On the benefits of GDP-indexed government debt: lessons from a model of sovereign defaults.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos ; Martinez, Leonardo
Whether governments should issue GDP-indexed sovereign debt--that
promise payments that are a function of the gross domestic product
(GDP)--continues to be the subject of policy debates. On the one hand,
several studies highlight possible benefits from tying sovereign debt
obligations to domestic GDP. (1) One benefit from GDP-indexation is that
issuing debt that promises lower payments when GDP takes low values may
facilitate the financing of automatic stabilizers (such as an increase
in unemployment benefits during economic downturns) and countercyclical
fiscal policy. Another benefit is that GDP indexation could diminish the
likelihood of fiscal crises for governments that face a countercyclical
borrowing cost (in part because of a countercyclical default risk).
Kamstra and Shiller (2010) argue that GDP indexation would help
investors who want exposure to income growth (for instance, to protect
relative standards of living in retirement) and protection against
inflation.
On the other hand, there are several difficulties in the
implementation of the basic idea described in the previous paragraph.
First, GDP-indexed bonds may introduce moral hazard problems by
weakening the government's incentives to implement growth-promoting
policies (see, for instance, Krugman [1988]). Second, GDP may not be
easily verifiable. This is in part because the government could
manipulate the GDP calculation (however, reporting lower GDP figures may
imply a political cost). Moreover, even without manipulation, final GDP
data are available with a significant lag. (2) This could force a
government to make a high payment during a low GDP period because the
previous year GDP was high (problems created by lags in GDP statistics
could be mitigated by provisions on the government's accounts; see
United Nations [2006]). (3) Third, gains from indexing sovereign debt to
GDP may be limited because domestic GDP is not the only determinant of
default risk and the government's borrowing cost (think, for
instance, about contagion, shocks to the investors' risk aversion,
political shocks, etc.; see Tomz and Wright [2007]). Perhaps because of
the implementation difficulties described above, the majority of
sovereign debt is not GDP indexed. However, past experiences show that
issuing GDP-indexed debt is feasible. For instance, Argentina issued GDP
warrants in 2005, during a period of renewed interest in these contracts
(see United Nations [2006]). The 2012 debt restructuring in Greece also
included the issuance of bonds carrying detachable GDP warrants. (4)
This article contributes to the debate on GDP-indexed sovereign
debt by discussing the effects of using this debt contract. We study a
model in which the government faces a countercyclical borrowing cost
because of a countercyclical default risk. We use this model to discuss
the effects of introducing GDP-indexed bonds.
We introduce income-indexed sovereign bonds into the equilibrium
default model studied by Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) and Arellano (2008),
who extend the framework proposed by Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) to
analyze its quantitative performance. We study a small open economy that
receives a stochastic endowment stream of a single tradable good. The
government's objective is to maximize the expected utility of a
representative private agent. Each period, the government makes two
decisions. First, it decides whether to default on previously issued
debt. Second, it decides how much to borrow or save. The cost of
defaulting is given by an endowment loss and temporary exclusion from
capital markets. We study two versions of this model. First, we assume
that the government issues one-period bonds that promise a
non-contingent payment. Second, we assume the government can issue a
one-period income-indexed bond that promises a payment function of
next-period income. In both cases, bonds are priced in a competitive
market inhabited by risk-neutral investors.
We solve the model using the calibration in Arellano (2008), which
is based on an economy facing significant default risk: Argentina before
its 2001 default. The ex-ante welfare gain from the introduction of
income-indexed bonds when there is no initial debt is equivalent to an
increase of 0.5 percent of consumption. Introducing income-indexed bonds
results in welfare gains because it allows the government to:
1. Eliminate defaults. In the model, debt and income are the only
determinants of default. With income-indexed bonds, the government makes
a different payment promise for each level of next-period income, which
means that there is no uncertainty about whether a government promise
will be paid. Then, lenders would never pay for a payment promise on
which they know the government would default and a bond making such a
promise is not traded. In contrast, with non-contingent bonds, when the
government borrows it promises the same payment for all next-period
income levels. The government defaults in the next period at income
levels that are sufficiently low.
2. Increase its indebtedness from 4 percent to 18 percent of mean
income. The government is assumed to be eager to borrow (it discounts
future consumption at a rate higher than the risk-free interest rate).
With indexed bonds, the government can bring forward resources from
future high-income states without increasing the default probability in
low-income states (the cost of defaulting is assumed to be lower in
low-income states). In contrast, with non-contingent bonds, the future
resources the government can bring forward are limited by default risk.
