Housing and the Great Recession: a VAR accounting exercise.
Henly, Samuel E. ; Wolman, Alexander L.
Measured in terms of either output or employment, the United States
economy has gone through a period of extreme weakness since early 2008.
Real gross domestic product (GDP) fell by 3.83 percent from the second
quarter of 2008 to the second quarter of 2009. If it had instead grown
at its average post-1982 rate, GDP would have risen by 3.2 percent over
the same interval. Nonfarm payroll employment has fallen by 6.1 percent
from December 2007-February 2010; growth at its average post-1982 rate
would have meant an increase of 3.6 percent over the same interval.
Comparisons to some past episodes, presented in Figure 1, are
useful for evaluating the severity of the current one. The decline in
real GDP in 2008 and 2009 is larger than any that the United States has
experienced since the immediate post-World War II period.1 The next
largest postwar decline was 3.73 percent, from 1957:Q3-1958:Q1. Even in
the early 1980s, GDP never fell below its previous peak by more than
2.87 percent. Employment behavior also looks extreme when compared to
other episodes (see Figure 1, Panel B). Since the end of World War II,
the previous greatest peak-to-trough decline in employment was 4.37
percent from April 1957-June 1958, compared to the 6.1 percent decline
in the Great Recession. And in the early 1980s the peak-to-trough
decline in employment was never greater than 3.1 percent.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
There is thus no doubt about the severity of the decline in
economic activity since late 2007. Understanding why the decline
occurred is more difficult. We aim to take some initial steps toward
such an understanding by studying the behavior of the major components
of output and, in less detail, employment. We will focus especially on
the behavior of the housing components of output and employment. Much
popular commentary on the recession has emphasized the role of the
housing bust and the subsequent (and related) financial crisis. After
documenting that the decline in the housing component of GDP was of
roughly the same magnitude as the decline in GDP itself, we will use
vector autoregressions (VARs) to investigate the extent to which housing
can be identified as a cause of the decline in aggregate activity. While
we do not propose any economic model to explain the recession, our
statistical analysis may be suggestive for subsequent modeling that does
attempt to assign causality.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
1. FACTS ABOUT THE RECESSION
Figure 2 displays the annualized quarterly levels of real GDP
(right scale) and real residential investment (left scale) from 2002 to
the present. Residential investment peaked in the fourth quarter of
2005, and fell $439 billion in real terms through the second quarter of
2009, a decline of more than 56 percent. As reported above, real GDP
peaked in the second quarter of 2008 and bottomed out in the second
quarter of 2009. The 3.8 percent fall in real GDP represents about $514
billion in chained 2005 dollars. Thus, the cumulative decrease in
residential investment so far has been approximately the same magnitude
as the decrease in real GDP that ended in the second quarter of this
year. Just as striking as the similarity in magnitudes is the difference
in timing of the declines in residential investment and GDP: Residential
investment fell steadily for two years before GDP began to fall.
Evidently other components were supporting GDP growth during 2006 and
2007 before weakening in 2008. Figures 3 and 4 show that consumption and
nonresidential investment fit this description; decreases in those two
components--which together account for 80 percent of GDP--were roughly
contemporaneous with the fall in real GDP.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Like output, aggregate employment lagged housing-related employment
in the current recession. Figure 5 displays total nonfarm payroll
employment, along with employment in residential building construction.
The latter peaked in April 2006 at 1.02 million, and has since fallen by
43 percent, to 586,000 in November 2009. Aggregate employment began to
fall 20 months after residential construction employment, in December
2007, and thus far has fallen by 6.1 percent, from 138 million to 130
million. Unlike output, the fall in housing-related employment has been
much smaller in absolute terms than the fall in overall employment. (2)
Even if we add residential specialty trades to residential building
construction, the decline in housing-construction related employment
amounts to only about one-sixth of the total job losses since December
2007.
The data portrayed in Figures 2-5 raise many questions. The
remainder of this article will focus on just one of them: To what extent
did the fall in aggregate output represent the economy's typical
lagged response to a shock to the housing sector? Although overall
employment fell much more than employment in home construction, we can
and will ask the same question about employment. That is: Did the large
fall in overall employment reflect the normal propagation of a shock to
housing? We will determine this normal statistical pattern using vector
autoregressions for the components of output and employment.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
2. BACKGROUND ON VAR METHODOLOGY
A VAR is a statistical model of the behavior across time of a set
of variables. A VAR specifies that the value of each variable in a given
time period is a linear function of (1) the lagged values of all the
variables and (2) one or more exogenous random variables. For our
purposes, a VAR for the components of real GDP (or employment) is useful
because it provides a summary of the relationship between those
components over the sample with which the VAR is estimated. With a VAR,
we will be able to assess whether the recent behavior of real GDP and
employment can be interpreted as reflecting the normal response to a
larse shock to the housing sector.
