Implications of some alternatives to capital income taxation.
Athreya, Kartik B. ; Waddle, Andrea L.
A general prescription of economic theory is that taxes on capital
income are bad. That is, a robust feature of a large variety of models
is that a positive tax on capital income cannot be part of a long-run
optimum. This result suggests that it may be useful to search for
alternatives to taxes on capital income. Several recent proposals
advocate a move to fundamentally switch the tax base toward labor income
or consumption and away from capital income. The main point of this
article is to demonstrate that, as a quantitative matter, uninsurable idiosyncratic risk is important to consider when contemplating
alternatives to capital income taxes. Additionally, we show that tax
reforms may be viewed rather differently by households that differ in
wealth and/or current labor productivity.
We are motivated to quantitatively evaluate the risk-sharing
implications of taxes by the findings of two recent theoretical
investigations. These are, respectively, Easley, Kiefer, and Possen
(1993) and Aiyagari (1995). The work of Easley, Kiefer, and Possen
(1993) develops a stylized two-period model where households face
uninsurable idiosyncratic risks. Their findings suggest that, in
general, when households face uninsurable risk in the returns to their
human or physical capital, it is useful to tax the income from these
factors and then rebate the proceeds via a lump-sum rebate. However, the
framework employed in this study does not provide implications for the
long-run steady state. Conversely, Aiyagari (1995) constructs an
infinite-horizon economy in which households derive value from public
expenditures and face uninsurable idiosyncratic endowment risks and
borrowing constraints. In this case, the optimal long-run capital income
tax rate is positive. Specifically, Aiyagari (1995) shows that the
optimal capital stock implies an interest rate that equals the rate of
time preference. However, labor income risks generate precautionary
savings that force the rate of return on capital below this rate.
Therefore, to ensure a steady state with an optimal capital stock, a
social planner will need to discourage private-sector capital
accumulation. A strictly positive long-run capital income tax rate is,
therefore, sufficient to ensure optimality. (1)
The approach we take is to study several stylized tax reforms in a
setting that allows the differential risk-sharing properties of
alternative taxes to play a role in determining their desirability. We,
therefore, choose to evaluate a model that combines features of Easley,
Kiefer, and Possen (1993) with those of Aiyagari (1995), and is rich
enough to map to observed tax policy. In terms of the experiments we
perform, we study the tradeoffs involved with using either (i) labor
income or (ii) consumption taxes to replace capital income taxes. Our
work complements preceding work on tax reform by focusing attention
solely on the differences that arise specifically from the exclusive use
of either labor income taxes or consumption taxes. To our knowledge, the
divergence in allocations emerging from the use of either labor or
consumption taxes has not been investigated. (2) We study a model that
confronts households with risks of empirically plausible magnitudes, and
allows them to self-insure via wealth accumulation. Our work is most
closely related to three infinite-horizon models of tax reform studied
respectively by Imrohoroglu (1998), Floden and Linde (2001), and Domeij
and Heathcote (2004). The environment that we study is a standard
infinite-horizon, incomplete-markets model in the style of Aiyagari
(1994), modified to accommodate fiscal policy. The remainder of the
article is organized as follows. Section 1 describes the main model and
discusses the computation of equilibrium. Section 2 explains the results
and Section 3 discusses robustness and concludes the article.
1. MODEL
The key features of this model are that households face uninsurable
and purely idiosyncratic risk, and have only a risk-free asset that they
may accumulate. For tractability, we will focus throughout the article
on stationary equilibria of this model in which prices and the
distribution of households over wealth and income levels are
time-invariant.
Households
The economy has a continuum of infinitely lived ex ante identical
households indexed by their location i on the interval [0, 1]. The size
of the population is normalized to unity, there is no aggregate
uncertainty, and time is discrete. Preferences are additively separable across consumption in different periods, letting [beta] denote the time
discount rate. Therefore, household i [member of] [0, 1] wishes to solve
[max.[{[c.sub.t.sup.i]}[member of][PI]([a.sub.0], [z.sub.0])]]
[E.sub.[o]][[infinity].summation over (t=0)] [[beta].sup.t]
u([c.sub.t.sup.i]), (1)
where {[c.sub.t.sup.i]} is a sequence of consumption, and [PI]
([a.sub.0], [z.sub.0]) is the set of feasible sequences given initial
wealth [a.sub.0] and productivity [z.sub.0]. To present a flow budget
constraint for the household, we proceed as follows.
Households face constant proportional taxes on labor income
([[tau].sup.l]), on capital income ([[tau].sup.k]), and on consumption
([[tau].sup.c]) (3) Households enter each period with asset holdings
[a.sup.i] and face pre-tax returns on capital and labor of r and w,
respectively. Each household is endowed with one unit of time, which it
supplies inelastically, that is, [l.sup.i] = 1, and receives a lump-sum
transfer b. It then receives an idiosyncratic (i.e., cross-sectionally
independent) productivity shock [z.sup.i], which leaves it with income
w[q.sup.i], where [q.sup.i] [equivalent to] [e.sup.z.sup.i]. Given the
taxes on capital and labor income, the household comes into the period
with gross-of-interest asset holdings (1 + r (1 -
[[tau].sup.k])[a.sup.i]) and after-tax labor income (1 -
[[tau].sup.l])w[q.sup.i]. The household's resources, denoted
[y.sup.i], in a given period are then
[y.sup.i] = b + (1 - [[tau].sup.l])w[q.sup.i] + [1 + r(1 -
[[tau].sup.k])][a.sup.i]. (2)
If we denote private current-period consumption and end-of-period
wealth by [c.sup.i] and [a.sup.i'], respectively, the
household's budget constraint is
(1 + [[tau].sup.c])[c.sup.i] [less than or equal to] [y.sup.i] -
[a.sup.i']. (3)
The productivity shock evolves over time according to an AR(1)
process
[z.sup.i'] = [rho][z.sup.i] + [[epsilon].sup.i], (4)
where [rho] determines the persistence of the shock and
[[epsilon].sub.t.sup.i] is an i.i.d. normally distributed random
variable with mean zero and variance [[sigma].sub.[epsilon].sup.2].