If the government issued a non-contingent bond equivalent to 18 percent
of mean income, for most current income levels the revenue it would
collect from that debt issuance would be even smaller than the revenue
it would collect from issuing debt equivalent to 4 percent of mean
income. The reason is that lenders would internalize that, at a debt of
18 percent of mean income, there is a significant mass of income
realization states at which the government would default, and lenders
would thus offer to buy those bonds at a significant discount.
3. Reduce the ratio of standard deviations of consumption relative
to income from 1.07 to 0.79. With income-indexed bonds, the government
chooses to smooth consumption by buying claims that pay in states with
lower income and borrowing against states with higher income.
Furthermore, the borrowing cost is constant because the government does
not pay a default premium. Thus, the government chooses to borrow more
when income is lower. In contrast, with non-contingent bonds, the
borrowing cost is countercyclical. In bad times, the cost of defaulting
is assumed to be lower and, therefore, the probability of default and
the cost of borrowing are higher. Consequently, optimal borrowing
becomes procyclical: In bad times, since the cost of borrowing is
higher, the government chooses to finance more of its debt service
obligations by lowering consumption instead of borrowing. (5)
It should be noted that our analysis does not consider the
implementation difficulties of GDP-indexed bonds that we mentioned
above: We assume that the goverment cannot affect GDP growth, that bond
payments can be determined using current income, and that income is the
only determinant of sovereign defaults. Thus, the gains from introducing
GDP-indexed bonds measured in this article should be seen as an upper
bound. Relaxing the simplifying assumptions that limit our analysis
increases the dimensionality of the model's state space and thus
augments the computation time required to solve the model. Relaxing
these simplifying assumptions is the subject of our ongoing research but
is beyond the scope of this article.
In spite of the interest in GDP-indexed bonds among policymakers,
there are few formal studies of the effects of introducing these bonds.
Athanasoulis and Shiller (2001) and Durdu (2009) also study the effects
of GDP-indexed debt but in frameworks without endogenous borrowing
constraints determined by default risk.
Chamon and Mauro (2006) study the effects of introducing
GDP-indexed bonds using a debt sustainability framework, commonly used
in policy institutions. Because of the low computation cost of solving
this framework, Chamon and Mauro (2006) can study a set of debt
instruments richer than the one we study in this article. However, a
disadvantage of the sustainability framework is that the
government's borrowing (the primary balance) is estimated using
past data and is not the result of an optimization problem. Thus, the
analysis assumes that the government's borrowing does not change
when indexed bonds are introduced (in contrast with our findings).
Furthermore, their debt sustainability framework does not allow default
risk to affect the borrowing cost. The framework is also not suitable
for the derivation of the optimal indexation. As we do, Chamon and Mauro
(2006) find that indexation could reduce default risk.
Faria (2011); Sandleris, Sapriza, and Taddei (2011); and Hatchondo,
Martinez, and Sosa Padilla (2012) study the effects of introducing
GDP-indexed sovereign debt in an environment with equilibrium default
risk. Comparing quantitative predictions of these studies is difficult
because of differences in the parameterizations and the reported
statistics. Faria (2011) and Sandleris, Sapriza, and Taddei (2011)
present the effects of introducing an income-indexation that is not
chosen by the government and is constant over time. As in this article,
Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sosa Padilla (2012) allow the government to
choose how to index its debt to future income in each period. Hatchondo,
Martinez, and Sosa Padilla (2012) compare the effects of introducing
income indexation with the ones of introducing interest-rate indexation.
The latter form of indexation is the main focus of that article.
The rest of the article proceeds as follows. Section 1 introduces
the model. Section 2 discusses the parameterization. Section 3 presents
the results. Section 4 concludes.
1. THE MODEL
There is a single tradable good. The economy receives a stochastic
endowment stream of this good [y.sub.t] with
log([y.sub.t]) = log(A) + [rho]log([y.sub.t-1]) + [[epsilon].sub.t]
with |[rho]| < 1, and [[epsilon].sub.t] ~ N (0,
[[delta].sub.[member of].sup.2]).
