that pressure from
residents of the county and from state-level legislators limit their
ability to raise these taxes to levels that would cover the cost and
operation of infrastructure. Furthermore, the addition of new debt by
the county is constrained by any deterioration in the county's
revenue-expense ratio. The county finance director states that a less
favorable ratio reduces the county's debt rating.
(3) According to the 2000 Census, in total, Loudoun County collects
$300 million in real property taxes, approximately $223 million of
which, close to the model's prediction, comes from the eastern,
developed portion of the county.
(4) Recall that all individuals have the same utility in
equilibrium, [C.sub.i] = [C.sub.j] [for all]i, j [member of] M.
(5) This is also the case in Chatterjee and Carlino (2001).
(6) Note that the social optimum would yield population allocations
different than those given by the decentralized equilibrium if
congestion had an effect on commuting costs.
(7) In practice, these proffers can only be raised following zoning
or rezoning actions.
(8) Observe that housing units can be of different sizes, our proxy
for [G.sub.i]. Furthermore, an implicit assumption here is that each
individual requires one housing unit, although individuals can combine
into households.
(9) Since our model is static and does not distinguish between
housing stock built at different dates, we think of [[LAMBDA].sub.i] as
the yearly amount corresponding to the capitalized proffer value that a
developer would be charged at the time of construction.
(10) Observe also that any two-part pricing strategy that
successfully attracts customers away from {[p.sub.i], [[LAMBDA].sub.i]}
= {[gamma][d.sub.i.sup.[eta]], [[product].sub.i]} necessarily yields
negative profits.
REFERENCES
Chatterjee, S., and G. Carlino. 2001. "Aggregate Metropolitan
Employment Growth and the Deconcentration of Metropolitan
Employment." Journal of Monetary Economics 48 (December): 549-83.
Henderson, V. 1987. "General Equilibrium Modeling of
Cities." In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, vol. II:
Urban Economics. Ed. E.S. Mills. New York: New Holland.
Loudoun County Office of Mapping and Geographic Information.
http://www.loudoun.gov/omagi/index.htm (accessed December 23, 2003).
Meeting with Loudoun County Officials (Ben Mays of Loudoun County
Management Services and Clark Draper, Sean LaCroix, and Cindy Richmond
of the Loudoun County Department of Economic Development), Leesburg,
Virginia. August 2, 2003.
Milligan, J. 2003. "Showdown in Loudoun." Virginia
Business (April): 8-13.
Sowell, T. 2001. "Property Rights." Townhall.com.
http://www.townhall.com/columnists/thomassowell/ts20010809.shtml
(accessed December 23, 2003).
U.S. Census Bureau. "United States Census 2000."
http://www.census.gov/main/www/cen2000.html (accessed December 23,
2003).
Writ, Clay L. 1989. "Dillon's Rule." Virginia Town
and City 24 (8): 12-15.
We wish to thank Yongsung Chang, Tom Humphrey, Daniel Tatar, and
John Weinberg for many helpful comments on an earlier draft. We also
thank Ben Mays, Clark Draper, Sean LaCroix, and Cindy Richmond for
providing us with clarity on the issues facing and policies of Loudoun
County. In addition, we greatly appreciate the research assistance
provided by Elliot Martin and Matt Harris. Any errors are our own. The
views expressed in this article do not necessarily represent those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.