Credit exclusion in quantitative models of bankruptcy: does it matter?
Athreya, Kartik B. ; Janicki, Hubert P.
Why is there unsecured lending? Given that borrowers seem to have
essentially no obvious incentive to repay under the generous provisions
afforded them by U.S. consumer bankruptcy law, why would anyone make an
unsecured loan? One answer is that borrowers are actually providing a
more intangible form of collateral, such as their reputation or
"good name." Such an answer is problematic, however. In
particular, can households credibly bind themselves to agreements to
which they may later have little interest in keeping? What about
lenders? In particular, notice that lenders themselves have no incentive
to act "punitively" after a bankruptcy filing. This is because
if there are gains from renewed trade, any lender that
"renegotiates" with borrowers will profit. In other words, in
a competitive setting, the only reasonable changes in credit terms are
those warranted by a change in assessing the likelihood of repayment.
Perhaps the most natural representation of the destruction of a
reputational form of capital in unsecured loan markets is the reduction
in the "credit score" that typically follows a bankruptcy
filing. Thus, if neither borrowers nor lenders can credibly promise to
forgo mutually beneficial transactions after a default, there would seem
to be little hope for unsecured credit. And yet, a great deal of such
credit exists, in an amount that currently exceeds $1 trillion!
The thorny issues raised above have, in large measure, been avoided
by quantitatively oriented researchers. Instead, they typically assume
that a penalty for default is exclusion from future borrowing, at least
temporarily. However, for such analysis, the effects of exclusion on
borrowing and lending depend on the precise specification of the income
paths facing households. To understand why, assume first, as economists
since Friedman (1957) have, that households use credit markets to
"smooth" consumption. That is, they wish to shield consumption
from changes in income. Smoothing occurs both in response to predicted
changes in income as well as to unforeseen ones. The value of credit
markets, in turn, depends on what households ask of them. Notably, if
income risk is large and extremely persistent, or permanent, the
household has little choice but to reduce consumption when hit with a
negative shock. In such a case, the value of access to the credit
markets may be quite low. If, instead, shocks are small or primarily
transitory, borrowing will be an effective bulwark. It is the latter
case in which the assumption of exclusion following bankruptcy would
have the most bite. Thus, both households facing large and possibly
infrequent shocks, as well as those facing small but frequent shocks may
find the inability to borrow quite painful. Because the quantitative
role of exclusion following bankruptcy may depend on the precise
specification of income risks faced by households, the relevant question
is: In recent quantitative models of bankruptcy, what role does credit
exclusion play?
The two central contributions of this article are to (1) take a
first step in evaluating the commonly used (but rarely justified)
assumption in recent models of unsecured household borrowing of credit
that defaulting borrowers get exiled and (2) quantitatively examine the
role of exclusion in affecting the sharp rise of both debt and
bankruptcy observed in the 1990s. We consider a simple model of consumer
borrowing and lending developed in Athreya (2002, 2004). This model
shares enough with other recent work to be useful in gleaning insights
about exclusion. We organize our results around three experiments. In
the first two, we investigate the extent to which reductions in
exclusion-related penalties matter for post-bankruptcy asset
accumulation under a variety of income processes. In the third
experiment, we ask whether these changes generate outcomes consistent
with recent observations on aggregates, such as the bankruptcy rate and
debt discharged in bankruptcy.
Specifically, we proceed in two steps. First, we simulate
counterfactual exclusionary periods precisely to understand the extent
to which exclusion matters. Second, we link the length of credit
exclusion to the level of competition in the unsecured lending market.
The experiments performed in the first step will inform us as to the
inherent "plausibility" of exclusion as a credible phenomenon.
That is, if exclusion is found to be a "binding" constraint,
then households value borrowing and would, in the absence of other
constraints, be able to renegotiate loans with lenders. It has been
observed that a high level of competition in the unsecured credit market
makes purely punitive exclusion increasingly unlikely. This trend stems
from a reduction in search and switching costs for households. We employ
the intuition that while punitive exclusion may be sustainable with a
few lenders, it will not be with a large number of them.
Our central findings are twofold. First, we find that exclusion
from credit markets alone seems insufficient to explain current
repayment rates on unsecured debt. Second, we observe that a reduction
in exclusion-related penalties for bankruptcy arising from technological
changes in the 1990s is consistent with both growth in debt and personal
bankruptcy.
One consideration that we address is the reason for borrowing. In
particular, the nature of income shocks determines not only the
usefulness of borrowing, but also the misery inflicted by exclusion.
Consider an example in which a household faces minimal and transitory
uncertainty nearly all of the time, but is nonetheless prone to
prolonged spells of relatively low income. In such a world, the
household may choose to borrow and may hold substantial debt at the time
that the "long-term" shock occurs. In this situation, the
household may not value highly the option to borrow, simply because the
shock is expected to last a long time, thereby altering the present
value of future earnings nontrivially. In this setting, the household
will not care greatly that it will be excluded if it defaults. More
troubling is that we may not be able to easily disentangle a reduced
need to borrow after bankruptcy from a willful imposition of exclusion
by creditors. Both causes have similar symptoms.
What Is Exclusion?
The sanctions assumed in recent work range from infinitely long
periods of autarky for defaulters to relatively short periods where only
borrowing is prohibited and saving is allowed. The former penalties have
been used extensively to evaluate the best possible risk-sharing
arrangements that are sustainable given a party's ability to walk
away from contracts at any time. In these settings, default does not
occur in equilibrium. These studies dismiss the issue of whether the
penalties are credible. However, for their purposes, permanent autarky
may be appropriate as a harsh punishment that allows for a bound of
sorts on risk sharing under limited commitment. By contrast, when
attempting to capture costs of default in the U.S. credit market,
exclusion appears less plausible because of the coexistence of finite
penalties and default.
