Monetary policy and global equilibria in a production economy.
Hursey, Tim ; Wolman, Alexander L.
Macroeconomic models that are applied to the study of monetary
policy often exhibit multiple equilibria.(1) Prior to the mid-1990s,
applied monetary theory typically modeled monetary policy in terms of a
rule for the money supply, and it was well understood that multiple
equilibria often arose under constant money supply policies. Starting in
the mid-1990s, applied work shifted to modeling monetary policy in terms
of interest rate rules. This was mainly because of the accumulating
observations that central banks in fact operated with interest rate
targets rather than money supply targets. A particular class of interest
rate rules--so called "active Taylor rules," featuring a
strong response of the policy interest rate to inflation--attracted
special attention. In linearized models these policy rules were shown to
guarantee a locally unique nonexplosive equilibrium. Benhabib,
Schmitt-Grohe, and Uribe looked beyond the local dynamics in a series of
articles (e.g., 2001a, 2001b, 2002), and showed that active Taylor rules
could in fact lead to multiple equilibria. Whereas local analysis
ignored the zero bound on nominal interest rates, global analysis showed
that the zero bound implied the existence of a second steady-state
equilibrium, with low inflation and a low nominal interest rate. This
second steady state proved to be the "destination" for paths
that had appeared explosive in the local analysis. Benhabib,
Schmitt-Grohe, and Uribe's results attracted much attention in the
academic literature because the prevailing wisdom had held that active
Taylor rules generated a unique equilibrium. More recently, the
persistence of low inflation and low nominal interest rates has brought
attention to Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohe, and Uribe's work in policy
circles. Most notably, Bullard (2010) argued that monetary policy in the
United States could unintentionally be leading the economy to a steady
state in which inflation is below its target.
This article provides an introduction to Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohe,
and Uribe's work on multiple equilibria under active Taylor rules,
using two simple models. While the type of results presented here is not
new, the specific modeling framework--Rotemberg price setting in
discrete time--is new, and it fits neatly into the frameworks typically
used for applied monetary policy analysis. Furthermore, we provide
computer programs in the open source software R to replicate all the
results in the article. The programs are available at
www.richmondfed.org/research/economists/bios/wolman_bio.cfm.
Section 1 places the topic of this article in historical
perspective. Section 2 shows the existence of multiple equilibria in a
reduced-form model consisting only of an active Taylor rule and a Fisher
equation, assuming that the real interest rate is exogenous and fixed.
Section 3 describes the discrete-time Rotemberg pricing model to be used
in the remainder of the article. Steady-state equilibria and local
dynamics are described in Section 4, and global dynamics are described
in Section 5. Section 6 concludes.
1. Historical Context
Multiple equilibria is a common theme in monetary economics, and
has been at least since the work of Brock (1975). On the theory side,
there has been a steady stream of work on multiple equilibria since the
1970s. In contrast, emphasis on multiple equilibria in applied monetary
policy research has fluctuated as new theoretical results have appeared,
the tools of analysis have evolved, and economic circumstances have
changed. The immediate explanation for why the theoretical results
described in this article have attracted attention in policy circles--10
years after those results first appeared--involves economic
circumstances, namely the existence of low inflation and near-zero
nominal interest rates in the United States. There is a longer history,
however, that also involves the ascent of interest rate feedback rules
and linearized New Keynesian models, and the accompanying focus on
active Taylor rules as a descriptive and prescriptive guide to central
bank behavior.
Beginning with Bernanke and Blinder (1992), quantitative research on monetary policy in the United States rapidly shifted from modeling
monetary policy as controlling the money supply to modeling monetary
policy as controlling interest rates.(2) At around the same time,
Henderson and McKibbin (1993) and Taylor (1993) influentially proposed
particular rules for the conduct of monetary policy. These rules
involved the policy rate (federal funds rate in the United States) being
set as a linear function of a small number of endogenous variables,
typically including inflation and some measure of real activity.
Henderson and McKibbin focused on the normative aspects of interest rate
rules, whereas Taylor also argued that what would become known as the
"Taylor rule" actually provided a reasonable description of
short-term interest rates in the United States from 1986-1992.
Just as Taylor rules were attracting more attention, another shift
was occurring in the nature of quantitative research on monetary policy.
Bernanke and Blinder's 1992 article had used vector autoregressions
(VARs) for its empirical analysis and, in their policy analysis,
Henderson and McKibbin employed linear rational expectations models with
some rule-of-thumb behavior. These two approaches--VARs and linear
rational expectations models--had become standard in applied monetary
economics for empirical analysis and policy analysis, respectively.
Beginning with Yun (1996), King and Wolman (1996), and Woodford (1997),
however, the tide shifted toward what Goodfriend and King (1997) called
New Neoclassical Synthesis (NNS) models. NNS models represented a
melding of real business cycle (RBC) methodology--dynamic general
equilibrium--with nominal rigidities and other market imperfections.
Nominal rigidities made the NNS models appealing frameworks for studying
monetary policy, and the RBC methodology meant that it was
straightforward to model the behavior of monetary policy as following a
Taylor-style rule.
While NNS models, like RBC models, were fundamentally nonlinear,
they were typically studied using linear approximation. In linearized
NNS models (as with their predecessors, the linear rational expectations
models), the question of existence and uniqueness of equilibrium
generally was presumed to be identical to the question of whether the
model possessed unique stable local dynamics in the neighborhood of the
steady state around which one linearized. (3) In turn, the nature of the
local dynamics depended on the properties of the interest rate rule.