Stationary Recursive Household Problem
Given constant tax rates, constant government transfers, and
constant prices, the household's problem is recursive in two state
variables, a and z. Suppressing the household index i, we express the
stationary recursive formulation of the household's problem as
follows:
v(a, z) = max u(c) + E[v(a', z')|z], (5)
subject to (2), (3), and the no-borrowing constraint:
a' [greater than or equal to] 0 (6)
Given parameters ([tau], b, w, r), the solution to this problem
yields a decision rule for savings as a function of current assets a and
current productivity z:
a' = g(a, z|[tau], b, w, r). (7)
To reduce clutter, in what follows we denote optimal asset
accumulation by the rule g(a, z) and optimal consumption by the rule
c(a, z). As households receive idiosyncratic shocks to their
productivity each period, they will accumulate and decumulate assets to
smooth consumption. In turn, households will vary in wealth over time.
The heterogeneity of households at a given time-t can be described by a
distribution [[lambda].sub.t] (a, z) describing the fraction (measure)
of households with current wealth and productivity (a, z). In general,
the fraction of households with characteristics (a, z) may change over
time. More specifically, let P (a, z, a', z') denote the
transition function governing the evolution of distributions of
households over the state space (a, z). P (a, z, a', z')
should be interpreted as the probability that a household that is in
state (a, z) today will move to state (a', z') tomorrow. It is
a function of the household decision rule g(dot), and the Markov process for income z.
We will focus, however, on stationary equilibria, whereby
[[lambda].sub.t](a, z) = [lambda](a, z), [for all] t. Therefore, we
locate a distribution [lambda](a, z) that is invariant under the
transition function P(dot), which requires that the following hold:
[lambda](a', z') = [integral] P(a, z, a',
z')d[lambda]. (8)
We denote the stationary marginal distributions of household
characteristics a and z by [[lambda].sub.a] and [[lambda].sub.z],
respectively. Given this, aggregate consumption C [equivalent to]
[[integral].sub.AxZ] c(a, z)d[lambda], aggregate savings A [equivalent
to] [integral] g(a, z)d[lambda], and aggregate labor supply L
[equivalent to] [integral] q(z)d[[lambda].sub.z] all will be constant.
Firms
There is a continuum of firms that take constant factor prices as
given and employ constant-returns production in physical capital K and
labor L. Given total factor productivity [LAMBDA], aggregate output Y
then is given by a production function:
Y = F([LAMBDA], K, L). (9)
Physical capital depreciates at constant rate [delta] per period.
Government
There is a government that consumes an aggregate amount [C.sup.G]
and transfers an aggregate amount B [equivalent to] [integral]
bd[lambda] in each period. To finance these flows, the government may
collect revenues from taxes on labor income, capital income, and
consumption. Therefore, given [lambda](a, z), tax revenue in each period
denoted T([tau], B) is
T ([tau], B) = [[integral].sub.AxZ] [[[tau].sup.l] wq(z) +
[[tau].sup.k] rg(a, z) + [[tau].sup.c] c(a, z)]d[lambda]. (10)
The government's outlays in each period are given by
G = B + [C.sup.G], (11)
where [C.sup.G] is government consumption. The preceding
collectively imply that the economy-wide law of motion for the capital
stock is given by
K' = (1 - [delta])K + F([LAMBDA], K, L) - C - [C.sup.G]. (12)
In equilibrium, T([tau], B) = G. In our model, we abstract from
government debt for two reasons. First, we wish to maintain a simpler
environment and second, the ratio of public debt has fluctuated
substantially over the past several decades, making a single, long-run
number more difficult to interpret.
Equilibrium
Given constant tax rates [tau] = [[[tau].sup.l] [[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.c]], factor productivity [LAMBDA], government consumption
[C.sup.G], and per capita transfers b, a stationary recursive
competitive general equilibrium for this economy is a collection of (i)
a constant capital stock K; (ii) a constant labor supply L; (iii)
constant prices (w, r); (iv) decision rules for the household
[lambda](a, z) and c(a, z); (v) a measure of households [lambda](a, z)
over the state space; (vi) a transition function P(a, z, a',
z') governing the law of motion for [lambda](a, z); and (vii)
aggregate savings A([tau], B, r, w) [equivalent to] [integral] g(a,
z)d[lambda], such that the following conditions are satisfied:
1. The decision rules solve the household's problem described
in (1).
2. The government's budget constraint holds
G([tau], B|r, w) = T([tau], B). (13)
3. Given prices, factor allocations are competitive:
[F.sub.k]([LAMBDA], K, L) - [delta] = r, and
[F.sub.l]([LAMBDA], K, L) = w. (14)
4. The aggregate supply of savings satisfies the firm's demand
for capital
A([tau], B, r, w) = K. (15)
5. The distribution of households over states is stationary across
time:
[lambda](a', z') = [integral] P(a, z, a',
z')d[lambda]. (16)
Discussion of Stationary Equilibrium
Our focus on stationary equilibria warrants some discussion. In
particular, even if government behavior were time-invariant, there may
be equilibria in which prices faced by households vary over time in
fairly complicated ways. Unfortunately, computing such equilibria is
very difficult when households face uninsurable income shocks each
period. The problems arise because even under constant prices, it is not
possible that household-level outcomes remain constant through time. In
turn, the distribution of households over wealth and productivity may
vary through time. The moments of that distribution will, of course,
vary as well. In such a setting, households would have to forecast an
entire sequence of cross-sectional distributions of wealth and
productivity over the infinite future in order to forecast the prices
needed to optimally choose their own individual level of consumption and
savings. Given the difficulties previously discussed, we restrict
attention to equilibria where prices and allocations remain stationary
over time. Under this simplification, households maximize their utility
under a conjecture that they will face an infinite sequence of constant
prices and taxes, and markets clear. In our case, the prices, taxes, and
transfers are as follows: w, r, [tau] = [[[tau].sup.l] [[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.c]], and b, respectively.