Purely temporary exclusion has been an attractive modeling device
for recent quantitative work, such as Athreya (2002, 2004) and
Chatterjee et al. (2005) on unsecured consumer debt, and Yue (2005),
Aguiar and Gopinath (2005), and Sapriza and Cuadra (2005) on sovereign
debt. Nonetheless, such exclusion is not easily supported and deserves
more justification than has been provided. In particular, a key problem
is that in choosing to punish default ex post by exclusion, lenders and
borrowers forgo opportunities for mutually beneficial trade that exist
after default. In other words, once default has taken place,
"bygones should be bygones"; the parties should recontract and
move on. However, the possibility of recontracting itself undermines the
initial obligation of the borrower to commit to repay. Unless the lender
can somehow credibly threaten to cut off the borrower from all
creditors, the problem is not easily circumvented.
One case where exclusion may be plausible occurs when a single, or
small number of, creditors may be able to coordinate to sustain ex post
exclusion as a credible threat. Furthermore, it is possible, even with a
large number of creditors and an infinite horizon, to construct systems
of beliefs among market participants such that exclusion becomes
sensible ex post. These belief systems are, however, not immune to
criticism. In the subsequent section, we discuss an example where
assumptions regarding these beliefs rationalize, at one level, the
presence of unsecured debt. Nevertheless, the lack of discipline imposed
on "off-equilibrium" beliefs can make ex post exclusion
inefficient.
There is a good deal at stake in understanding the nature of
penalties for default on unsecured debt. From an efficiency standpoint,
limits to commitment, along with private information, are the prime
suspects in the limited risk sharing we observe in the world around us.
Moreover, since exclusion does not involve transfers of resources across
parties, these penalties are socially wasteful ex post. Thus, unless
offset by their ability to sustain better risk sharing, deadweight
penalties should be regarded with concern. From a distributional
standpoint, there is perhaps even more at stake; it is reasonable to
suspect that the income-poorest are often the young, who, in turn, are
wealth-poor. Therefore, the inability to commit to repayment affects
this subgroup most profoundly, while leaving untouched those who may
post collateral such as home equity.
Recent Changes in the Unsecured Credit Market
Our interest in the potential implication of changes in the
competitiveness of the unsecured credit market is derived from the
seminal studies of Ausubel (1991) and Calem and Mester (1995). These
studies confirmed the popular view of many that, in the late 1980s and
early 1990s, the U.S. market for unsecured credit was an imperfectly
competitive marketplace in which rational lenders systematically earned
supernormal profits. We now examine some well-publicized changes in the
structure of unsecured lending and assess its role in driving the even
more well-publicized increases in household debt and bankruptcy. We
divide our focus into two broad periods: the 1980s and the 1990s to the
present.
The 1980s
The most important article in this relatively large body of
literature might be that of Ausubel (1991), who argues on empirical
grounds that as of the late 1980s, returns in unsecured credit markets
were highly supernormal. Moreover, and more intriguing, was that the
market seemed to offer a near textbook case of perfect competition. In
particular, Ausubel documents that there were in excess of 4,000 lenders
and that free entry seemed possible. In particular, Ausubel (1991) notes
that the ten largest lenders accounted for only two-fifths of market
share and therefore could not be said to monopolize the market. The
returns to credit card lending grow even more puzzling as it is
difficult to find any evidence of overt collusion or price fixing. One
finding in particular has spurred substantial analysis, namely, the
feature that credit card interest rates are remarkably insensitive to
changes in the measured cost of funds. In conclusion, Ausubel (1991)
suggests three possibilities for the observed behavior of the credit
card market. First, he allows for departures from standard consumer
rationality, and argues that in a setting with irrational households
that systematically underestimate their own likelihood of carrying
credit card balances, lenders may be able to earn supernormal profits.
Second, Ausubel allows for search and switching costs to reflect several
hurdles that lie in front of those wishing to switch credit cards.
Lastly, Ausubel suggests that asymmetric information regarding the
default risk of borrowers could make it difficult to control risk using
interest rates. In particular, a fall in the rate offered by a lender
might simply attract a disproportionate response from those most likely
to default, and would generate only indifference from low-risk
households that often did not carry balances on which they paid
interest. In this setting, one might reasonably expect retail interest
rates to move far less in response to changes in funding costs than when
more was known about cardholders.
An important article that pursues the conjectures of Ausubel (1991)
in explaining credit card interest-rate stickiness is that of Calem and
Mester (1994). These authors conclude that all three aspects of
Ausubel's reasoning receive empirical support when data from
individual consumers (from the Survey of Consumer Finances) is used.
Notably, Calem and Mester do find a significant role for the effect of
both search and switching costs. One of the costs they note that is that
while borrowers provide real-time information on their financial
situation through their repayment behavior, credit bureau data in the
1980s was not updated as frequently. In turn, while lenders had measures
of the risk posed by their own cardholders, this risk was only partially
revealed, as it did not reveal the behavior of the same individual with
respect to other accounts, nor the risk posed by new account holders.
More subtly, as noted by Calem and Mester (1995), high switch costs can
independently limit the value of search, leading again to stickiness in
interest rates.