Although specific conditions can vary across models, the results in
Leeper (1991) and Kerr and King (1996) were the basis for a useful rule
of thumb in many monetary models: Taylor-style interest rate rules were
consistent with unique stable local dynamics only if the coefficient on
inflation was greater than one; a coefficient less than one would be
consistent with a multiplicity of stable local dynamics. Taylor rules
with a coefficient greater than one became known as active Taylor rules,
and the rule of thumb that active Taylor rules guaranteed a unique
equilibrium became known as the Taylor principle. (4) Passive Taylor
rules, in contrast, are Taylor rules with a coefficient on inflation
less than one.
Some intuition for the Taylor principle comes from the much earlier
work of Sargent and Wallace (1975) and McCallum (1981). Sargent and
Wallace showed that if the nominal interest rate is held fixed by the
central bank, then in many models expectations of future inflation will
be pinned down, but the current price level is left indeterminate.
McCallum followed up by showing that if the nominal interest rate
responds to some nominal variable it is also possible to pin down the
price level. The Taylor principle states that multiplicity can occur if
the nominal interest rate does not respond strongly enough to inflation,
consistent with the message of Sargent and Wallace and McCallum.
With widespread understanding of the Taylor principle came
empirical applications by Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (2000) and Lubik
and Schorfheide (2004). These authors argued that (i) violation of the
Taylor principle could help explain the macroeconomic instability of the
1970s, and (ii) a shift in policy so that the Taylor principle did hold
could help explain the subsequent stability after 1982. Although this
work brought multiple equilibria into the mainstream of applied research
on monetary policy, it proceeded under the assumption that the local
linear dynamics gave an accurate picture of the nature of equilibrium.
These articles also helped to cement the idea that the Taylor principle
characterized "good" monetary policy, because the Taylor
principle would guarantee that inflation stayed on target.
Beginning with their 2001a article, Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohe, and
Uribe (BSU) showed that when there is a lower bound on nominal interest
rates, the local dynamics can be misleading about the uniqueness of
equilibrium when monetary policy is described by an active Taylor rule.
The details of BSU's argument will become clear below. The rough
intuition is as follows. Arguments for (local) uniqueness of equilibrium
with active Taylor rules posit that without shocks, the model has a
unique equilibrium at the inflation rate targeted by the interest rate
rule. Any other candidate solutions to the model equations would have
the inflation rate exploding to plus or minus infinity, or oscillating
explosively. But many of these explosive paths would violate the lower
bound on the nominal interest rate. When that bound is imposed and the
model is studied nonlinearly, it becomes clear that (i) there is a
second steady-state equilibrium at a lower inflation rate, and (ii)
there are many non-steady-state equilibria in which the inflation rate
converges to the low-inflation steady state in the long run.
Initially, while the articles by BSU were widely cited, they did
not attract much attention in policy circles. This is somewhat
surprising because the articles were showing that a policy advocated in
large part because it was believed to deliver a unique equilibrium
actually delivered multiple equilibria in some models! Furthermore, a
rule that violated the Taylor principle--a passive rule--would actually
be consistent with keeping inflation close to its targeted value, even
though there could be multiple equilibria with this property. Recently
however, the results in BSU have attracted substantial attention in
policy circles. The simultaneous occurrence of low inflation and low
nominal interest rates in the United States is suggestive of some of the
equilibria identified by BSU, so it is natural to wonder whether we are
experiencing outcomes associated with those global equilibria.
Policymakers care about this because the global equilibria involve
average inflation below its intended level.
2. A Simple Framework with Only Nominal Variables
As a simple framework for communicating some of the key ideas in
BSU, this section works through a two-equation model of the nominal
interest rate and inflation. That minimal structure is sufficient to
illustrate the potential for the local and global dynamics to diverge
when monetary policy is given by an active Taylor rule.
Assume that the real interest rate is exogenous and fixed,
[r.sub.t], = r, whereas the nominal interest rate ([R.sub.t]) and the
inflation rate ([pi].sub.t) are endogenous.(5) Expectations are
rational. The model consists of a Fisher equation relating the
short-term nominal interest rate to the short-term real interest rate
and expected inflation,
[R.sub.t] = r[E.sub.t][[pi].sub.[t + 1]] (1)
and a rule specifying how the central bank sets the nominal
interest rate--in this case as a function only of the current inflation
rate, with an inflation target of [pi]*:
[R.sub.t] = 1 + (R* - 1) [([pi].sub.t]/[pi]*).sup.[gamma]] (2)
where
R* = r[pi]*; (3)
that is, the targeted nominal interest rate is the one that is
implied by the steady-state Fisher equation when inflation is equal to
its target.
The interest rate rule in (2) may look unfamiliar relative to
standard linear Taylor rules. We use the nonlinear rule because it will
simplify the analysis in the second part of the article.(6) Furthermore,
the linear approximation to the rule in (2) around {[R.sup.*.,
[pi].sup.*]} is
[R.sub.t] - R* = [gamma](R* - 1/[pi]*)([[pi].sub.t] - [pi]*) (4)
a simple inflation-only Taylor rule in which the coefficient on
inflation is [gamma] (R* - 1) / [pi]*. and we assume that [gamma] (R* -
1) / [pi]* > r > 1. The standard local-linear approach around the
point {R*, [pi]*} involves combining the linearized Taylor rule (4) with
the linearized Fisher equation ([R.sub.t] - R* = (R* / [pi]*)
[E.sub.t]([[pi].sub.[t+1]] - [pi]*)), which yields an expectational
difference equation in inflation:
[E.sub.t]([[pi].sub.[t + 1]] - [pi]*) = [gamma](R* -
1/R*)([[pi].sub.t] - [pi]*).
