Orderly Liquidation Authority as an alternative to bankruptcy.
Pellerin, Sabrina R. ; Walter, John R.
When a large nonbank financial firm becomes troubled and in danger
of default, government policymakers traditionally have had two options:
they could 1) allow the firm to enter bankruptcy, or 2) if policymakers
believed bankruptcy is likely to produce widespread (system-wide or
"systemic") financial difficulties, the government could
provide aid (i.e., a bailout) to forestall failure. In 2010, a third
option was made available by the Orderly Liquidation Authority (OLA)
provisions, contained in the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection
Act (the "Dodd-Frank Act"). This legislation authorizes the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) to pursue an
agency-administered wind down for certain troubled financial firms. The
OLA provisions are modeled, in part, after the process long followed by
the FDIC for handling troubled banks.
The OLA provisions are a reaction to policymakers' and
legislators' dissatisfaction with the two options previously
available for handling failing nonbanks. For example, Ben Bernanke,
chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
argued, in 2009 testimony before the House Committee on Financial
Services, that bankruptcy was not an effective option for certain
failing financial firms (Bernanke 2009):
In most cases, the federal bankruptcy laws provide an appropriate
framework for the resolution of nonbank financial institutions.
However, the bankruptcy code does not sufficiently protect the
public's strong interest in ensuring the orderly resolution of
a nonbank financial firm whose failure would pose substantial
risks to the financial system and to the economy. Indeed, after
Lehman Brothers and AIG's experiences, there is little doubt
that we need a third option between the choices of bankruptcy
and bailout for such firms.
In a 2010 speech, Chairman Bernanke expanded on his testimony and
noted two goals for this "third option," or "orderly
resolution" authority (Bernanke 2010):
The government instead must have the tools to resolve a
failing firm in a manner that preserves market discipline--by
ensuring that shareholders and creditors incur losses and that
culpable managers are replaced--while at the same time
cushioning the broader financial system from the possibly
destabilizing effects of the firm's collapse.
Legislators focused on these two goals in the language of the
Dodd-Frank Act itself when explaining the purposes of the OLA provisions
(or the OLA "title"):
It is the purpose of this title to provide the necessary
authority to liquidate failing financial companies that
pose a significant risk to the financial stability of
the United States in a manner that mitigates such risk
and minimizes moral hazard.
In this article we review the features of bankruptcy and the OLA.
We identify some problem areas when large nonbank financial firm
failures are resolved through bankruptcy. We then describe two important
features of the OLA that are meant to improve on bankruptcy as a means
of handling these types of failures, and discuss how they attempt to
achieve the goals of mitigating risk to financial stability while also
minimizing moral hazard--goals that are not easily achieved
simultaneously.
1. FAILURE RESOLUTION
Goals of any Failure Resolution Regime
Any resolution regime, whether bankruptcy, bailout, or OLA, must
address two fundamental problems that arise when a firm faces financial
troubles and becomes unable to repay creditors. These three regimes each
take different approaches to solving these problems, and these differing
approaches are at the core of each regime. The first problem (detailed
below) is preserving "asset complementarities" and
"going-concern value" in the face of detrimental creditor
incentives to rush in and grab the firm's assets immediately upon a
firm's default. Resolution methods must take these incentives into
account and prevent the detrimental actions. The second problem is
determining whether to "liquidate" or "reorganize"
the troubled firm. Beyond addressing these two problems, an additional
concern arises when the troubled firm is a large financial firm or one
with many interconnections with other financial firms: What so called
systemic effects might the liquidation or reorganization have? Will
there be a significant negative effect on other financial firms or on
the macro economy in response to actions taken to resolve the troubled
firm? As noted in the introduction, policymakers are likely to have a
strong interest in any systemic effects when deciding on the appropriate
resolution method.