The 1990s to the Present
The preceding work deals with a period immediately prior to a
noticeable change in technology for intermediation. As documented by
Furletti (2003), FDIC (2004), and Edelberg (2003), the use of
large-scale credit scoring and intensive data mining led to large
changes in the growth of information available to lenders. In turn,
search costs fell. Notably, to the extent that search could be initiated
by either buyer or seller, a major change in the 1990s was the growth of
massive preapproved, direct-mail solicitation. Figure 1 (all figures
appear at the end of this article) shows that even a casual viewing of
the data makes clear that an important "regime change"
occurred in the early 1990s. To the extent that technological advances
mitigated adverse selection, price-based completion grew more
attractive. Indeed, Furletti (2003) and Edelberg (2003) argue that these
changes paved the way for much more detailed pricing strategies according to cardholder risk. (1) Perhaps the most interesting aspect
about the 1990s was the growth of debt and bankruptcy to unprecedented
levels.
The facts documented above for the 1990s can be expected to result
in a reduction or elimination of exclusion. Moreover, these changes may
be expected to first generate a transitional period during which
repayment rates on credit contracts issued prior to the early 1990s did
not reflect the intensifying competition. Additionally, in the longer
run, we might expect a "supply side" response leading to a
repricing of terms to accommodate this new reality. The first period
might well be associated with increased borrowing and default, while in
the longer run, the repricing of the riskier loans might led to a fall
in default rates (all else equal). Once again, the preceding experiment
is only partially a natural one because of the simultaneous change in
the technology of credit intermediation. Athreya (2004) explores the
effects of a fall in transactions costs on borrowing and default and
finds that it accounted well for the period between 1991 and 1997. In
this article, we abstract from technological advances and focus
exclusively on the aggregate consequences of reductions in credit
exclusion for debt, bankruptcy, and credit supply.
The article is organized as follows. In Section 1, we document some
recent empirical evidence on the consequences of bankruptcy. We also
briefly present a theoretical model and some quantitative theory to
review the standard approach to incorporating credibility of ex post
punishment and use of assets for consumption smoothing. Section 2
presents a simple model and evidence from counterfactual experiments to
examine the extent to which household behavior is dictated by exclusion
and income. In Section 3, we extend the model to address the effects of
exclusion on the aggregate unsecured credit market. Section 4 concludes.
1. BACKGROUND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE AND THEORY
Consequences of Bankruptcy: Empirical Evidence
Several recent articles have gathered empirical evidence that
argues that bankruptcy blights a credit score. Stavins (2000) finds that
having been turned down for credit makes one substantially more likely
to have filed for bankruptcy in the past. Relatedly, and perhaps as a
consequence, bankruptcy filers are less likely to hold at least one
credit card if they have filed for bankruptcy in the past. These two
observations are suggestive, but they do not have an unambiguous
interpretation of forcible "exclusion" from credit markets.
Ideally, what one would like to know is the probability of rejection
given a past bankruptcy. Instead, what we know from Stavins (2000) is
the probability of having filed a bankruptcy given that one is rejected
for credit. The second observation is perhaps more informative, as the
absence of a credit card means that households have foregone the
potential transactions-related benefits of convenience associated with
credit cards. On the other hand, the growth of debit cards allows for
access to the payment network of Visa, Mastercard, and others without
the need for a credit card. Moreover, the quantitative differences
between those with a prior bankruptcy and those without are not so
large. In particular, Stavins (2000) finds that the mean number of
credit cards held by those with a past bankruptcy was 2.91, while it was
3.58 for those without a bankruptcy. This also calls into question the
extent to which bankruptcy filers are truly "excluded." Among
the strongest findings in Stavins (2000) is that a past bankruptcy was
predictive of future delinquency. This suggests that something
systematic characterizes bankruptcy filers that warrants differentially
strict treatment, such as more frequent rejections in credit
application. Once again, the data do not speak with one voice, because
the interest rates faced by those having filed averaged only one
percentage point more than those who had not. Thus, conditional on
obtaining an unsecured credit card loan, past bankruptcy filers appear
not to be paying a great premium.
In the United States, credit bureaus are important institutions
that aggregate debt and repayment data across consumers and over time.
In the scoring models most commonly used, such as Fair Isaac & Co.
(FICO), the leading issuer of credit scores, repayment history is a
major determinant of score. In turn, scores are interpreted by lenders
as measures of risk, implying that the drop in credit score triggered by
bankruptcy leads to at least temporary repricing and possibly exclusion
from unsecured borrowing.
In addition to Stavins, another important reference in the
literature on post-bankruptcy credit extension is that of Musto (2004),
who exploits a natural experiment created by laws limiting the length of
time a bankruptcy may be retained on a credit record to ten years. The
main finding of the latter is that for more "creditworthy"
households, the removal of a past bankruptcy from a credit record has an
immediate and economically significant effect on household indebtedness.
When those with high and medium credit ratings were studied, as measured
by FICO, the average credit lines jumped in the tenth year from $2,810
to $4,578.
Lastly, Fisher, Filer, and Lyons (2000) study a panel of households
that have filed for bankruptcy, and they argue that the consumption of
this group is somewhat more sensitive to income than in the period
preceding the filing. This is consistent with borrowing constraints
binding in the post-bankruptcy period. Furthermore, the authors find
that after five years beyond the removal of the bankruptcy from a credit
record, consumption ceases to be excessively sensitive to income. Again,
this is consistent with bankruptcy leading to a temporary cutoff from
unsecured credit markets.
Exclusion in Theory: A Simple Example
Given the observation that sovereign debt and unsecured consumer
debt markets both exist, work on supporting punishments as credible
threats has occupied the time and imagination of theorists for some
time. A textbook example of such a system of beliefs is taken from
Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995, Ch. 6, 376-77). In this example, there are a
large number of a risk-averse nations facing uncertain country-specific
output. However, all shocks to output are uncorrelated across countries,
and there is, therefore, the possibility for complete insurance.