The government's objective is to maximize the present expected
discounted value of future utility flows of the representative agent in
the economy, namely
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
where E denotes the expectation operator, [beta] denotes the
subjective discount factor, and the utility function is assumed to
display a constant coefficient of relative risk aversion denoted by
[gamma]. That is,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
Each period, the government makes two decisions. First, it decides
whether to default. Second, it chooses the number of bonds that it
purchases or issues in the current period. (6)
There are two costs of defaulting (Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza
[2007a} discuss the costs of sovereign defaults). First, a defaulting
sovereign is excluded from capital markets. In each period after the
default period, the country regains access to capital markets with
probability [psi] [member of] [0, 1] (7) Second, if a country has
defaulted on its debt, it faces an income loss of [phi] (y) units in
every period in which it is excluded from capital markets. Following
Arellano (2008), we assume that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
With this income loss function, the default cost rises more than
proportionately with income. This property of the income loss triggered
by defaults helps the equilibrium default model to match the high
sovereign spreads--defined as the difference between the sovereign bond
yield and a risk-free interest rate--observed in the data (see, for
instance, the discussion of the effects of the income loss function in
Chatterjee and Eyigungor {forthcoming]). This is also a property of the
income loss triggered by default in Mendoza and Yue (2012). (8)
We focus on Markov perfect equilibrium. That is, we assume that in
each period, the government's equilibrium default and borrowing
strategies depend only on payoff-relevant state variables. As discussed
by Kruse11 and Smith (2003), there may be multiple Markov perfect
equilibria in infinite-horizon economies. In order to avoid this
problem, we solve for the equilibrium of the finite-horizon version of
our economy, and we increase the number of periods of the finite-horizon
economy until value functions for the first and second periods of this
economy are sufficiently close. We then use the first-period equilibrium
functions as the infinite-horizon-economy equilibrium functions.
Government bonds are priced in a competitive market. Lenders can
borrow or lend at the risk-free rate r, are risk neutral, and have
perfect information regarding the economy's income.
We study two versions of this model. First, we assume the
government can issue non-contingent bonds. Each bond is a promise to
deliver one unit of the good in the next period. Second, we assume the
government can issue an indexed bond that promises a next-period payment
that is a function of next-period income.
Recursive Formulation with Non-Contingent Bonds
Let b denote the government's current bond position, and
b' denote its bond position at the beginning of the next period. A
negative value of b implies that the government was a net issuer of
bonds in the previous period. Let d denote the current-period default
decision. We assume that d = 1 if the government defaulted in the
current period and d = 0 if it did not. Let V denote the
government's value function at the beginning of a period, that is,
before the default decision is made. Let [V.sub.0] denote the value
function of a sovereign not in default. Let [V.sub.1] denote the value
function of a sovereign in default. Let F denote the conditional
cumulative distribution function of the next-period endowment y'.
Let h and g denote the optimal default and borrowing rules followed by
the government. The default rule h takes one of two values: 0 if the
rule prescribes to pay back, and I if the rule prescribes to default.
The price of a bond equals the payment a lender expects to receive
discounted at the risk-free rate. The bond price is given by the
following functional equation:
q(b', y) = 1/(1 + r)[integral][1 - h (b', y')]
F(dy'| y). (4)
This bond price satisfies a lender's expected-zero-profit
condition and is equal to the payment probability discounted by the
risk-free interest rate. Recall a bond promises to pay one unit of the
consumption good next period. Thus, the payment the holder of a bond
will receive next period with the state (b', y') is given by
[1 - h (b', y')].
For a given price function q, the government's value function
V satisfies the following functional equation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
where
[V.sub.1](y) = u(y) - [phi](y)) + [beta][integral][[psi]V(0, y) +
(1 - [psi]) [V.sub.1](y')] F(dy'| y), (6)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
Definition 1 A Markov perfect equilibrium is characterized by
1. a set of value functions V, [V.sub.1], and [V.sub.0],
2. a default rule h and a borrowing rule g,
3. a bond price function q,
such that:
(a) given h and g, V, [V.sub.1], and [V.sub.0] satisfy functional
equations (5), (6), and (7), when the government can trade bonds at the
bond price function q;
(b) the bond price function q is given by equation (4); and
(c) the default rule h and borrowing rule g solve the dynamic
programming problem defined by equations (5) and (7) when the price at
which the government can trade bonds is given by the bond price function
q.
Recursive Formulation with the Indexed Bond
With the income-indexed bond, the government can choose what to
promise to pay next period for each realization of next-period income
y' (payments can be negative). Let [^.b'] denote the payment
function promised by the government. Let [^.g] and [^.h] denote the
govemment's borrowing and default rules, respectively.