For simplicity, assume perfect foresight--that is, the future is
known with certainty, so that [E.sub.t] ([[pi].sub.[t+1]] - [pi]*) can
be replaced with [[pi].sub.[t+1] - [pi]*. Perfect foresight is clearly
an unrealistic assumption, but it is a convenient one for illustrating
the difference between local and global dynamics. With perfect
foresight, we have
([[pi].sub.[t + 1]] - [pi]*) = [gamma](R* - 1/R*)([[pi].sub.t] -
[[pi]*]).(5)
By assumption the coefficient on [[pi].sub.t] - [pi]* is greater
than one--the rule obeys the Taylor principle. Consequently, we can show
that there is a unique non-explosive equilibrium. Constant inflation at
the targeted steady-state level ([[pi].sub.t] = [pi]*) is clearly an
equilibrium because it represents a solution to the difference equation
(5). If inflation in period t were equal to any number other than [pi]*,
inflation would have to follow an explosive path going forward because
the coefficient on current inflation is greater than one. Any such
explosive path would be ruled out as an equilibrium by assumption in the
standard local-linear approach. (7)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Steady-State Equilibria
It is obvious that [pi]*, {[pi].sup.*]} represents a steady-state
solution to the Fisher and Taylor equations ([1] and [2]). Less
obviously, there is also a second steady-state solution with a lower
inflation rate and a lower nominal interest rate. To see this, combine
the steady-state Fisher and Taylor equations into a single equation in
[pi]:
[pi] = [r.sup.[- 1]](1 + (R* - 1)[([pi]/[pi]*).sup.[gamma]]). (6)
Figure 1 displays a plot of the right-hand side of (6) (essentially
the Taylor rule) against the 45-degree line--which is also the left-hand
side, or the Fisher equation. The two intersections of the right-hand
side and left-hand side represent the two steady-state equilibria. The
targeted inflation rate is 2 percent, and the other steady state
involves slight deflation.
The specific Taylor rule we chose for this example never allows the
nominal interest rate to hit the zero bound. Alternatively, if we had
chosen a typical linear Taylor rule ([R.sup.t] = max {R* + f
([[pi].sub.t] - [pi]*), 0}), there would be a kink in the steady-state
Taylor curve at [pi] = 1 /r, and the second steady state would be at
[pi] = [pi]* - (1/f)R*. BSU (2001a) and Bullard (2010) contain pictures
of the analogues to Figure 1 implied by several different interest rate
rules that all satisfy the Taylor principle at the targeted steady
state, and all imply the existence of a second steady state with lower
inflation.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Example of a Non-Steady-State Equilibrium
The fact that there are two steady-state equilibria suggests that
there may also be equilibria in which inflation and nominal interest
rates fluctuate. Returning now to the nonlinear model, by combining the
Fisher equation (1) and the interest rate rule (2) and imposing perfect
foresight, we have a first-order difference equation for the inflation
rate:
[[pi].sub.[t + 1]] = [r.sup.[- 1]](1 + (R* -
1)[[([pi].sub.t]/[pi]*).sup.[gamma]]). (7)
This is the nonlinear analogue of (5). In contrast to the
linearized model, we can show that there is a continuum of nonexplosive
equilibria. (8) In Figure 2 we plot the right-hand side of (7): It is an
identical curve to the solid line in Figure 1. The dotted line is the
45-degree line, which is also the left-hand side of (7). The
intersections between the two lines are the steady states and, starting
with any initial inflation rate below the targeted steady state, we can
trace an equilibrium path using the solid line and the 45-degree line.
For example, from an initial inflation rate of 1.014, the vertical solid
lines with arrows pointing down indicate the successive values of
inflation going forward. Generalizing from this example, the figure
shows that all perfect foresight equilibria except for the targeted
steady state converge to the nontargeted steady state. In contrast, the
conventional local linear approach applied to the targeted steady state
would conclude that the targeted steady state was the only
equilibrium--other solutions are locally explosive and would be ruled
out by assumption. Figure 2 conveys the essence of the literature that
began with BSU (2001a): Local analysis suggests a unique equilibrium,
whereas global analysis reveals that many solutions ruled out as
explosive instead lead to a second steady-state equilibrium.
Because the qualitative results involving a second steady state and
multiple equilibria will carry over into the model with an endogenous
real interest rate and endogenous output, it is interesting to discuss
the economics behind these results. In a neighborhood of the targeted
steady state, the interest rate rule responds to an upward (downward)
deviation of inflation from target by moving the interest rate upward
(downward) more than proportionally. This sets off a locally explosive
chain: The Fisher equation (1) dictates that an increase in the current
nominal interest rate must correspond to a higher future inflation rate,
which then is met with a further increase in next period's interest
rate, etc. One notable aspect of this process is that there is no sense
in which a higher nominal interest rate represents "tighter"
monetary policy. The model has only nominal variables, and a higher
nominal interest rate must correspond to higher expected inflation. In
contrast, the Taylor principle is often thought of as ensuring that an
increase in inflation is met with a monetary tightening, as represented
by a higher nominal interest rate. In models with real effects of
monetary policy--such as the one discussed below--an increase in the
nominal interest rate does not have to correspond to higher expected
inflation. However, we have learned from the two-equation model that
this association of higher interest rates with tight monetary policy is
not an inherent ingredient in the local uniqueness and global
multiplicity associated with the Taylor principle. (9)
3. A MODEL WITH REAL VARIABLES AND MONETARY NONNEUTRALITY
The model above taught us that the Fisher equation together with a
Taylor rule that responds strongly to inflation can lead to multiple
steady states and other equilibria because of the lower bound on nominal
interest rates. However, the only endogenous variables in that model are
nominal variables. One of the simplest ways to endogenize real variables
and introduce real effects of monetary policy is with a version of the
Rotemberg (1982) model, which has quadratic costs of nominal price adjustment. In this model, there is a representative household that
takes all prices and aggregate quantities as given, and chooses how much
to consume and how much to work. There is a continuum of
monopolistically competitive firms that face convex costs of adjusting
their nominal prices, and there is a monetary authority that sets the
short-term nominal interest rate according to a time-invariant feedback
rule.