In turn, the solution to the household optimization problem generates a time-invariant rule that governs optimal consumption and
savings as a function of current resources and productivity. In such a
stationary setting, it is more reasonable (and indeed, often to be
expected) that a household's movements through time will be
described by a single, unique, distribution. (4) Intuitively, household
decisions determine how the endogenous state variable of wealth evolves
from one period to the next. However, because future productivity shocks
are drawn at random, so is future wealth. In our model, wealth moves
through time in a way that its probability distribution one period from
now depends only on current wealth and current productivity. This type
of movement occurs because productivity shocks are purely first-order
autoregressive, and the household wishes only to choose wealth
one-period ahead. In sum, wealth and productivity together follow a
first-order Markov process. Under fairly general circumstances, the
long-run behavior of such processes is time-stationary. Namely, across
any two arbitrarily chosen (but sufficiently long) windows of time, the
fraction of time that a household spends at any given combination of
wealth and productivity will be equal. More useful for us, however, is
that the preceding then generally implies that, across any two dates,
the fractions of any (sufficiently large) collection of households with
a given level of wealth and productivity will also be equal. That is,
the cross-sectional distribution of households over wealth and
productivity will be time-invariant. (5) If this stationary distribution
also clears markets, households are justified in taking the conjectured
infinite sequence of constant prices as given. (6)
Measuring the Effects of Policy
The welfare criterion used here is the expectation of discounted
utility taken with respect to the invariant distribution of shocks and
asset holdings, as is standard in the literature. (7) It is denoted by
[PHI] and is given by
[PHI] = [integral] v(a, z)d[lambda], (17)
where v(dot) is the value function as defined in (5), and [lambda]
is the equilibrium joint distribution of households as described in
(16). Let [[PHI].sup.bench] denote the value under the benchmark and
[[PHI].sup.policy] denote the value under an alternative policy.
Given [PHI], we can compare welfare across policy regimes by
computing the proportional increase/decrease to benchmark consumption
that would make households indifferent between being assigned an initial
state from the benchmark stationary distribution and being assigned a
state according to the stationary distribution that prevails under the
proposed policy change. Under our assumed CRRA preferences, this is
given as:
[PSI] = ([[PHI].sup.bench]/[[PHI].sup.policy])[.sup.1/[1-[mu]]] -
1. (18)
[PSI] > 0 implies that the policy is welfare improving, while
[PSI] < 0 implies the reverse. (8)
Parameterization
In the benchmark economy, the goal of the calibration is to locate
the discount rate, [beta]*, that allows the capital market to clear at
observed factor prices, transfer levels, and tax rates. We then will use
[beta]* when computing outcomes in the policy experiments. The model
period is one year. We follow the work of both Domeij and Heathcote
(2000) and Floden and Linde (2001) in parameterizing the benchmark
economy. We observe directly some of the parameters associated with
benchmark policy. These consist of the three tax rates measured by
Domeij and Heathcote (2000) as [[tau].sup.l] = 0.269, [[tau].sup.k] =
0.397, and [[tau].sup.c] = 0.054, respectively. (9) Lump-sum transfers
as a percentage of output are set following Floden and Linde (2001), at
B/Y = 0.082. We specify production by a Cobb-Douglas function whereby
F([LAMBDA], K, L) = [LAMBDA][K.sup.[alpha]][L.sup.1-[alpha]]. The
interest rate, r* = 0.04, and capital-output ratio of 3.32 follow
Prescott (1986). Lastly, we set factor productivity [LAMBDA] to
normalize benchmark equilibrium wages w* to unity.
We assume that a is bounded below by zero in every period, which
precludes borrowing. This follows the work of Floden and Linde (2001),
Domeij and Heathcote (2000), Domeij and Floden (2006), and Ventura
(1999). We restrict the households' asset holdings to the interval
A=[0, [bar.A]]. However, we set [bar.A] high enough that it never binds.
The utility function is CRRA and is given by u (c) =
[c.sup.1-[mu]]/[1-[mu]]. We set [mu] = 2.0, as is standard. The values
governing the income process are subject to more debate, however. We,
therefore, study economies under two different levels of earnings risk
that collectively span a range of estimates documented by Aiyagari
(1994). In particular, we study a "high-risk" economy, in
which [[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] = 0.2, and also a "low-risk"
economy, in which [[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] = 0.1. With respect to the
persistence of shocks, a reasonable view of the literature suggests that
[rho] lies between 0.88 and 0.96. We therefore choose [rho] = 0.92. The
household discounts at a rate [beta] that, for each level of earnings
risk, will be calibrated to match aggregate capital accumulation under
observed factor prices, depreciation, and tax policy.
To parameterize [alpha], [delta], and [LAMBDA], we will use direct
observations on (i) the output-capital ratio, (ii) the interest rate r,
and (iii) the share of national income paid to labor [wL/Y]. First,
given prices w and r, the profit-maximizing levels of capital and labor
that a firm wishes to rent solve the following problem:
max [LAMBDA][K.sup.[alpha]][L.sup.1-[alpha]] - wL - ([delta] + r)K.
(19)
For labor, this has the first-order necessary condition:
(1 - [alpha])[LAMBDA][K.sup.[alpha]][L.sup.-[alpha]] = w.
Multiplying both sides by L and rearranging allow us to write:
(1 - [alpha]) = wL/Y.
Thus, [alpha] can be inferred from the observed share of national
income going to labor. Turning next to depreciation, optimal capital has
the first-order necessary condition:
[alpha][LAMBDA][K.sup.[alpha]-1][L.sup.1-[alpha]] = r + [delta],
(20)
which, after multiplying by K and rearranging, allows us to use the
measured output-capital ratio Y/K to recover [delta] as a function of
observables:
[delta] = [alpha][Y/K] - r.