As in the previous subsection, a bond price is equal to the
expected payment a lender will receive, discounted at the risk-free
rate. For the indexed bond, this price is given by
[^.q]([^.b'], y) = 1/1 + r
[integral][^.b']([^.y'])[1 - [^.h]([^.b']([^.y'],
y')] F (dy' | y). (8)
Note that, with N possible income levels {[y.sub.1], [y.sub.2],
..., [y.sub.N]), we could think about the government choosing a
portfolio of N defaultable Arrow-Debreu securities instead of the
payments of an income-indexed bond. For all i [member of] {1, 2, ...,
N}, security i promises to deliver one unit of the good in the next
period if and only if y' = yi. The price of each of these
securities is equal to the expected payment the lender will receive. Let
[b.sub.i] denote the number of securities issued by the government
promising to pay if and only if y' = [y.sub.i]. Let [P.sub.i](y)
denote the probability of y' = [y.sub.i] given current income y.
The price of a security promising to pay if and only if y' =
[y.sub.i] is equal to the likelihood of y' = [y.sub.i] multiplied
by the payment the lender would receive (1 - [^.h]([b.sub.i],
[y.sub.i])), and discounted at the risk-free rate:
[~.q]([b.sub.i], y) = 1/1 + r[1 - [^.h]([b.sub.i], [y.sub.i])]
[P.sub.i](y) (9)
Without loss of generality, we assume that the government only
promises payments [^.b'](y') for which it would not choose to
default. Since the government makes a different promise for each level
of next-period income, and debt and income are the only determinants of
default, there is no uncertainty about whether a government promise will
be paid. Note that, for any payment [^.b'](y') on which the
government would choose to default ([^.h]([^.b'](y'), y')
= 1), the contribution of [^.b'](y') to the bond price in
equation (8) is equal to zero. Then, the government cannot gain from
promising a payment [^.b'](y') on which it would choose to
default. (9) In contrast, without income indexation, the government may
issue a bond promising a payment on which it will default next period in
some states (y') but not in other states. Since the government may
pay next period, lenders are willing to pay for a defaultable bond.
Let [W.sub.1] denote the value function of a government in default.
Since a defaulting government does not pay its debt, W1 is not a
function of the debt level.
Let [W.sub.0] denote the value function of a government not in
default. When the government pays it debt, its expected utility is a
decreasing function of its debt leve1. (10)
Since [W.sub.0] is decreasing with respect to the government's
debt level and WI is not a function of the government debt level, for
any income level y, there exists a debt level B(y) such that the
government defaults if and only if its debt level is higher than--B(y).
This debt threshold satisfies [W.sub.0](B(y), y) = [W.sub.1](y), where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (10)
s.t. c = y + b - 1/1 + r
[integral][^.b'](y')F(dy'|y) (11)
[^.b'](y') [greater than or equal to] B(y') for all
y', (12)
and
[W.sub.1](y) = u (y - [phi](y)) +
[beta][integral][[psi][W.sub.0](0, y') + (1 -
[psi])[W.sub.1](y')] F(dy'| y). (13)
One way of thinking about the government's lack of commitment
to its future default decisions is to suppose that, each period,
decisions are made by a different government, and that the current
government has no control over future governments' decisions. For
instance, the borrowing constraint in equation (12) is exogenous to the
current government because B(y') is determined by the next-period
government's default decision and the current government cannot
control that decision.
The borrowing constraint in equation (12) is the only difference
between the economy with indexed bonds and an Arrow-Debreu economy. A
binding borrowing constraint would be the source of inefficiency in the
indexed-debt economy.
Definition 2 A Markov pedect equilibrium is characterized by
1. a set of value functions [W.sub.0] and [W.sub.1],
2. a borrowing rule [^.g],
3. debt thresholds B(y'),
such that:
(a) given the borrowing rule [^.g] and debt thresholds B(y'),
[W.sub.0] and [W.sub.1] satisfy functional equations (10) and (13);
(b) given debt thresholds B(y'), the borrowing rule [^.g]
solves the dynamic programming problem defined by equation (10); and
(c) B(y) satisfies [W.sub.0](B(y), y) = [W.sub.1](y).