A VAR for N variables observed over T periods, [Y.sup.t] = {
[y.sub.1], t, [y.sub.2], t, ..., [y.sub.N], t, t = 1,.2,..., T, would be
written as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
In (1), c is a vector of constant terms, [[PHI].sub.k] are
coefficient matrices for each of K lags, and [u.sub.t], is an error
vector. The coefficient matrices, [[PHI].sub.k], can be estimated using
ordinary least squares. (3)
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
We are interested in isolating the aggregate effect of a shock to
the housing component of GDP or employment. Consider the case of GDP and
allow residential investment to be the first element of [Y.sub.t]; an
obvious approach is to treat the first element of [u.sub.t], as the
shock to residential investment, and use the estimated [[PHI].sub.k]
matrices to determine the effect of this shock on all the components of
GDP and thus on GDP itself. Unfortunately, the elements of [u.sub.t] are
generally correlated within the period. That is, a high value for the
first element of [u.sub.t] provides information about other elements of
[u.sub.t], and that information needs to be taken into account in
determining the effect of a shock to residential investment.
The process of accounting for correlation of elements of [u.sub.t]
within a period is called orthogonalization. Let us denote the
covariance matrix of [u.sub.t] by [SIGMA],
Euu' = [SIGMA] (2)
To orthogonalize the N errors [u.sub.t], we decompose them into N
errors [v.sub.t], which are a linear combination H of [u.sub.t],
[v.sub.t] = H[u.sub.t]. (3)
For the matrix H to orthogonalize the errors, it must be the case
that the elements of the resulting vector [v.sub.t] are uncorrected
within the period:
E (vv') = I. (4)
From (2)-(4), it follows that the linear transformation H must be
related to the covariance matrix [SIGMA] as follows:
[H.sup.-1] ([H.sup.-1])' = [SIGMA]. (5)
For ease of notation, define G [equivalent to] [H.sup.-1]. Then we
have
GG' = [SIGMA] (6)
Thus, if we can find a matrix G that satisfies (6), we can
meaningfully trace out the effects of the N different shocks [v.sub.t]
on each of the variables [Y.sub.t]. Unfortunately, there are generally
many matrices G that satisfy (6). We will restrict G to be lower
triangular, meaning that it has only zeros above the diagonal. There is
a unique lower triangular G satisfying (6), and it is known as the
Cholesky matrix.
With the Cholesky approach to orthogonalization, it is natural to
think about the order of variables in the VAR. To make this point clear,
we use a two-variable example:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Note that we have replaced [u.sub.t] in the VAR of (1) with
G[v.sub.t]. We say that [Y.sub.1], t is ordered first in the VAR because
only the first element of [v.sub.t] affects [Y.sub.1], t within the
period. With the Cholesky decomposition there is some justification for
referring to the random variable [v.sub.1], t as a shock to [Y.sub.1],
t. In what follows, we will order the housing component of GDP or
employment first in our VARs and investigate the role of "housing
shocks." By ordering residential investment first, we unambiguously
identify housing shocks--there is only one shock that affects
residential investment independently of the VAR's dynamics (the
[PHI] matrices). Of course, one may wonder whether our results are
robust to different orderings--perhaps there is more than one shock that
affects residential investment contemporaneously. This concern will be
addressed.