However, it is also assumed that each nation may walk away with its
current income at any time. The only penalty is a permanent exclusion
from credit markets. The key question is whether such a punishment can
be credible. Below is a set of beliefs and strategies that generate
credibility. If country A is to be penalized by the others, (1) it must
be that country A has no reputation for repayment, and (2) all other
countries lose their own reputations for repayment by dealing with
country A. Note that without clause (2), a country could default and
then buy an insurance contract against income risk by putting up money
up front, thereby removing all credit risk. With clause (2) in place, no
defaulting country would dare send money to a country that agreed to
insure it. This is also beneficial because it confirms the beliefs held
by the nondefaulters about country A. Namely, since country A believes
that any insurer B will default at the first chance, country A will
default on any obligations it has to country B. In turn, country B would
be optimizing by seizing any payments by country A.
What is notable about this example is not so much that punishments
may be sustained, but that they depend intricately on the systems of
beliefs held by market participants. Moreover, to the extent that we do
not have definitive means of winnowing the sets of beliefs that are
"plausible," such resolutions are somewhat troubling. There is
also a more serious problem, namely that of "renegotiation."
In particular, even though the threats specified above are credible in
that they remain in the interest of countries to impose ex post, they
are not immune to renegotiations. We now examine a problem with the
belief system discussed above. In particular, all the gains from trade
that could be realized between the parties go unrealized. In the
preceding example, the problem arises because even though the
specification of beliefs makes it sensible for the borrower to take the
threat of exclusion seriously, the actual imposition of the threat ex
post is inefficient for all parties. This creates incentives for all
parties, not just the ones that have experienced default, to create
other contractual arrangements beyond those rendered unworkable given
people's beliefs. As a result, one might expect that ex ante, the
threat of exclusion will once again become ineffective to sustain risk
sharing.
Value of Asset Markets in Quantitative Theory
To obtain an initial measure of the value of assets for smoothing,
and thereby the pressure not to impose exclusion ex post, we turn now to
a canonical model of savings and consumption taken from Deaton (1991). A
broad lesson of this work is that temporary shocks will generally be
smoothed via borrowing and savings, while persistent, or permanent,
shocks will not.
To make things clearer, consider a household that maximizes the
following objective:
[E.sub.0][[infinity].summation over (t=0)][[beta].sup.t]
[[[c.sub.t.sup.1-[kappa]] - 1]/[1 - [kappa]]].
In the preceding, consumption in period t is given by [c.sub.t],
[beta] is the discount factor, and [kappa] specifies risk aversion. The
latter is a key parameter governing the extent to which households
borrow to keep consumption smooth in the face of shocks. The objective
function is maximized subject to the constraints
c + [a'/[1 + r]] [less than or equal to] y + a
a' [greater than or equal to] 0,
where y denotes income from sources other than wealth, a, and r
denotes the interest rate. Notice that there is a restriction that
a' [greater than or equal to] 0, ruling out borrowing. However, the
exercise is still instructive because our primary goal is to understand
the effect of limits on the decumulation of wealth, with an exclusion
from borrowing being a special case. If we now specify a simple AR(1)
income process
[y.sub.t] - [bar.y] = [phi]([y.sub.t-1] - [bar.y]) +
[[epsilon].sub.t],
where
[[epsilon].sub.t] ~ N (0, [sigma]),
we obtain Table 1 from Deaton (1991).
Notice that as shocks become more persistent, households choose not
to smooth shocks. The ratio of the standard deviation of consumption to
that of income grows systematically with the persistence of shocks to
income. The intuition here is that highly persistent negative shocks,
for example, have a grave impact on lifetime income. To the extent that
it is lifetime income that determines in large part the long-run average
level of consumption, a large downward revision demands a reduction in
average consumption. In other words, households will generally be
unwilling to borrow against a greatly diminished future income just to
avoid today the anticipated pain of a bad event. By contrast, a highly
persistent positive shock implies a relatively large upward revision in
future income prospects. In light of this, households will reduce their
indebtedness or increase their savings. Lastly, take the extreme case
where the shocks to income are permanent. An example of this is a
"raise" in salary that also resets the "base" at
which future raises are computed. In this case, the positive shock may
lead to borrowing in anticipation of future good times. At the other
extreme, if a permanent bad shock occurs, households may actually
increase their savings to allow them to make the transition more
smoothly to a permanently lower level of income.
The implications of this example for a world with bankruptcy are
noteworthy. In particular, it matters a great deal whether one lives in
a world of highly persistent income risk. If so, credit markets are not
useful to households anyway, and credit exclusion is not painful. In
short, the incentives to default for any given debt level are relatively
large when compared to a world of less persistent income risk. On the
other hand, the usefulness of bankruptcy in such a setting is less
obvious. After all, little smoothing can be done via borrowing in such
an environment. Ironically, exclusion may be "sustainable" in
this setting simply because there is not much at stake for creditors in
imposing it.
With more transitory shocks, however, the incentives to borrow for
consumption smoothing are relatively large, and the threat carried by a
credible promise of exclusion following default is meaningful.
Nonetheless, ex post exclusion hurts the household precisely because it
values borrowing and raises the issue of the credibility of an
exclusion. Credibility is even more implausible when it is assumed to be
imposed by a highly competitive industry where consumers are well aware
of competitors' terms and rates.