Preserving Complementarities and Going-Concern Value
Following a firm's default on a debt, creditors are likely to
rush to seize, and separately sell, assets that, if sold together with
other assets, could produce a higher sale price (assets that are
"complementary"). For example, one can imagine that with
numerous creditors vying for a manufacturer's assets, individual
components of an assembly line might be sold off separately, when, if
sold as a complete assembly line, these components would be of greater
value and produce a higher price. Therefore, this incentive can reduce
the total amount that creditors, as a group, receive and can also
undercut productivity and economic efficiency. Creditors who manage to
be the first to seize assets are likely to recover a higher proportion
of their debts than creditors who are slower to react. As a result,
creditors have a strong individual incentive to move quickly to
undertake such seizures. Preserving complementarities can be important
whether the firm is liquidated or is preserved via a reorganization
process.
If creditors are allowed to rush in and seize assets, they are also
likely to grab those assets that are fundamental to the firm's
continued operations, so called "going-concern assets." Such
assets might include, for example, necessary operating equipment for a
manufacturing firm, or buildings for a financial firm. For a firm that
is going to be closed and liquidated, protecting going-concern assets is
unimportant, but for firms that might be successful if reorganized,
creditors will be made better off, as a group, if their removal is
prevented. Indeed, if creditors are allowed to seize going-concern
assets, a troubled firm that might otherwise become quite productive in
reorganization could be doomed to fail by the asset seizures.
In bankruptcy, the automatic stay (discussed in detail below)
prevents immediate asset seizures, and creates a court-overseen process
for allocating assets in a way that preserves complementarities and
going-concern value. (1), (2) The OLA process also involves a stay, but
grants the FDIC this preservation role. Bailouts, by (typically)
preventing the troubled firm's default on debts, remove the ability
of creditors to seize the troubled firm's assets. (3)
Determining Whether to Liquidate or Reorganize
When a firm becomes unable to meets its debt payments, one of two
outcomes are possible. First, as already mentioned, the firm might be
closed and its assets liquidated. Alternatively, if the firm can be
returned to profitability by restructuring (typically reducing) its
debts, then, in many cases, it should be reorganized, allowing it to
continue operating after a debt restructuring process. If the firm is
unlikely to return to profitability, even with a lowered debt burden,
because the firm's assets are unlikely to produce a market rate of
return, then the firm should be liquidated: The firm should be shut down
and its assets sold to the highest bidders. In this case, liquidation
will distribute assets to firms that can make more productive use of
them, enhancing economic productivity and efficiency. Any resolution
regime is faced with a decision between liquidation and resolution, and,
ideally, will choose the one that produces the most economically
efficient outcome.
Addressing Systemic Risk (4) and Moral Hazard
When faced with the failure of a large financial firm, or one with
many connections with other financial firms, government decisionmakers
will not only wish to ensure that complementarities and any
going-concern value are preserved, and that the choice between
liquidation or reorganization is optimally made, but they will also care
greatly about systemic effects. Simply bailing out the troubled firm
will prevent its failure, preserve complementarities and going-concern
value, as well as avoid systemic effects. But any bailouts will create a
"moral hazard" problem: the view, among investors, that large
financial firms are likely to be protected, such that in the future,
creditors of such firms will reduce their risk-monitoring efforts and
these firms will be willing to undertake an inefficiently large amount
of risk-taking. Therefore, any method employed to resolve a large or
interconnected financial firm must balance systemic dangers against the
danger of excessive risk-taking. Bailouts prevent current systemic
problems but are likely to lead to less efficient resource allocation choices in the future. Relying on bankruptcy can avoid future moral
hazard because, as discussed later, bankruptcy provides no source of
funds for bailouts, but the bankruptcy of a large financial firm carries
the risk of heavy current systemic problems. As such, when Congress
crafted the OLA, addressing systemic risk was a priority, but so was
resolving firms in a manner that does not simultaneously increase moral
hazard. The OLA aims to address systemic risks that may otherwise be
present when resolving systemically important financial institutions
(SIFIs) through bankruptcy, in part, by 1) giving the FDIC broad
discretion in how it funds the resolution process and pays out
creditors, as well as by 2) changing the way derivatives and repurchase
agreements (repos)--known as qualified financial contracts
("QFCs")--are treated.