3. VAR FOR COMPONENTS OF GDP
Table 1 describes the breakdown of GDP into six components for
which we estimate the VAR, along with the 2002 GDP shares of those
components. (4) The VAR will be specified in log levels for most of the
variables. (5) Net exports and inventory investment need to be treated
differently because they can be negative; we include those variables in
the VAR as shares of GDP. The VAR contains five lags and is estimated
over the period 1985:Q1-2009:Q4. (6)
Table 1 VAR Output Components
Category Share in 2002
Personal Consumption Expenditures (C) 69.4 percent
Government Expenditures (G) 19.7 percent
Nonresidential Fixed Investment (NFI) 10.2 percent
Residential Fixed Investment (RFI) 5.3 percent
Change in Inventories (dI) 0.1 percent
Net Exports (X) -4.8 percent
As described above, the results that we emphasize have residential
investment ordered first in the VAR. The only shocks we study are shocks
to residential investment, so the ordering of the other variables is
inconsequential. Because our primary interest is the relationship
between the decline in housing-related economic activity and the decline
in overall activity, most of our analysis will be based on economic
conditions as of the end of 2005--the peak of housing activity. We will
look at the VAR's forecasts conditional on data through the end of
2005, and then ask how much shocks to residential investment can account
for the deviation of outcomes from the VAR's forecast. The
variables in the VAR represent components of GDP, but we can generate
the VAR's forecasts for GDP itself by appropriately transforming
the component forecasts. (7)
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Baseline Results
Figure 6 displays a full set of impulse response functions for our
baseline specification; the variables are ordered as they appear in the
figure, with residential investment first. Note the relatively large and
persistent effects that shocks to residential investment have on RFI, C,
and NFI, which together account for about 85 percent of GDP. Turning to
the Great Recession, we illustrate some of our main results in Figure 7.
Focus first on the two solid lines, which represent the actual path of
GDP (black) and the path forecasted by the VAR conditional on data
through the end of 2005 (gray). If we define "trend" as the
level of GDP forecasted by the VAR, then GDP was at or above trend until
the third quarter of 2008. In the fourth quarter of 2008 and the first
quarter of 2009 there was a steep decline in GDP. As of the fourth
quarter of 2009, GDP remained approximately 3 percent below trend. (8)
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Next, turn to the dotted line, which represents the VAR forecast
conditional not only on data through 2005 but also conditional on the
estimated path for the residential investment shock. Until late 2006 the
contribution of the residential investment shock was relatively
unimportant in that the forecast conditional on the residential
investment shock is close to the trend line. Starting in 2007, the
residential investment shock accounts for an ever larger shortfall of
GDP relative to trend. Yet until late 2008 GDP remains at or above trend
because other shocks are accounting for an ever larger surplus of GDP
relative to trend. The contribution of these other shocks (the other
elements of [v.sub.t]) is indicated by the gap between the dashed and
the solid gray lines in Figure 7. (9,10) Finally, the effects of other
shocks disappear in importance late in 2008, and the cumulative effect
of shocks to residential investment leaves output well below trend in
mid-2009. In the second half of 2009 other shocks contributed to a
significant increase in GDP, allowing it to come back toward trend.
The most notable aspect of Figure 7 is that, from the standpoint of
late 2005, the level of output in mid-2009--the trough--can be explained
almost entirely by a sequence of shocks to residential investment.
Paraphrasing Section 1, we asked to what extent the unusual decline in
output could be understood as the usual response of output to an unusual
decline in residential investment. Based on the analysis presented in
Figure 7, we have a two-part answer: The severe decline in output from
2008:Q4-2009:Q2 is accounted for primarily by shocks other than
residential investment. However, in the preceding two years those other
shocks had worked in the opposite direction, counteracting the negative
effect of residential investment shocks. Thus, although the sudden
decline in output late in 2008 cannot be explained by the economy's
response to residential investment, the low level of output reached in
mid-2009 can indeed be explained in this way. When filtered by the VAR,
the severe decline in output looks like a delayed response to
residential investment shocks that had been accumulating for years.
As a basic reality check on our story that shocks to residential
investment have been important, it is useful to look at a version of
Figure 7 that substitutes residential investment for GDP. The shock that
we are referring to as a residential investment shock ought to be
important for the behavior of residential investment. Figure 8 shows
this to be the case. Residential investment persistently deviates from
trend, and that deviation is overwhelmingly accounted for by the
residential investment shock.