The representative household has preferences over consumption
([c.sub.t]) and (disutility of) labor ([h.sub.t]) given by
[[infinity]summation over(t=0)][[beta].sup.t](In(c.sub.t)-xh.sub.t). (8)
There is a competitive labor market in which the real wage is w,
per unit of time. The consumption good is a composite of a continuum of
differentiated products ([c.sub.t] (z)), each of which are produced
under monopolistic competition:
[c.sub.t][([1[integral].sub.0][c.sub.t][(z).sup.[[[epsilon] - 1]/
[epsilon]]]dz).sup. [epsilon]/[epsilon] - 1]. (9)
Households own the firms. An individual household's budget
constraint is
[c.sub.t] + [R.sub.t.sup.[- 1]][B.sub.t]/[P.sub.t] =
[w.sub.t][h.sub.t] + [B.sub.[t - 1]]/[P.sub.t] + [[PI].sub.t]/[P.sub.t]
(10)
where [PI], represents nominal dividends from firms, [p.sup.t] is
the price of the composite good, and [B.sup.t] is the quantity of
one-period nominal discount bonds. As above, [R.sup.t] is the gross
nominal interest rate. The household's intratemporal first-order
conditions representing optimal choice of labor input and consumption
are given by
[[lambda].sub.t][w.sub.t] = x, (11)
and
[[lambda].sub.t] = 1/[c.sub.t], (12)
and the intertemporal first-order condition representing optimal
choice of bondholdings is given by
[[[lambda].sub.t]/[P.sub.t]][R.sub.t.sup.[- 1]] = [beta]
[[[lambda].sub.[t + 1]]/[P.sub.[t + 1]]] (13)
In these equations, the variable [[lambda].sub.t]., is the Lagrange
multiplier on the budget constraint for period t--it can also be thought
of as the marginal utility of an additional unit of consumption at time
t. Note that the intertemporal first-order condition (13) corresponds to
the Fisher equation from the first model, with the real interest rate
now endogenous and given by
[r.sub.t] = [[beta].sup.-1] [c.sub.t + 1]/[c.sub.t].
Firms face a cost ([[xi].sub.t]) in terms of final goods of
changing the nominal price of the good they produce (z):
[[xi].sub.t](z) = [theta]/2 [([P.sub.t](z) / [P.sub.t - 1](z) -
1).sup.2].(14)
Because goods are produced both for consumption and for
accomplishing price adjustment, the market-clearing condition is
[y.sub.t] = [c.sub.t] + [[theta] / 2([[pi].sub.t] - 1).sup.2] (15)
where [y.sub.t] denotes total output of the composite good,
[[pi].sub.t], denotes the gross inflation rate ([P.sub.t] / [P.sub.t -
1]), and we have imposed symmetry across firms, meaning that all firms
choose the same price.
An individual firm chooses its price each period to maximize the
expected present value of profits, where profits in any single period
are given by revenue minus costs of production minus costs of price
adjustment. The demand curve facing each firm is [y.sub.t](z) =
[([P.sub.t] (z) / [P.sub.t]).sup.[- epsilon]] [y.sub.t], so the profit
maximization problem for firm z is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The first term in the square brackets is the real revenue a firm
earns charging a price [P.sub.t + j] (z) in period t + j; it sells
[([P.sub.t+j] (z) / [P.sub.t + j]).sup.[-epsilon]] [y.sub.t + j] units
of goods for relative price [P.sub.t + j] (z) / [P.sub.t + j]. The
second term in the square brackets (in the second line of the
expression) is the real costs the firm incurs in period t + j, number of
goods sold multiplied by average cost, which is equal to marginal cost and to the real wage because labor productivity is constant and equal to
one. Finally, the third term in the square brackets is the real cost of
adjusting the nominal price from [P.sub.t + j - 1] (z) to [P.sub.t + j]
(z). Note that the price chosen in any period shows up only in two
periods of the infinite sum. Thus, the part of the objective function
relevant for the choice of a price in period t is
[P.sub.t] (z) / [P.sub.t] [([P.sub.t] (z) /
[P.sub.t]).sup.[-epsilon]] [y.sub.t] - [w.sub.t] [([P.sub.t] (z) /
[P.sub.t]).sup.[-epsilon]] [y.sub.t] - [theta] / 2 [([P.sub.t] (z) /
[P.sub.t - 1](z)-1).sup.2] [beta] ([[lambda].sub.t + 1] /
[[lambda].sub.t]) [theta] / 2 [([P.sub.t + 1] (z) / [P.sub.t] (z) -
1).sup.2]
The first-order condition is
(1 - [epsilon]) 1 / [P.sub.t] [([P.sub.t] (z) /
[P.sub.t]).sup.[-epsilon]] [y.sub.t] + [epsilon] [w.sub.t] 1 / [P.sub.t]
[([P.sub.t] (z) / [P.sub.t]).sup.[-epsilon - 1]] [y.sub.t] - [theta] 1 /
[P.sub.t - 1] (z) ([P.sub.t] (z) / [P.sub.t - 1](z) - 1) + [beta]
([[lambda].sub.t + 1] / [[lambda].sub.t]) [theta] ([P.sub.t + 1] (z) /
[P.sub.t][(z).sup.2]) ([P.sub.t+1](z)/[P.sub.t](z) - 1) = 0
If we multiply both sides by [P.sub.t], and impose symmetry--that
is, assume that all firms choose the same price in any given period, the
expression simplifies to
(1 - [epsilon]) [y.sub.t] + [epsilon] [w.sub.t] [y.sub.t] - [theta]
[[pi].sub.t] ([[pi].sub.- 1]) + [beta] ([[lambda].sub.t + 1] /
[[lambda].sub.t]).[theta] [[pi].sub.t + 1] ([[pi].sub.t + 1] - 1) = 0
Using the goods market clearing condition (15) and the
household's optimally conditions, the previous equation simplifies
to a form that we will refer to as the New Keynesian Phillips Curve:
(10)
([[pi].sub.t] - 1) [[pi].sub.t] = ([c.sub.t] / [theta] +
([[[pi].sub.t] - 1).sup.2] / 2)(1 - [epsilon] + [chi] [epsilon]
[c.sub.t]) + [beta] [E.sub.t] ([c.sub.t] / [c.sub.t + 1]([[pi].sub.t +
1] - 1) [[pi].sub.t + 1]). (16)
where [[pi].sub.t], is the gross inflation rate.