Lastly, to set total factor productivity such that equilibrium
wages are normalized to unity, we use the first-order condition for
labor demand. First, note that we must locate a value of [LAMBDA] such
that
w = (1 - [alpha])[LAMBDA][K.sup.[alpha]][L.sup.-[alpha]] = 1. (21)
However, since capital must satisfy (20), optimal capital (fixing L
= 1) is given by
K = ([r + [delta]]/[alpha][LAMBDA])[.sup.1/[[alpha]-1]]. (22)
Substituting into (21), we have
(1 - [alpha])[LAMBDA] ([r +
[delta]]/[alpha][LAMBDA])[.sup.[alpha]/[[alpha]-1]] = 1,
which then implies that
[LAMBDA] = (1/[1 - [alpha]])[.sup.1-[alpha]]([r +
[delta]]/[alpha])[.sup.[alpha]].
Table 1 summarizes our parameter choices.
Computation
We solve the recursive formulation of the household's problem
by applying standard discrete-state-space value-function iteration (see,
for example, Ljungqvist and Sargent [2000] 39-41). In order to do this,
we first assume that the productivity shocks can take 25 values. We
follow Tauchen (1986) to obtain a discrete approximation of the
continuous-valued process defined in (4). For assets, we use a grid of
500 unevenly spaced points for wealth, with more points located where
the value function exhibits more curvature. In the benchmark economy, we
know that prices and transfers must match the data. Therefore, treating
prices and transfers as fixed, we guess a value for [beta], solve the
household's problem, and obtain aggregate savings. We then iterate on the discount factor [beta] until we clear the capital market. Labor
supply is inelastic, so the labor market clears by construction. (10)
Once we have located a discount factor that clears the capital market,
we obtain aggregate tax revenue T([tau], B). (11) We then set government
consumption, [C.sup.G], as the residual that allows the government
budget constraint to be satisfied. (12)
For the policy experiments, note first that our definition of
revenue neutrality means that the revenue needed by the government is
exactly the level needed in the benchmark, as we hold both transfers and
government consumption fixed at their benchmark levels. Given this
condition, we compute equilibria by iterating on both tax rates and the
interest rate. Specifically, we first guess an interest rate that, under
the aggregate labor supply of unity, also yields the wage rate. We then
guess a tax rate and impose the precise level of transfers obtained from
the benchmark. Given these parameters, we can solve the household's
problem, from which we obtain aggregate savings. We then check whether
savings clears the capital market, and if not, we update the interest
rate. Once we have found an allocation that clears the capital market,
we check whether the government's budget constraint is satisfied.
That is, we check whether the market-clearing allocation found allows
the government to raise the same level of revenue as in the benchmark.
If not, we adjust the specific tax rate that is under study in a given
policy experiment. We then return to the iteration on the interest rate
in order to clear the capital market. We continue this process until we
have located both an interest rate and a tax rate whereby capital
market-clearing and the government budget constraint are both
simultaneously satisfied.
2. RESULTS
The experiments conducted in this article compare allocations
obtained in the benchmark economy with those obtained under four
alternative tax regimes. These are regimes that raise revenue by (i)
using only consumption taxes, (ii) using only labor income taxes, (iii)
eliminating labor income taxes, and (iv) eliminating consumption taxes.
The results are then presented in two sections. First, we study
aggregate outcomes alone. Second, we study how households in different
circumstances behave and also how their welfare changes across taxation
regimes. We then discuss the robustness of our findings.
Tax Policy and Long-Run Aggregates
Our findings for aggregate outcomes can be summarized as follows.
First, capital income taxes are unambiguously important for allocations.
Second, a regime of pure consumption taxation leads to the highest
steady-state savings rates among the alternatives we consider. Third, we
find that the increased steady-state savings rates are, in turn,
generally associated with substantially larger capital stocks than the
alternatives. Fourth, the implications of taxation regime depend, in
some cases strongly, on the level of income risk faced by households.
Table 2 presents aggregate summary data from both the high- and low-risk
economies.
We first turn to a discussion of distortions to capital
accumulation resulting from differing tax regimes. Table 2 displays the
over-accumulation of capital that results from differing tax regimes
under incomplete markets as compared to the complete-markets case,
denoted by [K.sup.INC] and [K.sup.CM], respectively. It is important to
note, however, that [K.sup.CM] is calculated using the effective
interest rate implied by [beta] and [[tau].sup.k]. That is, the
over-accumulation, [[K.sup.INC]/[K.sup.CM]] - 1, expressed in the tables
takes the tax regime as given, and thus, is a symptom of incomplete
markets and the inability of households to completely insure themselves
against risk. From this calculation, we observe that regimes with no
capital taxation result in less over-accumulation of capital, especially
in the low-risk economy. This implies that households are able to insure
themselves more fully through precautionary savings under policies that
do not tax returns to capital. Additionally, income risk matters for the
way in which households respond to pure consumption taxes. This can be
seen by noting that in the low-risk economy, households over-accumulate
capital by the smallest percentage under the pure consumption tax
policy, while in the high-risk economy, households over-accumulate by a
large percentage under the same regime. This further elucidates the role
taxes play in an household's ability to insure itself against
future risk.
Ignoring distributional issues, we now address the issue of whether
pure consumption taxation regimes yield large benefits in terms of
increased aggregate output and consumption. The answer here is
unambiguously "yes." In the long run, under both high- and
low-income risk, pure consumption taxation is associated with capital
deepening, as measured by the capital-output ratio on the order of 20 to
25 percent. This fact can also be seen in Figure 1, which shows the
cumulative distribution of wealth under the various tax regimes. Average
long-run consumption is also higher across income-risk categories and is
made possible by the fact that the increased capital stock does not
require disproportionately greater resources to maintain.
However, it does not appear to be necessary to move to a strictly
consumption-based tax system to realize much of the gains from
eliminating capital income taxes. In Table 2, we see that a regime of
pure labor income taxes has much the same effect when measured in terms
of impact on the capital stock, consumption, and output. That is, the
intertemporal distortion arising from capital taxation seems most
significant. Given the intuition provided at the outset for the
differential risk-sharing properties arising from the two main
alternatives to capital income taxes, the question now is, in terms of
aggregates, how large are these differences? The short answer here is
"not much." In other words, pure labor income taxes and pure
consumption taxes yield broadly similar outcomes.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
However, before concluding that consumption taxes are a "free
lunch," there is one meaningful difference. The size of the
increase in capital stock arising from a move to pure consumption taxes
is much larger when income risk is higher. This is a key point that
suggests that not all the increase in capital accumulation arising from
a move to consumption taxes should be interpreted as emerging from the
removal of an intertemporal distortion to savings.