Our results are remarkably robust to the way variables are ordered
in the VAR. For an ordering with residential investment in the
[n.sup.th] position (our baseline has n = 1), we call the [n.sup.th]
shock the RFI shock. We compare impulse response functions for our
baseline to those for n = 6 and there is little change in the responses
to the RFI shock. We also generate the analogue to Figure 7, showing the
contribution of the RFI shocks to GDP in the current recession, for
every Cholesky ordering. For every ordering, the difference between GDP
in 2009:Q4 and the level explained by RFI shocks only (i.e., the
distance between the solid black line and the dotted line) is less than
1.5 percent in absolute value, and for a majority of the orderings the
difference is less than 0.75 percent. Each ordering also preserves the
property that weakness in GDP coming from RFI shocks was offset by other
shocks in 2007 and early 2008.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Out-of-Sample Approach
Figures 7 and 8 were generated by a VAR for the (log) levels of GDP
components, estimated from 1.985:Q1-2009:Q4. Here we look at the
implications of estimating the VAR only through 2005:Q4. Figures 9 and
10 are analogues to Figures 7 and 8, where the estimation period ends in
2005:Q4--these figures display out-of-sample forecasts. In Figure 9, the
deviation of output from trend at the end of the sample rises to almost
6 percent from 3 percent with the full sample estimates. It is not
surprising that output is further from the perceived trend as of 2005:Q4
than it is from the currently perceived trend. The most striking aspect
of Figure 9, however, is the tremendous "overshooting"
generated by the residential investment shock. The residential
investment shock alone accounts for a shortfall of output from trend
that is more than three times as large as the observed shortfall,
meaning that the other shocks account for a large positive deviation of
output from trend (the dashed line). To understand what is going on
here, it helps to look at Figure 10, which plots residential investment
for this same case. When we estimate only through 2005, the housing bust
is not in the sample, so the post-2005 trend for residential investment
does not involve a large decline (compare the solid gray lines in
Figures 8 and 10). Of course the large decline in residential investment
did occur, and the VAR accounts for that decline primarily with shocks
to residential investment (the dotted line in Figure 10). Those shocks
were extreme by historical standards so, according to the VAR, they
should generate an extreme decline in output--on the order of 21
percent! Such an extreme decline did not occur, so the other shocks must
account for an extreme increase in output (the dashed line in Figure 9).
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
The Housing Boom
Our discussion thus far has centered on the housing bust and the
subsequent decline in real GDP. We can also use VAR methodology to
investigate the housing boom. Figures 11 and 12 provide the same
information as Figures 7 and 8, except that the time scale is shifted
back more than five years, to condition on data as of 2000:Q3 and then
project ahead to 2006:Q1. (11) It is apparent in Figure 11 that, until
late 2003, output was below trend and residential investment shocks
accounted for little of the deviation from trend. For the next
two-and-a-half years, however, output increasingly exceeded trend, and
the deviation is more than accounted for by shocks to residential
investment. Figure 12 shows that residential investment deviated
persistently from trend for the entire period, but it was only after the
middle of 2003 that the residential investment shocks began to account
for an increasing share of the deviation. By the end of the boom period,
shocks to residential investment accounted for most of the deviation of
residential investment from trend. Figures 11 and 12 paint a picture of
the housing boom changing shape in mid-2003. It would be interesting to
investigate whether there is corroborating evidence for this view. For
example, did underwriting standards for home mortgages change around
this time?
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
A Broader Perspective on Housing and Output
Although the VAR results are influenced by data as far back as
1985, we have focused exclusively on interpreting the most recent
business cycle. We showed that a shock to residential investment plays a
central role in accounting for the current shortfall in GDP relative to
trend. The current recession is clearly special in terms of its
magnitude; is it also special in terms of the temporal relationship
between residential investment and output? There is an extensive
literature arguing that housing fluctuations do have predictive power
for future GDP fluctuations, with Learner (2007) as perhaps the most
forceful proponent. Here we provide some findings consistent with that
view.
Figure 13 displays real residential investment for the eight
quarters on either side of the peaks of the eight recessions since 1960.
For each recession, the level of real residential investment is
normalized to be 100 in the quarter of the National Bureau of Economic
Research (NBER) business cycle peak. The figure shows that the peak in
residential investment preceded the business cycle peak for each
recession except for 2001. The current recession is unusual, however, in
the length of time during which residential investment fell before the
business cycle peak, and in the depth of the decline.
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
Next, we estimated a two-variable VAR in (log) residential
investment and GDP, over the period 1959-2009. The top panel of Figure
14 displays the impulse response of GDP to a residential investment
shock when residential investment is ordered first in the VAR. Indeed, a
positive shock to residential investment generates a positive,
hump-shaped response of GDP, with the peak response of GDP occurring
seven quarters after the shock. The same result holds if the ordering of
variables in the VAR is reversed. If we estimate the VAR over the more
recent sample, the same qualitative relationship holds. However, the
elapsed time between the arrival of the residential investment shock and
the peak in GDP increases from seven quarters to 14 quarters (bottom
panel of Figure 14). The 14-quarter lead time may seem high, given that
the most recent peak in residential investment occurred just 10 quarters
before the peak in GDP. Note, however, that the peak in residential
investment most likely was not a period in which there was a large
positive residential investment shock. In fact, the two-variable VAR
shows that the peak own response of residential investment to a shock
occurs nine periods after the shock, using the estimates for the recent
sample.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
4. VAR FOR COMPONENTS OF EMPLOYMENT
In Section 1 we saw that viewing the economy in terms of employment
rather than output led to a rather different picture of the relationship
between housing activity and aggregate activity in the Great Recession.