Finally, monetary policy is given by a nominal interest rate rule
similar to what was used in the two-equation model, with the one
difference that the interest rate responds to expected future inflation
instead of to current inflation:
[R.sub.t] = 1 + ([pi]* / [beta] - 1)[([[pi].sub.t + 1] / [pi]
*.sup).[lambda]] (17)
Recall that in the two-equation model, using a policy rule
identical to (17) would render the model entirely static, whereas the
rule that responds to current inflation introduces dynamics. In the
current model, optimal pricing already introduces dynamics, so we choose
to use the future-inflation version of the policy rule. (11) Combining
the policy rule with the household's intertemporal first-order
condition (13), using the definition of the inflation rate to eliminate
the price level, and using the household's intratemporal
first-order condition (12) to eliminate [lambda], we have
[([c.sub.t] / [[pi].sub.t + 1] [c.sub.t + 1]).sup.-1] = [beta](1 +
([[pi]* / [beta] - 1)[([[pi].sub.t+1]/[pi]*).sup.[lambda]]). (18)
The model has now been reduced to two nonlinear difference
equations (16) and (18) in the variables [c.sub.t], [[pi].sub.t],
[c.sub.t + 1], [[pi].sub.t + 1].
4. LOCAL DYNAMICS AROUND STEADY-STATE EQUILIBRIA
As with the ad-hoc model in Section 2, there are two steady-state
equilibria. That there are two steady-state equilibrium inflation rates
is immediately apparent from (18)--in a steady state it is identical to
(6). One of the steady states has inflation equal to the targeted
inflation rate [pi]*, and the other steady state has a lower inflation
rate. (12) The steady-state levels of consumption are determined by
(16).
To study dynamic equilibria, we follow the same steps as in the
two-equation model, beginning with the linearized model and then moving
on to the exact nonlinear model. The two dynamic equations (16) and (18)
can be represented as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
G([c.sub.t] [c.sub.t + 1], [[pi].sub.t + 1]) = [[pi].sub.t + 1]
[c.sub.t + 1] - [beta] [c.sub.t](1 + ([pi]* / [beta] - 1)[([[pi].sub.t +
1] /[pi]*).sup.[lambda]]).
Table 1 Parameter values
[beta] 0.99
[epsilon] 6
[theta] 17.5
[chi] 5
[gamma] 90
[pi]* 1.005
Linearizing around the steady state with the targeted inflation
rate (denoted [c sup.*, [[pi] sup.*]) yields
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (19)
where [H.sub.j] (s) denotes the [j.sup.th] partial derivative of
the generic function H (), evaluated at s.
The existence and uniqueness of a nonexplosive equilibrium in the
linearized model depends on the eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix j,
given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Neither [c.sub.t], nor [[pi].sub.t], are predetermined variables,
so the condition for a unique nonexplosive equilibrium is that both
eigenvalues of j be less than one in absolute value. Because we are not
able to provide a general proof of the parameter conditions under which
equilibrium exists and is unique, we turn to a numerical example, which
we will stay with for the rest of the article. (13) Table 1 contains the
parameters for that example; they are chosen to be consistent with a 2
percent annual inflation target (the model is a quarterly model), a 4
percent real interest rate, a markup of 20 percent, and a coefficient in
the Taylor rule of 1.33 when the Taylor rule is linearized around the
targeted steady state. In addition, our choice of [theta] implies that
price adjustment costs are less than 2/10 percent of output.
At the targeted steady state, the local (nonexplosive) dynamics are
unique, in a trivial sense. The Jacobian's eigenvalues are
0.99771321 [+ or -] 0.12791602i, which means that both eigenvalues have
absolute value 1.0059. Local to the targeted steady state, the fact that
both eigenvalues have absolute value greater than one and are imaginary
means that any solution to the difference equation system (19) other
than the steady state itself oscillates explosively. In the linearized
model the local dynamics are the global dynamics, so the only
nonexplosive solution is the targeted steady state itself.
Suppose instead that we linearize around the low-inflation steady
state. There the Jacobian's eigenvalues are 1.1291231 and
0.89509305. This eigenvalue configuration, with one explosive root and
one stable root (less than one), means that there is a saddlepath: Given
an initial value for c (or an initial value for [pi]), there is a unique
initial value for [pi] (or for c) such that the economy will converge
from that point to the steady state with low inflation. If either
inflation or consumption were predetermined variables, then this
saddlepath would describe the unique equilibrium at any point in time.