We now turn to the differences created by using consumption taxes
instead of labor income taxes. The key finding is that capital
over-accumulation grows substantially from the use of consumption taxes
in the high-risk economy, from approximately 30 to 38 percent, while it
remains essentially constant, at 14 percent, in the low-risk economy.
This finding is a clear indicator that consumption taxes indeed have
undesirable risk-sharing consequences, which households attempt to
buffer themselves against.
Perhaps even more persuasive evidence for the increased risk to
households created by consumption taxation is the fact that we
calibrated the high- and low-risk economies separately. In particular,
we see from Table 1 that the calibrated discount factor in the high- and
low-risk economies are [beta] = 0.9673 and [beta] = 0.9557,
respectively. This difference is greater than a full percentage point.
To put the implications of the preceding into perspective, we check what
this means for the complete-markets capital level, [K.sup.CM], which is
calculated to match the interest rate implied by [beta] and
[[tau].sup.k]. In percentage terms, the ideal capital stock in the
high-risk economy is around 15 percent smaller than under the low-risk
economy. (13) Yet, despite this, the steady-state capital stock under
pure consumption taxes grows by 40 percent under high-income risk, and
by just 14 percent under low-income risk. Moreover, in Table 2, we see
that in absolute terms, the capital stock is substantially larger under
pure consumption taxes when income risk is high.
Studying the implications of consumption taxes for steady-state
welfare further clarifies the sense in which the "size" of the
economy, as measured by output, is a misleading measure of welfare
gains. In particular, we see first that welfare gains from a move to
consumption taxes under low-income risk are substantial, at
approximately $3,000 annually, or 7 percent of median income. Further,
this gain dwarfs the gains obtained from moving, in the low-risk economy
from the benchmark, to a pure labor income tax regime, which is only
about two-thirds as large ($1,927). The elimination of capital taxation
results in consumption increases in both economies. However, even though
the growth is larger in the high-risk economy, the welfare gains are
smaller.
Intuitively, the risk created by consumption taxation demands a
buffer stock of savings of a size that depends crucially on the income
risk that households face. The response of the size of the buffer stock
can be seen in terms of savings rates. Specifically notice that both the
regime of pure consumption taxes and the regime of pure labor income
taxes generate almost identical savings in the low-risk economy, but
lead to a 2 percentage point (6 percent) increase in the high-risk
economy relative to its nearest alternative, which is the pure labor
income tax.
In Table 3, we display both the standard deviation of consumption
as well as the coefficient of variation of consumption, which is the
ratio of the standard deviation to the mean. The coefficient of
variation highlights the consumption risk associated with a given
policy. (14) These data show again that increased aggregate output is
not necessarily attributable to fewer distortions but instead may be due
to more risk exposure for households. In the high-risk economy,
increases in output and the capital stock are always accompanied by
increases in the standard deviation and coefficient of variation of
consumption, indicating that under each policy, the household is subject
to increased risk. By contrast, in the low-risk economy, a move to a
pure consumption tax yields lower variation in consumption, both in
absolute and relative terms. This serves to further illustrate that the
effects of tax policies depend in important ways on the underlying
income risk that households face.
Our results make clear that when choosing between the polar
extremes of pure labor taxes and pure consumption taxes, income risk
must be taken into account. Is the same warning applicable to more
intermediate tax reforms as well? To answer this, we study the effects
arising from holding capital income taxes fixed at their benchmark level
and moving to alternative regimes, which raise the remainder of revenues
via only one of the two remaining taxes. That is, we consider two
alternatives: (1) [[tau].sup.k] = 0.397 and [[tau].sup.l] = 0 and (2)
[[tau].sup.k] = 0.397 and [[tau].sup.c] = 0. In each of these cases, the
remaining tax is set to meet the government's expenditure
requirements.
Three findings are worth emphasizing. First, steady-state welfare
under regimes in which labor income taxes are eliminated are preferable
to those in which consumption taxes are eliminated. This is true under
both specifications of income risk. Once again, however, the gains from
preserving consumption taxes are much larger (roughly double) when
income risk is low. Second, under high-income risk, not only are the
gains to eliminating labor income taxes smaller, but also the gains
themselves are, in large part, an artifact of the increased buffer stock
that households build up. This is seen in the substantially larger
capital stock associated with the "no-labor-tax" regime
relative to the "no-consumption-tax" regime.
Lastly, notice that though allocations under the no-consumption-tax
regime are in some ways similar to the other allocations, the reliance
in this case on a combination involving a subset of the available tax
instruments does worse in welfare terms than the alternatives. That is,
welfare-maximizing policies are those that either (1) use one instrument
alone, such as in the cases with pure labor or consumption taxes, or (2)
use all three instruments, such as in the benchmark. We now turn to the
effect of tax policies on the household-level savings decisions that
ultimately generate the aggregates discussed previously.
Household-Level Outcomes
Tax Policy and Changes in Savings
Having focused earlier on the response of economy-wide aggregates,
we now study a variety of subsets of households in order to understand
the origins of the aggregate responses. We first discuss household
savings behavior and then turn to welfare. In Figures 2 and 3, we study
the effects of changes in policy on the amount of wealth accumulated in
both the high- and low-risk economies across income shocks. Notice,
first, that the two regimes in which capital income taxes are
eliminated, both generate the largest increases in savings, which is
consistent with the substantial growth of the capital stock seen in the
aggregate. Conversely, as long as capital income taxes are used at all,
savings rates do not deviate substantially from the benchmark. Notice,
though, that deviations from the benchmark at low levels of skill and
wealth are greatest for the case in which revenues are raised through
labor taxes only. However, it is still true that, on average, the level
of savings is highest under a consumption-tax-only regime. For those
with low wealth, as seen for the 20th percentile of wealth, the response
of savings rates to tax policy also is more sensitive to current labor
productivity (see Figure 3). Intuitively, for low-wealth households,
labor income is important in determining the current budget, especially
as these households cannot borrow.