According to both metrics, the decline in aggregate activity lagged the
decline in housing. However, the raw magnitudes of the decline in
housing and aggregate activity were roughly equal in the case of output,
whereas overall employment fell by more than 8 million, against a
decline in housing employment of just 1.3 million! (12) Based on the raw
data then, it seems unlikely that identified shocks to housing
employment could succeed in explaining the decline in overall employment
in the way that residential investment shocks succeeded in explaining
the decline in GDP. VAR analysis will allow us to investigate formally
whether that intuition holds, or whether there is a large "housing
employment multiplier" that amplifies the aggregate effects of
shocks to housing employment.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
We use data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics's
establishment survey to estimate a VAR for the components of employment.
Employment is categorized differently than output, so the variables in
the VAR will not match up well with the variables in the output VAR.
Table 2 lists the components of employment in the VAR, along with their
shares of total nonfarm employment in 2002. In specifying a component of
employment that represents "housing," one has to choose how to
classify specialty trades (e.g., plumbing, painting). Specialty trades
comprise a sizable fraction of employment in the housing sector: In
2009:Q3 this number was approximately 70 percent. However, prior to
2001, data for specialty trades employees are not broken down into
residential and nonresidential components. Thus, the choice is between
including or omitting all specialty trades from our housing employment
number. We choose to omit specialty trades so as to be confident that
the employment category we call "housing" is not contaminated
by other areas of economic activity, such as commercial construction.
Note that in 2002 residential construction accounted for just 0.6
percent of total nonfarm payroll employment.
Table 2 Employment VAR Components
Category Share in 2002
Services 66.1 percent
Government 16.5 percent
Manufacturing 11.7 percent
Nonresidential Construction 4.5 percent
Residential Construction 0.6 percent
Mining and Logging 0.4 percent
Figure 15 displays the same basic set of results for employment
that Figure 7 displays for output. The level of employment was on trend,
if at all, only through about late 2006, then climbed well above trend
before beginning to plummet--both absolutely and relative to trend--in
the second half of 2008. At the end of the sample, employment lay less
than 2 percent below trend. (13) Unlike what we saw for output, the
innovation to employment in the housing sector for much of the sample
contributes to a positive deviation of employment from trend, although
by the end of the sample that shock explains roughly half the deviation
of employment below trend. This is consistent with our intuition based
on the raw data: The decline in overall employment was so much greater
than the decline in housing-related employment that it seemed unlikely
that the decline in overall employment could be explained as the usual
response to a housing shock. Surprisingly, the housing shock is
relatively unimportant in accounting for the weakness in employment in
housing (Figure 16).
5. CONCLUSION
The NBER-defined recession that began in December 2007 has been
referred to by many as the Great Recession. Indeed, the facts presented
in Figure 1 confirm that the current recession stands out as
particularly severe among post-1950 recessions. Why such a severe
recession occurred is a question that will likely never be answered
definitively. However, researchers in academia, government (including
central banks), and the private sector have argued convincingly for the
importance of various factors in the severity of the recession. Some of
the factors that have been discussed are the financial crisis of
September 2008, the dramatic increase in oil prices from January
2007-July 2008 (Hamilton 2009), and inappropriate monetary policy in
mid-to-late 2008 (Hetzel 2009, Sumner 2009).
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
Almost all discussions of the Great Recession, however, include
some role for the housing boom and bust. Residential investment declined
before and during the Great Recession by about the same amount as GDP,
although the decline in GDP occurred with a lag. This observation led us
to investigate whether the severity of the recession could be understood
as the typical response to a shock emanating from the housing sector.
With respect to output, the answer is a qualified "yes":
Viewed from the peak of the housing boom, subsequent shocks to
residential investment can account for the level of GDP late in 2009.
The qualification is that these shocks to residential investment account
for approximately zero GDP growth over 2007-2009--they do not account
for the sharp decline in late 2008 and early 2009. Similar analysis
conducted on employment data attributes much of the shortfall in
employment from trend to a housing shock by the end of the sample.