As we will see in the following section, the presence of default
makes the results above less obvious. In particular, one's
willingness to smooth even temporary disturbances may depend importantly
on the presence of longer-term shocks and the ability to default should
such shocks occur. Conversely, even a persistent shock may be smoothed
by a household that has access to a default option. In particular,
bankruptcy introduces an incentive to "gamble" that is not
otherwise present. In the present context, the household may gamble by
borrowing more than it otherwise would just to ensure a smooth
consumption path, knowing that bankruptcy is a possibility should poor
incomes continue. Of course, creditors will price such risk, and in the
end, households may choose not to borrow in equilibrium. Therefore, the
net effect of bankruptcy on the equilibrium willingness of households to
smooth shocks is not perfectly straightforward and remains a
quantitative issue.
2. THE BASIC MODEL
To study the effects of exclusion and the dependence of the effects
of exclusion on income risk, we now turn to the following model, taken
from Athreya (2004). Let there be a large number of infinitely lived
households with identical preferences given by
[E.sub.0][[infinity].summation over (t=0)][[beta].sup.t]
[[[c.sub.t.sup.1-[kappa]] - 1]/[1 - [kappa]]]. (1)
Households save in risk-free claims to consumption that mature in
the next period. Savings earns an interest rate of (1 + [r.sup.d]).
Households have the option of defaulting on debt. In each period, the
household chooses whether to file for bankruptcy. Bankruptcy is kept
simple and is assumed to remove all the debt of a household.
Bankruptcy generates two costs. Households must pay transactions
costs associated with legal proceedings, as well as have their utility
lowered by any stigma they may feel. Moreover, households are assumed to
be temporarily banned from borrowing. We denote the sum of all costs
that did not arise from credit exclusion by [lambda] and the length of
the average exclusionary period by [gamma]. The preceding structure
leads to the following set of value functions. (2)
At any date, households are either solvent, which we denote by S,
or "borrowing constrained" while excluded because of a past
bankruptcy, which we denote by BC.
The value of being solvent, [V.sup.S], must satisfy
[V.sup.S](y, a) = max[[W.sup.S](y, a), [W.sup.B](y, a)]. (2)
The value of repaying debt in the current period satisfies
[W.sup.S](e, a) = max{u(c) + [beta]E[V.sup.S](e', a')}
(3)
s.t.
c + [a'/[1 + [r.sup.l](a')]] [less than or equal to] y +
a. (4)
If a household files for bankruptcy, their debts are removed, and
they pay the transactions costs, [lambda].
In the period following a bankruptcy, the household is excluded
from borrowing, which means that the value, [V.sup.BC], from beginning
in this state is
[W.sup.B](e, a) = max{u(c) - [lambda] + [beta]E[V.sup.BC](a')}
(5)
s.t.
c + [a'/[1 + [r.sup.d]]] [less than or equal to] y. (6)
The exclusion from credit markets ends each period with
probability, [gamma], with the average restriction from borrowing
lasting 1/(1-[gamma]) periods. The value of this state is therefore
[V.sup.BC](y, a) = max{u(c) + [gamma][beta]E[V.sup.S](y',
a') + (1 - [gamma])[beta]E[V.sup.BC](y', a') (7)
s.t.
c + [a'/[1 + [r.sup.d]]] [less than or equal to] y + a. (8)
Let the default probability for a debt of d units be denoted
[[theta].sup.bk](a'). In equilibrium, economic profits must be
zero. Therefore, given the cost of funds for intermediaries, (1 +
[r.sup.d] + [tau]), where [tau] is a transactions cost that represents
recordkeeping and other operational expenses, the interest rate on loans
will be restricted to
[r.sup.l](a') = [(1 + [r.sup.d] + [tau])/(1 -
[[theta].sup.bk](a'))] - 1. (9)
Parameterization
With this simple model of consumer borrowing and bankruptcy, we
evaluate the interplay between income persistence, the size of income
shocks, the exclusionary period, and desired borrowing. We study five
income processes, which differ along two dimensions: the persistence of
shocks, denoted by [phi], and their variance, denoted by
[[sigma].sup.2]. The first process is our benchmark, taken from Athreya
(2004). It is an AR(1) process broadly consistent with panel data on
U.S. households and includes low income states that are interpretable as
"unemployment." For brevity, the reader is referred to Athreya
(2004) for details on the (discretized) version of this process. The key
parameters of that process are the mean level of income, [mu], which we
fix at unity, the variance among working households, set to 0.15, and
the serial correlation of income, set at 0.97. The remainder of the
processes involve changes in the variability persistence of income
shocks relative to the benchmark, where we hold mean income fixed. The
processes are summarized in Table 2. One period in the model represents
one quarter. The remaining parameters are given as [kappa] = 1 (which
implies logarithmic utility), [tau] = 0.0085, [beta] = 0.9865.
Using these processes, we simulate the income, consumption,
savings, and bankruptcy decisions of a large number of households. We
then evaluate household behavior immediately prior to, and following, a
bankruptcy filing. Specifically, we concentrate our attention to the 10
quarters preceding and 20 quarters following a bankruptcy. We study the
behavior of cross-sectional averages in each quarter of this 30-quarter
window. Our goal is to evaluate the extent that exclusion from credit
markets is actually a binding restriction that requires explanation. For
example, if, for the benchmark income process, removing exclusion did
not change post-bankruptcy debt accumulation, we would know that
exclusion cannot be an important deterrent to default. By contrast, if
removing exclusion did imply a substantial increase in post-bankruptcy
debt, we have evidence that exclusion matters.
For the remainder of this section, we focus on Figures 2-6. These
figures display the path of average quantities in the window around the
date of bankruptcy, where date 0 on the x-axis is the period of the
bankruptcy filing. The top panel in Figures 2-6 presents the results
where no post-bankruptcy exclusion is assumed. The middle panel in
Figures 2-6 contains results across the income process when exclusion is
set as in Athreya (2004) to an average of four years. By contrast, in
the bottom panel in Figures 2-6, we assume a lengthy exclusion of 25
years. For reasonable discount factors, exclusions of such high duration
generate outcomes similar to a truly permanent exclusion.