2. PARAMETERIZATION
We solve the model for the parameterization presented by Arellano
(2008). This parameterization was chosen to mimic some moments of the
Argentinean economy: properties of the GDP time series and the standard
deviation of the trade balance from 1993-2001, an average debt
service-to-GDP of 5.53 percent between 1980 and 2001, and a default
frequency of 3 defaults per 100 years chosen after counting 3 defaults
in the last 100 years for Argentina. Each period corresponds to a
quarter. Table 1 presents the parameter values.
Table 1 Parameter Values
Sovereign's Risk Aversion [gamma] 2
Interest Rate r 0.017
Income Autocorrelation [rho] 0.945
Coefficient
Standard Deviation of [[sigma].sub.[member of]] 0.025
Innovations
Income Scale A 10
Exclusion Length [psi] 0.282
Discount Factor [beta] 0.953
Default Cost [lambda] 0.969 E(y)
The parameterization studied by Arellano (2008) is a common
reference for quantitative studies of sovereign defaults. However, some
important limitations of this parameterization have been documented in
the literature. A model with one-period bonds targeting the average debt
service-to-GDP ratio results in debt levels that are too low compare to
the data (Hatchondo and Martinez [2009]; Arellano and Ramanarayanan
[2012]; Hatchondo, Martinez, and Roch [2012]; and Chatterjee and
Eyigungor [forthcoming] study frameworks with long-term debt). Targeting
a default frequency of 3 defaults per 100 years implies that the model
generates sovereign spreads that are lower than the ones observed in
Argentina before its 2001 default. This occurs in part because the model
assumes risk-neutral lenders (Lizarazo [2006], Arellano [2008], and Born
i and Verdelhan [2009] present models with risk-averse lenders).
We solve the models numerically using value function iteration. We
find two value functions: one for a government not in default, and one
for a government in default (i.e., [V.sub.0] and [V.sub.1], or [W.sub.0]
and [W.sub.1]). We discretize endowment levels and we use spline
interpolation for asset positions. The stochastic process for the
endowment is discretized using Tauchen (1986) on a uniformly distributed
grid of endowment realizations. We center points around the mean and we
use a width of three standard deviations. We use 200 endowment grid
points. (11)
3. RESULTS
Table 2 reports moments in the simulations of the models with
non-contingent and indexed bonds. Statistics correspond to the mean of
the value of each moment in 500 simulation samples. Each sample consists
of 32 periods before a default episode. The simulations in the economy
with state-contingent claims are computed using the same 500 samples of
32 periods that were used to compute the simulations in the benchmark
economy. The interest rate spread ([r.sub.s]) is expressed in annual
terms. The trade balance (income minus consumption) is expressed as a
fraction of income (tb = (y - c)/y). The logarithm of income and
consumption are denoted by [~.y] and [~.c], respectively. The standard
deviation of x is denoted by [sigma] (x) and is reported in percentage
terms. The coefficient of correlation between x and z is denoted by
[rho] (x, z). Moments are computed using detrended series. Trends are
computed using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of
1,600.
Table 2 Simulation Statistics
Non-Contingent Indexed Bonds
Bonds
[sigma] ([~.y]) 5.58 5.58
Defaults per 100 Years 2.82 0.00
E ([r.sub.s]) 3.24 0.00
[sigma] ([r.sub.s]) 2.92 0.00
Mean Debt (% of Mean Income) 3.94 17.89
[sigma]([~.c])/[sigma]([~.y]) 1.07 0.79
[sigma] (tb) 1.13 1.81
[rho] (tb, [~.y]) -0.24 0.69
[rho] ([r.sub.s], [~.y]) -0.36 0.00
[rho] ([~.c], [~.y]) 0.98 0.96
Table 2 shows that the income-indexed bond allows the government to
avoid defaults. With non-contingent bonds, the government, when it
borrows, promises payments for which it would choose to default if
next-period income is low. In contrast, with income-indexed bonds the
government cannot gain from promising a payment for which it would
choose to default.
Table 2 also shows that income-indexed bonds allow the government
to increase its mean level of indebtedness from 4 percent to 18 percent
of mean income. With non-contingent bonds, if the government were to
promise to pay 18 percent of mean income, the probability of default
would be very high and the government would have to pay a very high
interest rate to compensate lenders for default risk. That interest rate
would be high enough to deter the government from choosing such high
debt levels. In contrast, with indexed bonds, the government can promise
to pay more when next-period income is higher, which implies a higher
cost of defaulting (see equation (3)). That is, with indexed bonds, the
government can bring to the present resources from future high-income
states without increasing the probability of default in low-income
states. Figure 1 illustrates how this is in fact what the government
chooses to do. (12) Recall that in the model the government is eager to
borrow because it discounts future consumption at a rate higher than the
risk-free interest rate.