We also see that the current productivity shock received by the
household has very little effect on the response to policy changes for
wealthy households (in other words, those that are above the median of
the wealth distribution). The preceding is true regardless of current
labor productivity. Additionally, even for low-wealth households, the
response to a change from the benchmark to either of the two alternative
policies with positive capital tax rates is relatively unaffected by
current productivity. For poorer households, however, savings does
respond to the elimination of capital taxation. Specifically, in both
the high- and low-risk economies, savings rates under pure labor income
taxes are relatively higher for low-productivity households than for
high-productivity households.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Consider next a switch from the benchmark to either of the two
policies under which consumption taxes are zero, that is, [[tau].sup.l]
only and ([[tau].sup.l], [[tau].sup.k]). In these cases, the changes
generated by making the policy switch are very small relative to the
changes generated by a switch from the benchmark to the other
alternative taxation regimes. The intuition for this finding is that
under policies featuring proportional labor income taxes, higher current
productivity implies that a larger amount of the household's income
is extracted to pay taxes. If consumption is being smoothed, savings
behavior will have to respond. Conversely, under policies that eliminate
labor taxes altogether, those with high productivity are proportionally
richer than counterparts who face labor taxes and, thus, are able to
save and consume more. We also note the largest deviations in savings
from the benchmark arise for low-wealth households. The intuition
supporting this result is that low-wealth households are comparatively
more affected by any increase or decrease in taxes because of their
inability to smooth consumption through the use of previously
accumulated wealth.
Household Welfare
Turning now to the welfare consequences of the alternative tax
policies, we partition the population by wealth and current
productivity. We study the welfare gains or losses emerging from policy
changes by computing the quantity in (18) for households with each
particular combination of current wealth and productivity. The central
implication of our welfare analysis is simple: the welfare gains from a
move to capital income taxes depend very strongly on the level of income
risk faced by households. In particular, we saw previously that
steady-state welfare gains from removing capital income taxes are much
larger under low-income risk than under high-income risk. Figure 4 shows
that this difference arises from the fact that essentially all
households benefit more from such a policy under low-income risk than
under high-income risk. In this sense, the distributional effects are
somewhat simple to document. Specifically, the order of magnitude of the
welfare gains we find is approximately 10 to 30 percent for various
households under low-income risk, but only around 2 to 5 percent under
high-income risk. This is particularly striking given that capital
stocks in the high-income risk economies are larger than those in the
low-income risk economies.
The insurance-related effects of pure consumption taxes can also be
seen because under both income processes, high-productivity households
gain most from the switch to pure consumption taxes. By contrast, the
welfare effects of labor income taxes turn out to depend on both
productivity and wealth. In particular, under low-income risk, the
elimination of capital taxes seems more important than the way in which
the resulting revenue shortfall is financed. That is, households are
essentially indifferent between a move to pure labor income taxes and a
regime of pure consumption taxes. In sharp contrast, high-income risk
leads households to prefer high labor income taxes when they have low
productivity, and to prefer high consumption taxes when they have high
labor productivity. This is precisely a result of smoothing behavior:
the income-poor consume more than their income, and income-rich, the
reverse. The high levels of income risk faced by households then lead
them to prefer to smooth their tax liability across states of the world.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
When ordering households by their wealth holdings, we again see a
divergence between those who gain and those who lose from a pure
consumption tax. In the low-risk setting, the gains from moving to
consumption (or labor) taxation generate the largest gains for the
wealthy. By contrast, under high-income risk, the gains accruing to
wealthier households shrink systematically. Conversely, high-wealth
households in the high-risk economy gain more than their lower-wealth
counterparts because of the switch to a pure labor tax.
3. ROBUSTNESS AND CONCLUDING REMARKS
In this article, we studied the differential implications arising
from two commonly proposed alternatives to capital income taxes. Our
findings suggest that consumption and labor income taxes have quite
different effects and will be viewed disparately by households that
differ in both wealth and current labor productivity. In terms of
robustness, we focused exclusively on the role played by uninsurable
income risk, as the latter is a source of some contention in the
literature. However, our results may well depend on several additional
assumptions. Notably, our analysis is restricted to an infinite-horizon
setting. A central issue that arises, therefore, is the ability of most
(in other words, all but the least fortunate) households to build up a
substantial "buffer-stock" of wealth, in the long run. This
accumulation then renders the risk-sharing problem faced by households
easier to confront. In this sense, the infinite-horizon setting, while
convenient, may understate the hardship caused by uninsurable risks. In
particular, the polar opposite of the dynastic model is the pure
lifecycle model in which households care only about their own welfare,
and not at all about the welfare of their children. Under this view, the
young will enter life with no financial wealth, and will, therefore, be
very vulnerable to both income shocks and tax systems that force them to
pay large amounts when young. In such a setting, high consumption taxes
may be substantially more painful than in our present model.
A model with overlapping generations would also allow us to
highlight the intergenerational conflicts created by tax policy,
something that our present model cannot address. One specific issue that
would then be possible to address is that, at any given point in time, a
switch to consumption taxation away from income taxation would hurt
those who had saved a great deal. In a life-cycle model, this group
would be, in general, relatively older. After all, older households,
especially if retired, earn little labor income, but consume substantial
amounts. Conversely, young households that have not saved much will not
oppose consumption taxes in the same way--especially if they are
currently consuming amounts less than their income (i.e., are saving for
retirement).
In addition to using dynasties, we simplified our analysis by
employing an inelastic labor supply function. This is, of course, not
necessarily innocuous. If taken literally, such a specification would
call for a 100 percent labor tax that was then rebated to households in
a lump-sum payment. Immediately, risk sharing would be perfect. Common
sense strongly suggests that labor effort, even if inelastic over some
ranges, would likely fall dramatically as tax rates approached 100
percent. Thus, future work should remove this abstraction in order to
more accurately assess the costs of high tax rates.