Experiment 1: Effects of Income Risk, Given Exclusion
We begin by holding exclusion, [gamma], and filing costs, [lambda],
fixed. We vary the income process in order to display the effects of
income volatility and persistence on asset accumulation and decumulation
before and after a bankruptcy. In the top panel of Figures 2-6, we set
[gamma] = 0 (no exclusion). When comparing the top panel across Figures
2-6, we see immediately that asset holdings are uniformly higher at all
dates under processes [Y.sup.1] and [Y.sup.3], both of which display
relatively low persistence, than under [Y.sup.2] or [Y.sup.4], both of
which display high persistence. The intuition here is the same as
presented earlier. Note first that the average income preceding a
bankruptcy is falling for the population. Given the mean-reversion
implicit in all the income processes under consideration, we see that on
average, after a filing, incomes rise again and then level off at their
long-term average. The positive income shocks that occur on average to
bankruptcy filers after they file are treated as temporary under
processes [Y.sup.1] and [Y.sup.3] and treated as somewhat more permanent
under the other two processes. In turn, the former save some of the
gains and accumulate a "buffer stock" of savings. The
relationship between persistence and asset holdings is robust and
survives in the middle and bottom panels of Figures 2-6 as well.
However, the behavior of assets across the income process grows more
similar as exclusion becomes longer lasting.
Experiment 2: Effects of Exclusion, Given Income Risk
We now turn to the experiment of central interest: the effect of
varying exclusion under a fixed income process. A comparison across
panels of each of Figures 2-6 shows that increased exclusion is met
after bankruptcy by increased asset accumulation. Preceding a
bankruptcy, asset paths are quite similar across exclusionary periods.
What is perhaps more important to see is that even when exclusion is
eliminated (top panel in Figures 2-6), households simply do not borrow
much after bankruptcy. This is true across all four income processes
considered here. It suggests that a valid interpretation of the
observation is that households are not simply excluded from borrowing;
rather they do not wish to borrow after bankruptcy.
One consideration worth mentioning is that our experiments consider
the equilibrium effect of changes in exclusion. Namely, households are
assumed to know, understand, and respond to the changes. In turn, note
that our results focus on the behavior of those in and around a
bankruptcy filing. Therefore, when exclusion becomes strict, it is
possible that we observe bankruptcy only in those circumstances when ex
post exclusion would be least painful, all else equal. For example,
consider a world with long exclusionary periods and both transitory and
long-lasting income shocks, such as the processes used here. In such a
setting, one might expect that bankruptcy becomes used predominantly
when debts are large and a persistent shock strikes, rather than when a
more transitory shock occurs. Our findings suggest that this effect is
unimportant, as average incomes at the time of filing are very similar
across Figures 2-6. In the discretized income process we employ, the
income level "triggering" bankruptcy is always the state we
associate with prolonged unemployment at a time when unemployment
insurance benefits no longer are provided.
A second issue is that even if the circumstances at the time of
filing are not affected strongly by bankruptcy, the rate at which people
file may be materially altered by credit exclusion. This happens in part
because debt accumulation overall may change significantly, making
exclusion important as a deterrent even when it leaves the proximate "cause" (i.e., the state of the household at the time of
filing) of bankruptcy unchanged. We address this issue next by
evaluating the effects of exclusion on aggregate unsecured credit-market
activity in terms of debt accumulation, bankruptcy rates, and loan
pricing. We also provide a first look at studying a narrative that
addresses recent technological changes that have reduced search and
switching costs for households and have led to greater effective
competition across lenders.
3. COMPETITION IN UNSECURED CREDIT MARKETS
Athreya (2004) proposes an explanation for events detailed above by
modeling technological advances by reductions in transactions costs and
finds that such changes produce outcomes broadly consistent with the
data. In the current work, we propose a different approach. Namely, we
emphasize in this article that while reductions in transactions costs
are part of the story, the fact that search and switching costs in
particular have fallen may resurrect the credibility problem faced by
unsecured lenders. In other words, a borrower who has defaulted now has
an easier time communicating his risk to prospective lenders, as better
credit bureau data are available to lenders. Moreover, a borrower may
more easily evaluate the quality of offers from a very wide range of
solicitors both because he receives roughly five times as many offers in
the late 1990s as he did in the late 1980s, and also because disclosure
regulations such as the "Schumer Box" allow for easy
comparisons of rates and terms. These changes, in turn, must begin to
force lenders to "treat bygones as bygones." Therefore, the
only remaining rationale for treating bankruptcy filers like "hot
potatoes" is that they must have revealed something about
themselves that makes them undesirable.
A key issue here is the following: To what extent does bankruptcy
differentiate households into persistently different risk categories?
Answering this question requires answering the question of
"who" bankruptcy filers are. Athreya (2004) summarizes work by
Sullivan, Warren, and Westbrook (1989, 2000), and others, reaching the
conclusions that along many relevant dimensions such as age, education,
and income, bankruptcy filers appear to be "middle class"
people who have gotten unlucky. While some of this poor luck was
persistent, much of the immediate history preceding bankruptcy filings
was not atypical. Once again, there in an inherent conflict in arguing
that bankruptcy leads to credit embargoes that filers are mainstream
households. After all, mainstream households would not be treated as
pariahs unless they were truly different from the remainder of the
population.