However, over much of the sample shocks emanating in home construction
push employment above trend.
Because there is no economics in our VAR model, our results cannot
be used to talk about policies that should have or could have been used
to lessen the recession's severity. Further, our results cannot
rule out that shocks emanating from monetary or financial policy may
have played a role in the Great Recession. However, those results may be
useful as an input to future economic modelling that can be used to
discuss policy. It is clear that any macroeconomic model used to address
the Great Recession ought to have a housing sector. Less trivially, such
a model ought to be consistent with (1) the fact that housing's
contribution to GDP fell by roughly the same amount as the subsequent
fall in GDP, and (2) our finding that a shock originating in, or
initially reflected in, the housing sector can broadly account for the
behavior of GDP during the Great Recession. Any modelling along these
lines also faces the challenge that the sectoral behavior of employment
followed a very different pattern than the sectoral behavior of output.
[FIGURE 16 OMITTED]
(1.) We are defining a decline in real GDP as the difference
between the level at its peak and the level at its subsequent trough. If
there are multiple local troughs before real GDP again reaches its
initial peak, we choose the lowest trough to measure the decline.
(2) In percentage terms, whether one looks at employment or output,
the decline in housin construclion dwarfs the decline in the aggregate
economy.
(3.) There are many good introductory treatments of VAR analysis;
two examples are Sims (1986) and Hamilton (1994).
(4.) We use 2002 to describe the shares because it occurred neither
during the height of the housing boom nor during the depths of the bust.
(5.) See Sims, Stock, and Watson (1990) on levels estimation of
VARs with nonstationary variables.
(6.) We use five lags because we want to capture any residual
seasonality while conserving on parameters, given the relatively short
sample.
(7.) If r, n, c, g, x, i represent, respectively, VAR forecasts for
the logs of residential investment, nonresidential investment,
consumption, and government spending, and the GDP shares of net exports
and inventory investment, we generate the forecast for GDP (Y) as
follows:
Y = (ex[p.sup.r] + ex[p.sup.n] + ex[p.sup.c] + ex[p.sup.g])/(1 - x
- i).
(8.) It is important to emphasize that our version of
"trend" is itself influenced by the Great Recession, since the
VAR was estimated over the full sample.
(9.) Because the VAR is specified in logs, in this and subsequent
figures that plot levels, the distances between (i) the dashed line and
the gray line and (ii) the dotted line and the gray line do not add up
exactly to the distance between the black line and the gray line. In
most cases the discrepancy is small, though it is large in Figure 9.
(10.) From Figures 3 and 4 we can see that these offsetting shocks
were reflected in the behavior of nonresidential investment and
consumption. It would of course be interesting to pursue an economic
interpretation of these offsetting shocks, but we leave that for future
work.
(11.) To generate Figures 11 and 12 we use the same full sample
estimates that generated Figures 7 and 8.
(12.) We define housing employment here as the sum of employment in
residential building construction and residential specialty trade
contractors.
(13.) We define trend as the level of employment predicted (in
sample) by the VAR conditional on data through December 2(305. Although
employment has fallen much more in percentage terms than GDP, according
to the VAR output is actually further from trend than employment.
REFERENCES
Hamilton, James D. 1994. Time Series Analysis. Princeton, NJ.:
Princeton University Press.
Hamilton, James D. 2009. "Causes and Consequences of the Oil
Shock of 2007-2008." Working Paper No. 15002. Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research (May).
Hetzel, Robert L. 2009. "Monetary Policy in the 2008-2009
Recession." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 95
(Spring): 201-33.
Learner, Edward. 2007. "Housing is the Business Cycle."
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Proceedings 2007: 149-233.
Sims, Christopher. 1986, "Are Forecasting Models Usable for
Policy Analysis?" Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review (Winter): 2-16.
Sims, Christopher A., James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson. 1990.
"Inference in Linear Time Series Models with Some Unit Roots."
Econometrica 58 (January): 113-44.
Sumner, Scott. 2009. "The Real Problem was Nominal."
www.cato-unbound.org/2009/09/14/scottsumner/the-real-problem-was-nominal/ (September 14).
The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the
Federal Reserve System. The authors acknowledge helpful comments from
Brian Gaines, Thomas Lubik, Yash Mehra, Pierre Sarte, and John Weinberg.
E-mai 1:
[email protected].