More subtle, however, is the possibility that with elastic labor
supply, households have an additional means of smoothing the effects of
productivity shocks. That is, by working more when highly productive and
less when not, a household can more easily accumulate wealth and enjoy
leisure. Recent work of Marcet, Obiols Homs, and Weil (forthcoming) and
Pijoan-Mas (2006) argues that variable labor effort can be an important
smoothing device. In fact, Marcet, Obiols Homs, and Weil (forthcoming)
even demonstrate that the additional benefit of being able to alter
labor effort can lead to a capital stock that is lower than the
complete-markets analog. In turn, the impetus for positive steady-state
capital income taxes may simply disappear.
Lastly, throughout our model, we prohibited borrowing. The
expansion of credit seen in recent years (see, for example, Edelberg
2003 and Furletti 2003) may now allow even low-wealth households to
borrow rather than use taxable labor income to deal with hardship. In
turn, the tradeoffs associated with a switch to consumption taxes will
be altered. In ongoing work, we extend the environment to allow for
life-cycle wealth, nontrivial borrowing, and elastic labor supply. Such
an extension will, we hope, provide a more definitive view of the
consequences of alternatives to capital income taxation.
REFERENCES
Aiyagari, S. Rao. 1994. "Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and
Aggregate Saving." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (3):
659-84.
Aiyagari, S. Rao. 1995. "Optimal Income Taxation with
Incomplete Markets, Borrowing Constraints, and Constant
Discounting." Journal of Political Economy 103 (6): 1,158-75.
Aiyagari, S. Rao, and Ellen McGrattan. 1998. "The Optimum
Quantity of Debt." Journal of Monetary Economics 42 (3): 447-69.
Domeij, David, and Martin Floden. 2006. "The Labor-Supply
Elasticity and Borrowing Constraints: Why Estimates Are Biased."
Review of Economic Dynamics 9 (2): 242-62.
Domeij, David, and Jonathan Heathcote. 2000. "Capital Versus
Labor Taxation with Heterogeneous Agents." Econometric Society World Congress Contributed Papers 0834, Econometric Society.
Domeij, David, and Jonathan Heathcote. 2004. "On the
Distributional Effects of Reducing Capital Taxes." International
Economic Review 45 (2): 523-54.
Easley, David, Nicholas M. Kiefer, and Uri M. Possen. 1993.
"An Equilibrium Analysis of Fiscal Policy with Uncertainty and
Incomplete Markets." International Economic Review 34 (4): 935-52.
Edelberg, Wendy. 2003. "Risk-Based Pricing of Interest Rates
in Consumer Loan Markets." Finance and Economics Discussion Series
2003-62, Federal Reserve Board of Governors.
Erosa, Andres, and Martin Gervais. 2002. "Optimal Taxation in
Life-Cycle Economies." Journal of Economic Theory 105 (2): 338-69.
Floden, Martin, and Jesper Linde. 2001. "Idiosyncratic Risk in
the United States and Sweden: Is There a Role for Government
Insurance?" Review of Economic Dynamics 4 (2): 406-37.
Furletti, Mark J. 2003. "Credit Card Pricing Developments and
Their Disclosure." Payment Cards Center Discussion Paper 03-02.
Garriga, Carlos. 2000. "Optimal Fiscal Policy in Overlapping
Generations Models." Mimeo, Florida State University.
Huggett, Mark. 1993. "The Risk-Free Rate in
Heterogeneous-Agent Incomplete-Insurance Economies." Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control 17 (5-6): 953-69.
Imrohoroglu, Selahattin. 1998. "A Quantitative Analysis of
Capital Income Taxation." International Economic Review 39 (2):
307-28.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J. 1993. "The Economic Impact of Replacing
Federal Income Taxes with a Sales Tax." Cato Policy Analysis No.
193 (April). Cato Institute. Available at:
http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa193.html (accessed on September 15,
2006).
Kydland, Finn E., and Edward C. Prescott. 1982. "Time to Build
and Aggregate Fluctuations." Econometrica 50 (6): 1,345-70.
Laffont, Jean-Jacques. 1998. The Economics of Uncertainty and
Information. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Ljungqvist, Lars, and Thomas J. Sargent. 2000. Recursive
Macroeconomic Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Marcet, Albert, Francesc Obiols Homs, and Philippe Weil.
Forthcoming. "Incomplete Markets, Labor Supply and Capital
Accumulation." Journal of Monetary Economics.
Nakajima, Makoto. 2006. "Note on Heterogeneous Agents Model:
Labor Leisure Choice and Fiscal Policy." Available at:
http://www.compmacro.com/makoto/200601econ552/note/note_hi_llchoice.pdf
(accessed on September 15, 2006).
Pijoan-Mas, Josep. 2006. "Precautionary Savings or Working
Longer Hours?" Review of Economic Dynamics 9 (2): 326-52.
Prescott, Edward C. 1986. "Theory Ahead of Business Cycle
Measurement." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff Report 102.
Tauchen, G. 1986. "Finite State Markov Chain Approximations to
Univariate and Vector Autoregressions." Economic Letters 20 (2):
177-81.
Ventura, Gustavo. 1999. "Flat Tax Reform: A Quantitative
Exploration." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23
(September): 1,425-58.
We thank Kay Haynes for expert editorial assistance; Leo Martinez,
Roy Webb, and Chris Herrington for very helpful comments; and Andreas
Hornstein for an extremely helpful editor's report and comments,
both substantive and expositional. The views expressed in this article
are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. All errors are
our own.
(1) Another strand of work by Erosa and Gervais (2002) and Garriga
(2000) illustrates settings in which the long-run capital income tax
remains strictly postive because households face trading frictions that
arise from living in a deterministic overlapping-generations economy.
(2) Imrohoroglu (1998) mentions this difference in a life-cycle
model but does not discuss the source for the divergence.