Because neither variable is predetermined, the saddlepath represents one
dimension of equilibrium indeterminacy at any point in time. That is,
any value of c (or [pi]) is consistent with equilibrium in period t, but
as was stated above, once that value of c (or [pi]) has been selected,
the associated value of [pi] (or c) is pinned down, as is the entire
subsequent equilibrium path. (14)
The conventional linearization approach to studying NNS models, as
followed, for example, by King and Wolman (1996), involves implicitly
ignoring the steady state with low inflation. In that approach it is
presumed that the only relevant steady state is the targeted one. From
the same kind of reasoning used in the discussion following (5), the
explosiveness of paths local to the targeted steady state means there is
a unique nonexplosive equilibrium, the steady state itself. One can then
proceed to study the properties of the model when subjected to shocks,
for example to productivity or monetary policy. However, the fact that
there are two steady states suggests that it may be revealing to
investigate the global dynamics. Furthermore, if one extrapolates the
local dynamics around the two steady states, it leads to the conjecture
that paths that explode locally from the targeted steady state may in
fact end up as stable paths converging at the low-inflation steady
state. This is indeed what we will find in studying the global dynamics.
5. GLOBAL DYNAMICS
Studying the model's global dynamics means analyzing the
nonlinear equations ([18] and [16]). We will combine the nonlinear
equations with information about the local dynamics to trace out the
global stable manifold of the low-inflation steady state. The global
stable manifold is the set of inflation and consumption combinations
such that if inflation and consumption begin in that set, there is an
equilibrium path that leads in the long run to the low-inflation steady
state. While this approach may not yield a comprehensive description of
the perfect foresight equilibria, it will provide a coherent picture of
how the two steady states relate to the dynamic behavior of consumption
and inflation. (15) We will find that the local saddlepath can be
understood as part of a path (the global stable manifold) that begins
arbitrarily close to the targeted steady state and cycles around that
steady state with greater and greater amplitude before converging
monotonically to the low-inflation steady state.
From Local to Global
Before plunging into the global dynamics, it may be helpful to take
stock of our knowledge. There are two steady-state equilibria, one with
the targeted inflation rate ([pi]*) and one with a lower inflation rate
([[pi].sub.l]). The levels of consumption in the two steady states are
[c.sub.*] and [c.sub.l]. Local to the targeted steady state, all dynamic
paths oscillate explosively. Local to the low inflation steady state
many paths explode and one path converges to that steady state. To go
further, we will combine the forward dynamics local to the low inflation
steady state with the nonlinear backward dynamics. This approach will
allow us to compute the global stable manifold of the low-inflation
steady state. Since all paths diverge around the targeted steady state,
no analogous approach can be applied there.
As described above, the local dynamics around {[c.sub.l],
[[pi].sub.t]} involve a unique path in {c, [pi]} space that converges to
the steady state. If we begin with a point on that path, very close to
the low-inflation steady state, and then iterate the nonlinear system backward, we can trace out the global dynamics associated with the
saddlepath--the global stable manifold. We now describe this process
algorithmically.
1. To find a point on the local saddlepath of the low-inflation
steady state, follow the approach described in Blanchard and Kahn
(1980). First, decompose the Jacobian matrix j into its Jordan form: j =
P [conjunction] [P.sup.-1], where [conjunction] is a diagonal 2 X 2
matrix whose diagonal elements are the eigenvalues of J, and where P is
a 2 X 2 matrix whose columns are the eigenvectors of J. Next, rewrite
the system in terms of canonical variables [x.sub.1, t]j and [x.sub.2,
t], which are linear combinations of [c.sub.t] and [[pi].sub.t],:
[[x.sub.1, t]. [x.sub.2, t]]' = P[[c.sub.t] - [c.sub.l]
[[pi].sub.t] - [[pi].sub.l]]'. The system is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (20)
Note that at the steady state [c.sub.l], [[pi].sub.l], we have
[x.sub.1, l] = [x.sub.2, l] = 0. Recall that one of the roots
([[lambda].sub.1], [[lambda].sub.2]) is greater than one. Without loss
of generality, assume that [[lambda].sub.1] [greater than] 1. Any point
on the local saddlepath must have [x.sub.1, t] = 0, because [x.sub.1, t
+ j] = [[lambda].sub.1] [x.sub.1, t + j - 1) and if [x.sub.1, t] [not
equal to] 0 then [x.sub.1, t + j] could not approach 0 as j [right
arrow] [infinity]. Select one such point within an [epsilon] ball of the
low-inflation steady state and call that point {[C.sub.T],
[[pi].sub.t]}. Set t = T.
2. From (18) we have
[c.sub.t - 1] = [c.sub.t] / [beta] ([[pi].sub.t] / 1 +
([[pi].sub.*] / [beta] - 1) ([[pi].sub.t] / [pi]*).sup.[lambda]]).
3. Compute [[pi].sup.t - j] by solving (16):
(1 - 1/2 (1 - [epsilon](1 - [chi][c.sub.t - 1]))) [[pi].sub.t -
1.sup.2] - [epsilon] (1 - [chi][c.sup.t - 1])) [[pi].sub.t - 1] -
([c.sub.t - 1] / [theta](1 - [epsilon](1 - [chi] [c.sub.t - 1])) +
[beta]([c.sub.t - 1] / [c.sub.t] ([[pi].sub.t] - 1) [[pi].sub.t])) = 0
(21)
With [c.sub.t - 1], [c.sub.t], and [[pi].sub.t] all known, (21) is
a quadratic equation in [[pi].sub.t - 1]. The presence of two solutions
is rooted in the properties of the firm's profit-maximization
problem--while there is a unique profit-maximizing price, there are
multiple solutions to the first-order condition. Only the positive root
of the quadratic is consistent with the firm maximizing profits--the
negative root typically implies a negative gross inflation rate, which
would imply a negative price level.