Overview of Bankruptcy and OLA
When comparing bankruptcy and OLA, understanding their overarching goals is important. The goal of a bankruptcy proceeding is to maximize
recoveries for creditors, through liquidation or the rehabilitation of
the debtor. The goal of the OLA, on the other hand, is to resolve
"failing financial companies that pose a significant risk to the
financial stability of the U.S. in a manner that mitigates such risk and
minimizes moral hazard."
Bankruptcy achieves its goals through a court-overseen process that
relies largely on the troubled firm's creditors and other investors
to decide how best, and most profitably, to resolve the firm's
troubles. Funding for a bankruptcy resolution typically comes only from
the assets of the troubled company and from any funds that might be
provided by private investors. See Table 1 for an outline of the
bankruptcy process.
OLA borrows several important ideas from bankruptcy, but moves
beyond bankruptcy because of policymakers' dissatisfaction with
possible outcomes under bankruptcy. The OLA attempts to capture the
firms whose resolution through bankruptcy could be detrimental to the
broader financial system. Therefore, the OLA can be differentiated from
bankruptcy based on several notable features that are designed
specifically with SIFT, or covered financial company (CFC), resolution
in mind. See Table 2 for a review of OLA's main features.
Table 2 OLA
Who Qualifies as a "Covered Financial Company" (CFC)?
A "financial company" whose failure would have serious
adverse effects on financial stability.
Process for Designating a Firm as a CFC
1. Recommendation by Federal Reserve and either FDIC, Securities
and Exchange Commission, or Federal Insurance Office, based on their
findings that the following is true for the financial company:
- It is in default or in danger of default
- A resolution under the Bankruptcy Code would produce serious
adverse consequences
- There is no viable private-sector alternative
2. Determination made by the Treasury Secretary in consultation
with the President
3. Appointment of FDIC as receiver of CFC
The FDIC's Powers and Duties
- They can 1) sell the CFC, or any portion of the assets or
liabilities to a third party; 2) establish a temporary bridge financial
company to preserve the company's value prior to being sold to a
third party; or 3) liquidate the company.
- Use their best efforts to maximize returns, minimize losses, and
mitigate the potential for serious adverse effects to the financial
system.
- Must ensure unsecured creditors bear losses and ensure the
directors and management team responsible for the company's
condition are removed.
- Has authority to make additional payments to certain creditors
(over what their priority would demand and possibly more than similarly
situated creditors) if determined to maximize value or limit losses
(excess may be "clawed back"), see below.
FDIC's Access to Funding
- Treasury: FDIC may immediately borrow funds from the Treasury (up
to 10 percent of the CFC's pre-resolution book-value assets within
first 30 days; 90 percent once fair-value is determined and liquidation
and repayment plan is in place and approved by Treasury)
- If funds from disposition of failed firm's assets are
insufficient to repay Treasury:
- Creditors (who were paid more than they would in bankruptcy)
would have to return excess funds ("claw backs")
- Large financial institutions can be assessed
Notes: "Financial Company" includes bank holding
companies, nonbank financial firms, and securities broker-dealers.
Nonbank financial firms are characterized as firms that are supervised
by the Fed (because of SIFI designation) or that derive at least 85
percent of their revenues from activities that are financial in nature.
During the 2007-2008 financial crisis, an unwillingness to trust
large firm failures to bankruptcy often resulted in government
assistance to firms popularly described as "too big to fail,"
such as Bear Stearns and AIG. Yet the grant of government assistance
sent strong signals to the market that other, similar firms would
receive assistance as well if they were to experience trouble, thereby
expanding credit subsidies for certain firms and moral hazard. For
example, bond prices for the largest financial institutions remained
relatively high during the crisis and prices for Lehman credit default
swaps (CDS) may not have accurately reflected default risk (Skeel 2010).
In contrast, allowing Lehman to fail can be seen as an attempt to
mitigate moral hazard; however, some argue this was done at the cost of
creating systemic risk. (5) These objectives are inextricably linked,
and focusing on the reduction of one has the likely result of increasing
the other. Therefore, the OLA, which charges the FDIC with administering
these provisions, was an attempt to address this conflict. How does the
FDIC meet this challenge?