Experiment 3: Are Rising Indebtedness and Default Rates Consistent
With Reduced Search and Switching Costs?
We now assume that the improvements in informational flows between
borrowers and lenders have led to competitive behavior, especially in
terms of lenders no longer being able to sustain the credit exclusion of
bankruptcy filers. Athreya (2004) investigates the role of reducing the
cost of intermediation itself and finds that such changes imply more
indebtedness and default. In this article, we focus solely on discerning
the effects of reduced credit exclusion, while fully acknowledging that
both processes may (and indeed seem likely to) have occurred together.
To generate the quantitative implications of such a change, we ask
whether the total elimination of any means of ex post credit exclusion,
whereby [gamma] = 0, produces increases in bankruptcy and debt broadly
consistent with the data since the early 1990s.
We proceed in two steps. We first allow for the removal of
exclusion in a way that creditors are not fully aware of the change.
This allows us to capture the initial effects of reductions in search
costs that facilitated more switching among debtors. In particular, we
study this "transitional" period by holding the loan pricing
function fixed at its initial steady state level. We then allow for
prices to adjust as lenders learn their environment and compute a new
steady state equilibrium. (3) Our first finding is seen in column one of
Table 3. We study the effects of setting [gamma] = 0 under the benchmark
income process.
As in Athreya (2004), the initial steady state assumes an
exclusionary period averaging 16 quarters (four years), and thereby sets
[gamma] = 0.9375, and under the benchmark income process, matches
several aggregate U.S. unsecured credit and default facts. When
exclusion is eliminated, the initial transition period is quite
striking. Notably, the quarterly aggregate default rate rises sharply
from 0.12 percent to 0.18 percent, a 50 percent increase in quarterly
filing rates! The increase in filings is in part driven by the temporary
mispricing of credit risk, which households use to their advantage. This
is seen along both the "extensive" margin of borrowing,
whereby more people borrow, and the "intensive" margin,
whereby borrowers are more indebted than before. In terms of the
fraction of borrowers, there is a very large 7.1 percentage point, or
roughly a 20 percent increase in the fraction of households that borrow.
Overall indebtedness, as measured by the conditional mean of debt among
those who borrow, also grows substantially, from approximately $3,400 in
the benchmark to $5,050 in the transition. These facts are all
qualitatively consistent with the observations over the early 1990s,
during which margins fell while debt and bankruptcies both grew. As
lenders adjust pricing to a world in which exclusion is simply
unsustainable, credit supply effectively shrinks, reducing indebtedness
and default along with it. This is seen in the top block of column one
in Table 3. The fraction of borrowers falls back from its transitional
maximum to a lower level that is very close to the initial steady state.
Conversely, to get a measure of the deterrent power of exclusion, we
present results for the case where exclusion is increased so as to
average 25 years. In essence, this represents nearly permanent
exclusion. In this case, the previous intuition goes through in reverse,
whereby borrowing and default initially fall very sharply, but then
result in long-run loan terms that make borrowing attractive again, as
seen in Figure 7. These features can also be seen in Figure 8. In the
long run, bankruptcy nearly disappears, but borrowing increases to the
point where roughly one-third (32.4 percent) of all households borrow,
and when they do, they actually borrow more than under benchmark
exclusion, at $5,050. These results are largely robust across the entire
set of income processes we consider, and for brevity, we refer the
reader to Table 3 and Figures 9-12 for details.
4. CONCLUDING REMARKS
Our finding that the removal of ex post exclusion leads to greatly
increased bankruptcy rates and indebtedness is striking. A corollary is
that the other costs of bankruptcy--namely, fees, time costs, and
ultimately, the shame or "stigma" felt by filers--must be very
acute indeed. After all, even in the absence of exclusion, the credit
market in our model continues to exist rather than collapse, even though
stigma-related costs were held fixed throughout. In other words, stigma
is arguably even more important, and might be all there is, in keeping
unsecured credit markets in existence.
Filing-related costs are important and worrisome, because they
indicate that unless monetary policymakers act to provide repayment
commitment, attitudes may be all that lie between the current setting
and a setting in which the young and the wealth-poor generally cannot
obtain credit. In particular, one institutional impediment to the
commitment to repay is the U.S. bankruptcy code. Even after currently
enacted reforms take hold, it is still unconstitutional to write
contracts waiving the right to bankruptcy. At present, only the wealthy,
who might post collateral, can do so. One alternative is that exemptions
be stricter, as they implicitly will make much of the borrowing of even
the wealth-poor collateralized. On the other hand, the benefits arising
from an increase in strictness of exemptions must be weighed against the
costs imposed by facing a rigid repayment schedule in an environment of
nontrivial income risk.
The results presented here are simple and suggestive, but by no
means definitive. Yet, they point to several directions for future
research, all of which seem essential if we are to explain the rich
array of unsecured credit products in a world where penalties appear
nebulous and even unavailable.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
REFERENCES
Aguiar, Mark, and Gita Gopinath. Forthcoming. "Defaultable
Debt, Interest Rates, and the Current Account." Journal of
International Economics.
Athreya, Kartik. 2002. "Welfare Implications of the Bankruptcy
Reform Act of 1999." Journal of Monetary Economics 49 (8): 1567-95.
______. 2004. "Shame As It Ever Was: Stigma and Personal
Bankruptcy." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 91
(Spring): 1-19.
Ausubel, Lawrence. 1991. "The Failure of Competition in the
Credit Card Market." American Economic Review 81 (1): 50-81.
Calem, Paul, and Loretta Mester. 1995. "Consumer Behavior and
the Stickiness of Credit Card Interest Rates." American Economic
Review 85 (5): 1327-36.