4. Set t = t - 1, return to step 2.
Figure 3 describes the results of iterating backward for 450
periods in steps 2 through 4. The figure is in c, [pi] space. It plots
the two steady states and the global stable manifold of the
low-inflation steady state, constructed as just described. The arrows
represent forward movement in time, as opposed to the backward movement
that characterizes the algorithm. The algorithm starts at a point close
to the low-inflation steady state and goes backward in time. The figure
shows that the only path that converges to a steady-state equilibrium
initially involves spirals around the targeted steady state and ends
with monotonic convergence to the low-inflation steady state. The figure
provides us with a unified understanding of the local results around the
two steady states. From the local dynamics we learn that all paths local
to the targeted steady state oscillate explosively. From Figure 3, we
see that one of those paths is not globally explosive, instead
converging at the low-inflation steady state. This path is what we refer
to as the global stable manifold.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
6. CONCLUSION
Since late 2008, both inflation and nominal interest rates have
been extremely Low in the United States. These facts have focused
attention on ideas motivated by the theory in BSU (2001a, 2001b, 2002):
An active Taylor rule, together with a moderate inflation target, could
have the unintended consequence of leading the economy to undesirably
low inflation with a near-zero nominal interest rate. The article by St.
Louis Federal Reserve Bank President James Bullard (2010) represents the
leading example of this attention.
The aim of this article was to provide an accessible introduction
to the ideas in BSU (2001a). Much of the literature in this area uses
models that are either set in continuous time or that assume prices are
flexible. In contrast, the model in this article is set in discrete time and has sticky prices. Discrete time reduces mathematical tractability,
but makes it easy to compute specific solutions; in addition, the
quantitative literature on monetary policy overwhelmingly uses discrete
time models. Sticky prices are also a central element in the applied
monetary policy literature. In adapting BSU's analysis to a
discrete-time framework with sticky prices, we have seen that the
general conclusions of their work also apply to the specific example we
have analyzed. First, with an active Taylor rule, the presence of a
lower bound on the nominal interest rate leads to the presence of two
steady states, one at the targeted inflation rate and one at a lower
inflation rate. Second, the targeted steady state, which is a unique
equilibrium according to the conventional local analysis, instead is the
source for a global stable manifold of the low-inflation steady-state
equilibrium.
In closing we will offer some caveats regarding using the kind of
analysis in this article to interpret current economic outcomes. It is
tempting to conclude from Figure 3 that the low-inflation steady state
is "more likely" because it does possess a stable manifold
while the targeted steady state does not. However, the model only tells
us what equilibria exist, not how likely they are to occur. It is also
tempting to conclude from this work that policy may be unwittingly
leading the economy to the unintended steady state. However, the
theoretical analysis is based on perfect information about the model and
the equilibrium by all agents. It is interesting to think about
situations where policymakers and private decisionmakers do not
understand the structure of the economy, but that is not the situation
analyzed here. Finally, we should stress that before using this kind of
framework for quantitative analysis, it would be desirable to enrich the
model to incorporate capital accumulation. The behavior of the capital
stock plays a key role in interest rate determination, and at this point
it is an open question whether the kind of dynamics described here carry
over to models with capital accumulation.
REFERENCES
Benhabib, Jess, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe, and Martin Uribe. 2001a.
"The Perils of Taylor Rules." Journal of Economic Theory 96
(January): 40-69.
Benhabib, Jess, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe, and Martin Uribe. 2001b.
"Monetary Policy and Multiple Equilibria." American Economic
Review 91 (March): 167-86.
Benhabib, Jess, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe, and Martin Uribe. 2002.
"Avoiding Liquidity Traps." Journal of Political Economy 110
(June): 535-63.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Alan S. Blinder. 1992. "The Federal
Funds Rate and the Channels of Monetary Transmission." American
Economic Review 82 (September): 901-21.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Charles M. Kahn. 1980. "The Solution
of Linear Difference Models Under Rational Expectations."
Econometrica 48 (July): 1,305-11.
Brock, William A. 1975. "A Simple Perfect Foresight Monetary
Model." Journal of Monetary Economics 1 (April): 133-50.
Bullard, James. 2010. "Seven Faces of the Peril." Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 92 (September): 339-52.
Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler. 2000.
"Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and
Some Theory." Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (February):
147-80.
Cochrane, John H. 2011. "Determinacy and Identification with
Taylor Rules." http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/research/Papers/ taylor_rule_jpe_revision.pdf
Goodfriend, Marvin S., and Robert G. King. 1997. "The New
Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy." In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Vol. 12, edited by Ben Bernanke and Julio
Rotemberg. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 231-96.
Henderson, Dale, and Warwick J. McKibbin. 1993. "A Comparison
of Some Basic Monetary Policy Regimes for Open Economies: Implications
of Different Degrees of Instrument Adjustment and Wage
Persistence." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy
39 (December): 221-317.
Kerr, William, and Robert G. King. 1996. "Limits on Interest
Rate Rules in the IS Model." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 82 (Spring): 47-75.
King, Robert G., and Alexander L. Wolman. 1996. "Inflation
Targeting in a St. Louis Model of the 21st Century." Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 78 (May): 83-107.
King, Robert G., and Mark W. Watson. 1998. "The Solution of
Singular Linear Difference Systems Under Rational Expectations."