(3) A tax on consumption can be implemented simply via a retail
sales tax, as we do here, or via an income tax with a full deduction for
any savings. See, for example, Kotlikoff (1993).
(4) For example, Huggett (1993) provides a proof of this for the
case where households face two levels of shocks, have unbounded utility
(as we do here), and face a borrowing constraint.
(5) More generally, the relevant "state-vector" will have
a constant cross-sectional distribution.
(6) Households only take equilibrium prices as given. If prices did
not clear markets, households or firms could not rationally take them as
given when optimizing. Consequently, households or firms would have no
guarantee of being able to buy (sell) the quantities they wished.
(7) See, for example, Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998).
(8) To convert model outcomes into dollar equivalents, note that
average labor income in the model is normalized to unity, and average
labor income in 2006 U.S. data is approximately $50,000.
(9) We use tax rates as measured for 1990-1996 in Domeij and
Heathcote (2000), Table 2.
(10) Nakajima (2006) contains a useful description of the iterative scheme used here.
(11) We simply multiply aggregate consumption C, capital K, and
individual labor income wL in that allocation by their respective tax
rates.
(12) Our use of the taxes estimated by Domeij and Heathcote (2004)
and transfers estimated by Floden and Linde (2001) implies that our
measure of government consumption as a percentage of output will not
necessarily coincide with that obtained in the latter. However, in our
benchmark, we find very similar results, 20.3 percent vs. 21.7 percent
in Floden and Linde (2001).
(13) That is, (5.69-4.97)/4.97 [approximately equal to] 0.15.
(14) Specifically, for a mean-preserving proportional risk,
multiplying the coefficient of variation of consumption by one-half of
the coefficient of relative risk aversion yields the percentage of mean
consumption that a household would be willing to pay to avoid a unit
increase in standard deviation. See, for example, Laffont (1998, 22).
Table 1 Parameters
Value {high,
Parameter low} Source
[[tau].sub.bench.sup.l] 0.269 Domeij and Heathcote (2000)
[[tau].sub.bench.sup.k] 0.397 Domeij and Heathcote (2000)
[[tau].sub.bench.sup.c] 0.054 Domeij and Heathcote (2000)
[r*.sub.bench] 0.04 Prescott (1986)
b/Y 0.082 Floden and Linde (2001)
[beta] {0.9587, 0.9673} Calibrated to clear capital
mkt. at [r*.sub.bench]
[mu] 2.0 Standard in literature
[alpha] 0.36 Kydland and Prescott (1982)
[delta] 0.0685 Calibrated to match K/Y =
3.32, given [alpha],
[r*.sub.bench]
[LAMBDA] 0.865 Calibrated to match w = 1
[rho] 0.92 Floden and Linde (2001)
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] {0.2, 0.1} Similar to Aiyagari (1994)
Table 2 Aggregates
High-Risk [[tau].sub.l] [[tau].sub.k] [[tau].sub.c] r*
Benchmark 0.269 0.397 0.054 0.040
[[tau].sup.c] only 0.000 0.000 0.400 0.022
[[tau].sup.l] only 0.360 0.000 0.000 0.026
[[tau].sup.c] & 0.000 0.397 0.347 0.035
[[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.l] & 0.320 0.397 0.000 0.041
[[tau].sup.k]
Low-Risk
Benchmark 0.269 0.397 0.054 0.040
[[tau].sup.c] only 0.000 0.000 0.390 0.025
[[tau].sup.l] only 0.370 0.000 0.000 0.025
[[tau].sup.c] & 0.000 0.397 0.330 0.040
[[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.l] & 0.320 0.397 0.000 0.040
[[tau].sup.k]
High-Risk w* Y C [K.sup.INC] [K.sup.INC]/Y
Benchmark 1.001 1.566 1.067 5.203 3.32
[[tau].sup.c] only 1.101 1.734 1.122 6.903 3.98
[[tau].sup.l] only 1.084 1.696 1.130 6.489 3.83
[[tau].sup.c] & 1.027 1.604 1.069 5.557 3.47
[[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.l] & 0.997 1.558 1.067 5.126 3.29
[[tau].sup.k]
Low-Risk
Benchmark 1.002 1.565 1.020 5.193 3.32
[[tau].sup.c] only 1.087 1.697 1.061 6.499 3.83
[[tau].sup.l] only 1.086 1.698 1.068 6.506 3.83
[[tau].sup.c] & 1.001 1.565 1.013 5.187 3.32
[[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.l] & 1.002 1.564 1.023 5.185 3.32
[[tau].sup.k]
High-Risk [K.sup.CM] [[K.sup.INC]/[K.sup.CM]] - 1 [PSI]
Benchmark 3.493 48.97% $0
[[tau].sup.c] only 4.974 38.77% $1,010
[[tau].sup.l] only 4.974 30.45% $1,026
[[tau].sup.c] & 3.493 11.71% $305
[[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.l] & 3.493 46.77% -$45
[[tau].sup.k]
Low-Risk
Benchmark 4.190 23.92% $0
[[tau].sup.c] only 5.697 14.06% $3,136
[[tau].sup.l] only 5.697 14.19% $1,927
[[tau].sup.c] & 4.190 23.79% $663
[[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.l] & 4.190 23.74% -$21
[[tau].sup.k]
Table 3 Volatilities
[[sigma].sub.cons]/ Savings
High-Risk [[sigma].sub.cons] [[mu].sub.cons] Rate
Benchmark .376 .352 .391
[[tau].sup.c] only .403 .359 .353
[[tau].sup.l] only .398 .352 .334
[[tau].sup.c] & .386 .361 .333
[[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.l] & .375 .351 .315
[[tau].sup.k]
Low-Risk
Benchmark .251 .246 .348
[[tau].sup.c] only .241 .227 .375
[[tau].sup.l] only .281 .263 .371
[[tau].sup.c] & .227 .224 .353
[[tau].sup.k]
[[tau].sup.l] & .258 .252 .346
[[tau].sup.k]