When the FDIC is appointed as the receiver of a failing financial
firm designated as a CFC, it assumes complete financial and operational
control of the institution. The FDIC has the authority to manage, sell,
transfer, or merge all the assets of the failing firm, as well as
provide the funds needed for an orderly liquidation, giving it broad
discretion. (6) The FDIC's guiding principles in carrying out these
responsibilities include using its best efforts to maximize returns,
minimize losses, and, unique to this regime, mitigate the potential for
serious adverse effects to the financial system and minimize moral
hazard. (7) Moreover, the language of the OLA forces the FDIC to balance
two competing interests. On one hand, it is to pay creditors no more
than what they would receive in bankruptcy (8) and ensure that creditors
bear losses in order to promote market discipline. On the other hand, it
is to minimize adverse effects on financial stability. In bankruptcy,
creditors only inject additional funds when the firm seems viable. The
FDIC, on the other hand, may find it necessary to prop up a firm or
perhaps protect certain creditors, at least for a time, to prevent any
potential systemic consequences even though the firm may not be viable.
The Dodd-Frank Act granted the FDIC a line of credit from the Treasury
to fund these efforts. Because the FDIC has broad discretion over the
way in which it balances these competing objectives, market participants
may find it difficult to predict which objective might receive more
weight in any given failure.
2. KEY FEATURES OF BANKRUPTCY, ITS WEAKNESSES, AND OLA AS AN
ALTERNATIVE
In the United States, the failure of a business firm typically
results in that firm entering bankruptcy, and actions taken by the firm
shift from being determined by management to being guided by rules
established under federal law, specifically under the U.S. Bankruptcy
Code. What are the core features of bankruptcy? What features lead
observers to conclude that bankruptcy is not an appropriate way to
handle a SIFT whose failure could pose substantial risk to the financial
system? What are the alternative resolution arrangements created by
Dodd-Frank's OLA provisions?
Key Bankruptcy Feature: The Automatic Stay
The "automatic stay" is a primary component of bankruptcy
and one that underlies many of the complaints raised against bankruptcy
as a means of handling SIFT failures. The stay works as follows.
Immediately upon the filing of a bankruptcy petition with the clerk of
the bankruptcy court, creditors are enjoined from attempting to collect
on their claims. (9) This feature of bankruptcy allows a
goverrnnent-appointed trustee to ensure that assets of the bankrupt firm
are liquidated in a manner that maximizes the total pool of funds
available for creditor repayment. Without the stay, as discussed
earlier, creditors can be expected to rush in, grab, and then sell the
bankrupt firm's assets. In so doing, creditors could destroy asset
complementarities. The stay typically lasts for the length of the
bankruptcy process, though the courts may grant exceptions.
In a Chapter 7 bankruptcy (liquidation), (10) the type of corporate
bankruptcy in which the troubled firm is closed down (liquidated), the
court-appointed trustee typically must sell all of the assets of the
bankrupt firm before distributing funds to creditors. (11) The goal of
the trustee is to sell the assets in a manner that maximizes the sum of
payouts to creditors. Achieving this maximization goal can result in a
lengthy process, so that creditors' funds may be inaccessible for
an extended period. Based on a study of all corporate bankruptcies from
two federal bankruptcy court districts between 1995 and 2001, the
average liquidation lasts 709 days (Bris, Welch, and Zhu 2006; 1,270).
It seems likely that for the largest, most complex financial firms the
process will take at least as long as average or perhaps longer.
Compared to liquidation, a corporate Chapter 11 bankruptcy
(reorganization) process tends to last longer still, 828 days on average
according to Bris, Welch, and Zhu (2006), though in reorganization
creditors will often be repaid well before this process ends. In
reorganization, the troubled firm's debts are rescheduled or
cut--but it continues to operate. (12) A corporation that finds itself
unable to repay all creditors in full can seek protection from
creditors' claims by petitioning the bankruptcy court to enter
reorganization. This protection from creditors, which includes a stay of
claims, is important when a firm is being reorganized because the stay
prevents creditors from seizing "going-concern" assets (assets
that might be necessary to keep the firm running). The stay can mean
that, in aggregate, creditors receive more than they would if individual
creditors had been allowed to seize assets to protect themselves.