International Economic Review 34 (November): 1,015-26.
Leeper, Eric. 1991. "Equilibria Under 'Active' and
'Passive' Monetary and Fiscal Policies." Journal of
Monetary Economics 27 (February): 129-47.
Lubik, Thomas A., and Frank Schorfheide. 2004. "Testing for
Indeterminacy: An Application to U.S. Monetary Policy." American
Economic Review 94 (March): 190-217.
McCallum, Bennett T. 1981. "Price Level Determinacy with an
Interest Rate Policy Rule and Rational Expectations." Journal of
Monetary Economics 8: 319-29.
McCallum, Bennett T. 1983. "A Reconsideration of Sims'
Evidence Concerning Monetarism." Economics Letters 13: 167-71.
Michener, Ronald, and B. Ravikumar. 1998. "Chaotic Dynamics in
a Cash-in-Advance Economy." Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control 22 (May): 1,117-37.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 1983. "Speculative
Hyperinflations in Maximizing Models: Can We Rule Them Out?"
Journal of Political Economy 91 (August): 675-87.
Rotemberg, Julio J. 1982. "Sticky Prices in the United
States." Journal of Political Economy 90 (December): 1,187-211.
Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace. 1975.
"'Rational' Expectations, the Optimal Monetary
Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule." Journal of
Political Economy 83 (April): 241-54.
Taylor, John B. 1993. "Discretion versus Policy Rules in
Practice." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39
(December): 195-214.
Woodford, Michael. 1997. "Control of the Public Debt: A
Requirement for Price Stability?" In The Debt Burden and Monetary
Policy, edited by G. Calvo and M. King. London: Macmillan (published
version is excerpted from NBER Working Paper No. 5684 [July]).
Yun, Tack. 1996. "Nominal Price Rigidity, Money Supply
Endogeneity and Business Cycles." Journal of Monetary Economics 37
(April): 345-70.
The views in this paper are those of the authors and do not
represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, the Federal
Reserve Board of Governors, or the Federal Reserve System. For helpful
comments, the authors thank Huberto Ennis, Brian Gaines. Andreas
Horn-stein, and Thomas Lubik. E-mails:
[email protected]@rich.frb.org.
(1) Micherner and Ravikumar (1998) provide a taxonomy of multiple
equilibria in monetary models that predates the recent sticky-price
literature.
(2) Bernanke and Blinder were not the first to suggest modeling
monetary policy in terms of interest rates. See for example McCallum
(1983).
(3) For example, see Blanchard and Kahn (1980) or King and Watson
(1998). In many economic models, explosive paths for some variables are
inconsistent with equilibrium. For example, explosive paths for the
capital stock can be inconsistent with a transversality condintion (in
nontechnical terms, consumers would be leaving money on the table), and
explosive paths for real money balances can violate the requirement of a
nonnegative price level. See Obstfeld and Rogoff (1983) for a discussion
of these issues.
(4) Note that Leeper (1991) emphasizes that an active rule
guarantees uniqueness only in conjunction with an assumption about
fiscal policy, specifically that fiscal policy takes care of balancing
the government budge. We maintain that assumption here. Benhabib,
Schmitt-Grohe, and Uribe (2002) discuss the implication of alternative
assumptions about fiscal policy for multiple equilibria induced by the
zero bound on nominal interest rates.
(5) Throughout the article, interest rates and inflation rates are
measured in gross terms--that is, a 4 percent nominal interest rate
would be written as [R.sub.t] = 1.04.
(6) Imposing the zero bound on an otherwise linear rule creates a
nondifferentiability, making computation more difficult.
(7) Since the model here is itself ad-hoc. we cannot complain about
ruling out explosive paths as equilibria by assumption. Depending on the
particular model, explosive paths up or down may or may not be
equilibria--see footnote 3. What is important here is that the ad-hoc
model we wrote down is nonlinear, and the nonlinear analysis yields
different conclusions about equilibrium than the linear analysis.
(8) Note the sensitivity of this result to whether current or
(expected) future inflation is the argument in the policy rule. If the
policy rule responds to 7rr+i instead of tti, then the same two
steady-state equilibria exist; but the system is entirely static and.
under perfect foresight, the two steady-state equilibria are also the
only two equilibrium values for inflation in any period. The
"economy" can bounce arbitrarily between those two values in a
deterministic way. There may also be rational expectations equilibria
with stochastic fluctuations.
(9) See Cochrane (2011) for a similar argument.
(10) We should note that the term "New Keynesian Phillips
Curve" typically refers to the linearized version of (16).
(11) Note that with current inflation in the policy rule, the
steady states do not change and it would be possible to study dynamic
equilibria in the same way we do here--tentative results suggest that
qualitatively similar results apply with current inflation in the policy
rule. Our approach in this article is positive rather than normative.
For a policymaker choosing a rule, whether multiple equilibria arise
would be one important consideration in that choice.
(12) This statement relies again on [gamma] being sufficiently
large. In contrast low enough [gamma] such that [R.sup.t] ([pi]*)[less
than] 1,the second steady state will involve inflation higher than
([pi]*).
(13) If the targeted inflation rate were zero ([pi]*= 1) then it
would be straightforward to characteriza uniqueness conditions
analytically--this is the standard New Keynesian Phillips Curve. With a
nonzero inflation target there are price-adjustment costs incurred in
steady state, and the analysis is less straightforward.
(14) Because we are dealing here with perfect foresight paths, the
discussion of period t really should apply only to an initial period the
equilibrium outcomes are unique.
(15) While we have not proved that the global stable manifold
contains all perfect foresight equilibria, we conjecture this to the
case