In addition, Table 2 shows that income-indexed bonds allow the
government to reduce the ratio of standard deviations of consumption
relative to income from 1.07 to 0.79. A mirror result is that the trade
balance is procyclical with income-indexed bonds and countercyclical
with non-contingent bonds. To account for this result, note first that
income-indexed bonds allow the government to smooth consumption by
buying claims that pay in states with lower next-period income and
borrowing against states with higher next-period income (see Figure 1).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Furthermore, as shown in Table 2, the spread is countercyclical in
the economy with non-contingent bonds. In bad times, the cost of
defaulting is lower (see equation (3)) and, therefore, the probability
of default and the cost of borrowing are higher. Consequently, optimal
borrowing becomes procyclical: In bad times, since the cost of borrowing
is higher, the government chooses to finance more of its debt service
obligations by lowering consumption instead of borrowing. In contrast,
with indexed bonds, the cost of borrowing is constant and thus the
government chooses to borrow more when income is lower.
Figure 2 presents the distribution of welfare gains from
implementing indexed bonds. We compute this distribution using all
combinations of income and debt levels in the simulations with
non-contingent bonds, for periods with access to capital markets. For
each combination of debt and income, we measure welfare gains as the
constant proportional change in consumption that would leave a consumer
indifferent between living in the economy with non-contingent debt and
in the economy with income-indexed bonds. This consumption change is
given by
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[([W.sub.0] (b, y)/[V.sub.0] (b, y)).sup.(1/(1 - r))] - 1,
and can be easily derived from equations (1) and (2). A positive
value means that agents prefer the economy with income-indexed bonds.
For instance, the figure shows that for 50 percent of the combinations
of income and debt levels we consider, welfare gains are higher than
0.45 percent.
Figure 2 shows that, for all combination of income and debt levels
we consider, the welfare gain from introducing indexed bonds is
positive. On average, this gain is equivalent to an increase of 0.46
percent of consumption.
Figure 3 depicts the distribution of welfare gains computed
comparing the economy with indexed debt with a hypothetical economy in
which there are no income losses triggered by defaults but in which the
government follows the saving and default rules of the benchmark economy
with non-contingent debt. The figure indicates that income losses
triggered by defaults play a relatively small role in accounting for the
welfare gains from introducing indexed debt. Most welfare gains from
intruding indexed debt come from the relaxation of the government's
borrowing constraint: Indexed debt allows the government to borrow more
and smooth consumption. The small role of income losses triggered by
defaults is not surprising since defaults are infrequent and occur in
periods where income losses are small (see equation (3)).
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
4. CONCLUSIONS
We introduced income-indexed bonds into a standard sovereign
default model and illustrated how a government may benefit from using
these bonds instead of non-contingent bonds. Income-indexed bonds allow
the government to avoid costly default episodes, increase its level of
indebtedness, and improve consumption smoothing.
There are difficulties from issuing income-indexed bonds that are
not present in our setup. First, we do not consider difficulties that
may arise in the verifiability of the state on which the debt contracts
are written. Second, there may be other shocks that could affect the
willingness to repay. Third, we circumvent moral hazard problems that
could be created by the introduction of GDP-indexed bonds. Expanding our
analysis would enhance the understanding of the effects of introducing
indexed sovereign bonds and is the subject of our ongoing research.
REFERENCES
Aguiar, Mark, and Gita Gopinath. 2006. "Defaultable Debt,
Interest Rates and the Current Account." Journal of International
Economics 69 (June): 64-83.
Arellano, Cristina. 2008. "Default Risk and Income
Fluctuations in Emerging Economies." American Economic Review 98
(June): 690-712.
Arellano, Cristina, and Ananth Ramanarayanan. 2012. "Default
and the Maturity Structure in Sovereign Bonds." Journal of
Political Economy 120: 187-232.
Athanasoulis, Stefano G., and Robert J. Shiller. 2001. "World
Income Components: Measuring and Exploiting International Risk Sharing
Opportunities." American Economic Review 91 (September): 1,031-54.
Bianchi, Javier, Juan Carlos Hatchondo, and Leonardo Martinez.
2012. "International Reserves and Rollover Risk." Mimeo.