Chatterjee, S., Dean Corbae, Makoto Nakajima, and Jose-Victor
Rios-Rull. 2005. "A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Credit With
Default." Mimeo, Univeristy of Pennsylvania.
Deaton, Angus. 1991. Understanding Consumption. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Edelberg, Wendy. 2003. "Risk-Based Pricing of Interest Rates
in Consumer Loan Markets." FEDS Working Paper 2003-62.
Fisher, Jonathan, Larry Filer, and Angela Lyons. 2004. "Is the
Bankruptcy Flag Binding? Access to Credit Markets for Post-Bankruptcy
Households." American Law and Economic Association. Annual Meetings
Paper 28.
Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function.
Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Furletti, Mark J. 2003. "Credit Card Pricing Developments and
Their Disclosure." Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Discussion
Paper (Payment Cards Center Series).
Musto, David M. 2004. "What Happens When Information Leaves a
Market? Evidence from Post-Bankruptcy Consumers." Journal of
Business 77: 725-48.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995. Foundations of
International Macroeconomics. Michigan: MIT Press.
Sapriza, Horacio, and Gabriel Cuadra. 2005. "Sovereign
Default, Terms-of-Trade, and Interest Rates in Emerging Market
Economies." Mimeo, Rutgers Business School.
Stavins, Joanna. 2000. "Credit Card Borrowing, Delinquency,
and Personal Bankruptcy." New England Economic Review July/August:
15-30.
Sullivan, Teresa, Elizabeth Warren, and Jay Westbrook. 1989. As We
Forgive Our Debtors. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
______. 2000. The Fragile Middle Class. New Haven, Conn.: Yale
University Press.
Yue, Vivian Z. "Sovereign Debt and Default with
Renegotiation." Mimeo, University of Pennsylvania.
The authors would like to thank Chris Herrington, John Walter, John
Weinberg, and especially Leonardo Martinez for helpful comments. The
views expressed herein are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1) See Athreya (2004) for an account of these changes and the
implication they have for indebtedness and default.
(2) See Athreya (2004) for more details.
(3) A natural criticism could be that we allow borrowers to learn
about the new environment before creditors do. Note, however, that we
assume that the technological change (i.e., reduced search and switching
costs) was unanticipated. Therefore, loans made just prior to adopting
the technological change turn out to be mispriced ex post.
Table 1
Persistence ([phi]) -0.40 0.00 0.30 0.50 0.70 0.90
1. s.d. y 10.90 10.00 10.50 11.50 14.00 22.90
2. estimated, s.d. y 10.80 10.20 10.00 11.40 13.30 27.50
3. estimated, s.d. c 4.60 5.10 6.70 7.60 10.40 25.90
ratio [s.d. c]/[s.d. y] 0.43 0.50 0.67 0.67 0.78 0.94
Table 2
Income Process [mu] [[sigma].sup.2] [phi]
[Y.sup.B] 1 0.15 0.97
[Y.sup.1] 1 0.10 0.50
[Y.sup.2] 1 0.10 0.99
[Y.sup.3] 1 0.30 0.50
[Y.sup.4] 1 0.30 0.99
Table 3
Income Process [Y.sup.B]=(0.97, 0.15) [Y.sup.1]=(0.5, 0.1)
Exclusion Length 0 0.9375 0.99 0 0.9375 0.99
Bankruptcy Rate 0.0018 0.0012 0.0010 0.0025 0.0014 0.0011
E(a|a<0) -0.443 -0.472 -0.505 -0.280 -0.318 -0.353
Consumption 0.142 0.142 0.140 0.084 0.077 0.075
Coefficient of
Variation
Fraction Borrowing 0.369 0.344 0.324 0.337 0.309 0.301
Transition Pricing [q.sup.y=0.9375] [q.sup.y=0.9375]
Bankruptcy Rate 0.0101 0.0006 0.0145 0.0006
E(a|a<0) -0.505 -0.342 -0.539 -0.341
Consumption 0.131 0.139 0.127 0.139
Coefficient of
Variation
Fraction Borrowing 0.415 0.247 0.449 0.248
Income Process [Y.sup.2]=(0.995, 0.1) [Y.sup.3]=(0.5, 0.3)
Exclusion Length 0 0.9375 0.99 0 0.9375 0.99
Bankruptcy Rate 0.0023 0.0012 0.0010 0.0015 0.0009 0.0008
E(a|a<0) -0.227 -0.356 -0.380 -0.417 -0.453 -0.483
Consumption 0.123 0.121 0.120 0.104 0.101 0.100
Coefficient of
Variation
Fraction Borrowing 0.465 0.311 0.295 0.232 0.225 0.235
Transition Pricing [q.sup.y=0.9375] [q.sup.y=0.9375]
Bankruptcy Rate 0.0060 0.0006 0.0136 0.0006
E(a|a<0) -0.496 -0.300 -0.515 -0.322
Consumption 0.137 0.139 0.128 0.139
Coefficient of
Variation
Fraction Borrowing 0.405 0.241 0.427 0.245
Income Process [Y.sup.4]=(0.995, 0.3)
Exclusion Length 0 0.9375 0.99
Bankruptcy Rate 0.0020 0.0012 0.0009
E(a|a<0) -0.332 -0.303 -0.195
Consumption 0.296 0.295 0.294
Coefficient of
Variation
Fraction Borrowing 0.419 0.366 0.329
Transition Pricing [q.sup.y=0.9375]
Bankruptcy Rate 0.0016 0.0005
E(a|a<0) -0.348 -0.214
Consumption 0.142 0.139
Coefficient of
Variation
Fraction Borrowing 0.252 0.130