Because creditors must agree to the troubled firm's proposed
reorganization plan--if not, the firm is likely to proceed to a
liquidation--firms receiving reorganization treatment are those for
which creditors, as a group, believe going-concern value exceeds the
value of firm assets if such assets are sold, i.e., if the firm is
liquidated (White 1998, 2-3).
While reorganization can last longer than liquidation, payouts to
creditors will often be made well before the end of the reorganization
process. As part of the reorganization, creditors may agree to lower
repayments and some may receive these repayments quickly. Further,
additional funding can flow into the troubled firm fairly quickly to
help keep it afloat.
A source of funding often available to a firm in reorganization is
"debtor-in-possession" (DIP) funding. In reorganization, the
troubled corporation, the debtor, continues to operate, or
"possess," the troubled entity. Any loans to the troubled
corporation are therefore loans to the DIP. Such loans are often senior
to all former--prior to the bankruptcy filing--debts of the bankrupt
firm. The prospect of being senior to other creditors allows funding to
flow as long as creditors can be convinced that the firm is likely to
survive and therefore repay.
Key Bankruptcy Feature: Limited Sources of Funding
Repayment of a bankrupt firm's creditors and funds to sustain
a firm reorganized under bankruptcy can only derive from two sources:
the assets of the troubled firm, and, in the case of reorganization,
added (DIP) loans that might flow to the troubled firm. While bankruptcy
law and practice do not prohibit government aid to troubled firms, such
funding is not typically available. As a result, creditors have an
incentive to carefully evaluate the riskiness of any firm prior to
providing funding and to monitor its activities once funding has been
provided. Such monitoring will tend to ensure that the firm undertakes
only those risks with a positive expected return. Yet, the government
has often provided aid to troubled firms because of the sluggishness
with which creditors are often repaid following failure and because of
the apparent difficulty of lining up DIP funding. In some cases this aid
has been provided prior to bankruptcy, in others during bankruptcy. (13)
Therefore, the monitoring advantage offered by bankruptcy can be
diminished by the expectation of government aid for certain (especially
large) financial firms. (14)
There is no DLP financing in a liquidation. In liquidation, a
"bankruptcy estate" is created, including all of the assets of
the bankrupt firm. One of the responsibilities of the trustee is to
locate all assets and gather them into the estate. The estate assets are
sold by the bankruptcy trustee and the proceeds of the sale provide the
funds from which creditors are repaid. Funds from no source beyond the
assets of the failed firm are available to the trustee and therefore to
the creditors.
In a reorganization proceeding, debts are restructured in a manner
such that the firm can continue operating. For example, the creditors of
a firm might come together and all agree to reduce the amounts the
bankrupt firm owes each of them by 30 percent, and extend the maturity
of all debts by two years. As a result, the bankrupt firm faces lower
monthly debt payments, payments that it might successfully manage. The
creditors will only agree to such a plan if they believe that sustaining
the operations of the firm is likely to mean larger payments than if the
firm descends into liquidation. The debt restructuring and the mode of
future operation is called the "reorganization plan" and is
subject to court review and creditor appeal to the bankruptcy court.
Typically the current management of the troubled firm operates the
reorganized firm. If the firm's liabilities exceed its assets,
owners are wiped out and the creditors inherit the decisionmaking rights
formerly enjoyed by owners. The debtor can acquire funding for the
reorganized firm because it can offer very favorable terms to the
lenders who provide DIP funding because the new lenders have a claim
that is senior to all other creditors. Thus, lenders will have an
incentive to provide DIP funding if they believe that the reorganized
firm is likely to be able to repay their loans from future
earnings--that the reorganized firm will be profitable.