Borensztein, Eduardo, Marcos Chamon, Oliver Jeanne, Paolo Mauro,
and Jeromin Zettelmeyer. 2004. "Sovereign Debt Structure for Crisis
Prevention." IMF Occasional Paper 237.
Borensztein, Eduardo, and Paolo Mauro. 2004. "The Case for
GDP-Indexed Bonds." Economic Policy 19: 165-216.
Borensztein, Eduardo, and Ugo Panizza. 2008. "The Costs of
Sovereign Default." IMF Working Paper 08/238 (October).
Boni, Nicola, and Adrien Verdelhan. 2009. "Sovereign Risk
Premia." Manuscript, MIT.
Caballero, Ricardo. 2002. "Coping with Chile's External
Vulnerability: A Financial Problem." Central Bank of Chile Working
Paper 154.
Chamon, Marcos, and Paolo Mauro. 2006. "Pricing Growth-Indexed
Bonds." Journal of Banking & Finance 30 (December): 3,349-66.
Chatterjee, Satyajit, and Burcu Eyigungor. Forthcoming.
"Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk." American Economic
Review.
Chatterjee, Satyajit, Dean Corbae, Makoto Nakajima, and Jose-Victor
Rios-Rull. 2007. "A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer
Credit with Risk of Default." Econometrica 75 (November): 1,525-89.
Durdu, Ceyhun Bora. 2009. "Quantitative Implications of
Indexed Bonds in Small Open Economies." Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control 33 (April): 883-902.
Eaton, Jonathan, and Mark Gersovitz. 1981. "Debt with
Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical Analysis." Review
of Economic Studies 48 (April): 289-309.
Faria, Andre L. 2007. "Growth-Indexed Bonds in Emerging
Markets: A Quantitative Approach." Mimeo.
Gavin, Michael, and Roberto Perotti. 1997. "Fiscal Policy in
Latin America." In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997 Volume/2, edited
by Ben S. Bemanke and Julio J. Rotemberg. Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research, 11-71.
Griffith-Jones, Stephany, and Krishnan Sharma. 2005. "GDP
Indexed Bonds: Making it Happen." United Nations Department of
Economic and Social Affairs Working Paper 21 (April).
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, and Leonardo Martinez. 2009.
"Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults." Journal of
International Economics 79 (September): 117-25.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, and Leonardo Martinez. 2010. "The
Politics of Sovereign Defaults." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 96 (3): 291-317.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Cesar Sosa Padilla.
2010. "Debt Dilution and Sovereign Default Risk." Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper 10-08R.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Francisco Roch.
2012. "Fiscal Rules and the Sovereign Default Premium."
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper 12-01 (March).
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Horacio Sapriza.
2007a. "The Economics of Sovereign Default." Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 93 (Spring): 163-97.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Horacio Sapriza.
2007b. "Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default and the Threat of
Financial Exclusion." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly 93 (Summer): 251-86.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Horacio Sapriza.
2009. "Heterogeneous Borrowers in Quantitative Models of Sovereign
Default." International Economic Review 50 (November): 1,129-51.
Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Horacio Sapriza.
2010. "Quantitative Properties of Sovereign Default Models:
Solution Methods Matter." Review of Economic Dynamics 13 (4):
919-33.
Ilzetzki, Ethan, and Carlos A. Vegh. 2008. "Procyclical Fiscal
Policy in Developing Countries: Truth or Fiction?" Working Paper
14191. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (July).
Kaminsky, Graciela L., Carmen M. Reinhart, and Carlos A. Vegh.
2004. "When It Rains, It Pours: Procyclical Capital Flows and
Macroeconomic Policies" In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2004, Volume
19, edited by Mark Gertler and Kenneth Rogoff. Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research, 11-53.
Kamstra, Mark J., and Robert J. Shiller. 2010. "Trills Instead
of T-Bills: It's Time to Replace Part of Government Debt with
Shares in GDP." The Economists' Voice Volume 7, Issue 3,
Article 5 (September).
Krugman, Paul R. 1988. "Financing vs. Forgiving a Debt
Overhang." Journal of Development Economics 29 (November): 253-68.
Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. 2003.
"Consumption-Savings Decisions with Quasi-Geometric
Discounting." Econometrica 71 (January): 365-75.
Lizarazo, Sandra. 2006. "Contagion of Financial Crises in
Sovereign Debt Markets." ITAM Working Paper.
Mendoza, Enrique G., and Vivian Z. Yue. 2012. "A General
Equilibrium Model of Sovereign Default and Business." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 127 (2): 889-946.
Sandleris, Guido, Horacio Sapriza, and Filippo Taddei. 2011.
"Indexed Sovereign Debt: An Applied Framework." Collegio Carlo
Alberto Working Paper 104 (November).
Shiller, Robert. 1993. Macro Markets: Creating Institutions for
Managing Society's Largest Economic Risks. New York, N.Y.: Oxford
University Press.
Talvi, Ernesto, and Carlos A. Vegh. 2005. "Tax Base
Variability and Procyclical Fiscal Policy in Developing Countries."
Journal of Development Economics 78 (October): 156-90.
Tauchen, George. 1986. "Finite State Markov-Chain
Approximations to Univariate and Vector Autoregressions." Economics
Letters 20 (2): 177-81.
Tomz, Michael, and Mark L. J. Wright. 2007. "Do Countries
Default in 'Bad Times?" Journal of the European Economic
Association 5: 352-60.
United Nations. 2006. "GDP-Indexed Bonds: An Idea Whose Time
has Come." Seminar Report held at the International Monetary Fund,
Washington, D.C., April 21.
Vegh, Carlos A., and Guillermo Vuletin. 2011. "How is Tax
Policy Conducted Over the Business Cycle?" University of Maryland
Working Paper.
(1.) See, for instance, Shiller (1993), Borensztein and Mauro
(2004), Borensztein et al. (2004), Griffith-Jones and Sharma (2005), and
the references therein.
(2.) For instance, payments for the GDP warrants issued by
Argentina during its 2005 debt restructuring arc made effective with a
one-year lag.
(3.) These problems could be addressed by indexing debt contracts
to variables that are correlated to GDP and that the government cannot
control (such as commodity prices or trading partners' growth
rates; see Caballero [20021).
(4.) Other experiences with GDP indexation include various
"Value Recovery Rights" indexed to GDP issued by Bosnia and
Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Costa Rica, Nigeria, and Venezuela in the early
1990s as part of the Brady bonds restructuring (Sandleris, Sapriza, and
Taddei 2011). For instance, Bulgaria issued, in 1994, bonds with a
potential premium if Bulgaria's GDP exceeded 125 percent of its
1993 level.
(5.) This is consistent with evidence of procyclical fiscal policy
in emerging economies (that pay a high and volatile interest rate), as
documented by Gavin and Perotti (1997); Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Vegh
(2004); Talvi and Vegh (2005); llzetzki and Vegh (2008); and Vegh and
Vuletin (2011).
(6.) Bianchi, Hatchondo, and Martinez (2012) study a sovereign
default framework where the government can issue debt and accumulate
assets simultaneously.
(7.) Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza (2007b) solve a baseline
model of sovereign default with and without the exclusion cost and show
that eliminating this cost affects significantly only the debt level
generated by the model. Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza (2009) argue
that lower borrowing levels after a default could be explained by
political turnover that triggered a default (see, also, Hatchondo and
Martinez [2010] for a discussion of the interaction between political
factors and default decisions).
(8.) Mendoza and Yue (2012) introduce an endogenous channel through
which defaults decrease output in the defaulting economy: They assume
that when the government defaults, local firms lose access to foreign
credit, which is necessary to finance the purchases of foreign inputs.
(9.) Equivalently, with Arrow-Debreu securities, if the government
chooses a bi for which it would choose to default next period
[b.sub.i]([^.h]([b.sub.i], [y.sub.i]) = 1), lenders would not pay for
[b.sub.i] ([~.q]([b.sub.i], y) = 0).
(10.) This is also a property of [V.sub.0]. Chatterjee et al.
(2007) provide a formal characterization of equilibrium functions in a
default model.
(11.) We do not find significant differences in the welfare gains
from introducing indexed debt when we use 100 grid points instead
(Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sapriza [2010] discuss the sensitivity of a
default model's predictions to changes in the grid specification).
(12.) The figure also shows that the indexed-debt borrowing limit
binds for sufficiently high next-period income. Furthermore, the figure
shows that with non-contingent debt, the government only issues debt
with a face value of 1.2 percent of current income.
For helpful comments, we thank Kartik Athreya, Huberto Ennis,
Andreas Hornstein, and Tim Hursey. The views expressed herein are those
of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive
Board, or its management; the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond; or the
Federal Reserve System. E-mail:
[email protected].