Weaknesses of Bankruptcy
A Weakness of Bankruptcy for Financial Firms: The Stay Threatens
Short-Term Debtholders
While the automatic stay, in liquidation or reorganization, may
cause no spread of losses when the creditors of the troubled firm are
typically long-term debtholders (who are not counting on quick receipt
of their funds), in the case of a failing financial firm, creditors are
likely to include a large contingent of those with very short-term
claims. Funds invested in financial firms (such as investment banks)
often have maturities of one or a few days. Creditors with such short
maturity claims are likely to be dependent on the immediate access to
their funds in order to pay their own creditors. If funds are tied up
for an extended period, as assets are gathered and sold in a liquidation
process or as a reorganization agreement is negotiated, the bankrupt
firm's creditors may find themselves unable to make payments to
their own creditors. As a result, the bankruptcy of one firm may result
in the failure of some of its creditors, especially if some of these
creditors are also financial firms with their own very short-term debts
to repay. Therefore, while the automatic stay may have significant value
in preventing creditors from separating complementary assets in
liquidation and preserving going-concern value in reorganization, the
stay, if it continues more than a very short time, may cause financial
distress to spread. The importance of short-term funding, which is often
present for nonbank financial firms, may make policymakers unwilling to
rely on bankruptcy when such firms become troubled.
A Weakness of Bankruptcy for Financial Firms: Opacity Reduces
Availability of DIP Financing
New funding, quickly available, will often be necessary in order
for a troubled firm to be successfully reorganized. After all, funds
from former sources may have dried up because of the losses these
creditors suffered on former loans to the troubled firm. But, financial
firms may find it to be relatively difficult, compared to nonfinancial
firms, to quickly obtain DIP funding. Such firms often have quite opaque
assets: assets that are difficult for outsiders, such as lenders, to
value. For example, assets of financial firms often include a heavy
concentration of loans to other firms. The value of such loans may
depend importantly on information that can be gathered only by
performing detailed analyses of the financial condition of the borrowing
firms. (15) As a result, DIP loans may be available only after lenders
spend a great deal of time reviewing the troubled firm's assets.
Further, DIP loans made to financial firms are likely to involve
unusually high interest rates to compensate for time spent in asset
review and for the potential risk of lending to a firm with highly
opaque assets. The opacity of financial firm assets contributes to the
desire to employ some method (i.e., bailouts or OLA) for their
resolution instead of bankruptcy. (16)
Key Features of OLA and OLA's Weaknesses
As in bankruptcy, when a troubled financial firm enters the OLA
process, creditors--with the exception of holders of QFCs, discussed
below--are stayed (prevented) from collecting their debts. The stay
lasts the duration of the period in which the financial firm is in the
OLA process. During the stay, the FDIC will typically establish a
receivership estate into which most assets and liabilities will be
placed. Assets placed in the receivership will be sold by the FDIC in
the manner that results in the largest returns to creditors--so that the
receivership may last, and creditors wait, an extended period while the
FDIC lines up buyers. In addition, some of the bankrupt firm's
assets and liabilities can be moved into a "bridge entity," a
separate company formed by the FDIC, which might be sold off as a whole
entity to a private buyer or might even be capitalized by some of the
creditors of the bankrupt firm, and continue as a going concern. (17)
One purpose of a bridge can be to preserve going-concern value of
portions of the troubled firm. (18)
The Dodd-Frank OLA process also abides by a priority schedule
similar to the one defined in bankruptcy law (see Table 1 for an
overview of bankruptcy priorities). But Dodd-Frank authorizes the FDIC
to violate the priority list established in OLA under certain
circumstances. Specifically, section 210(d)(4) of the Dodd-Frank Act
permits the FDIC to pay a creditor more than priority rules might
otherwise allow "if the Corporation determines that such payments
or credits are necessary or appropriate to minimize losses to the
Corporation as receiver from the orderly liquidation of the covered
financial company." According to the FDIC's discussion of its
proposed rules related to this section of the Dodd-Frank Act, such
additional payments may be made if they are necessary to "continue
key operations, services, and transactions that will maximize the value
of the firm's assets and avoid a disorderly collapse in the
marketplace." (19)
Table 1 Corporate Bankruptcy
Types of Bankruptcy
Chapter 7 Chapter 7 bankruptcy (liquidation), the troubled
firm is closed down, with the longer-run outcome
being the sale of all the company's assets
(liquidation) because creditors or management do
not believe it can be successfully reorganized.
Assets of the troubled firm are assembled by the
bankruptcy trustee and then sold in a manner that
maximizes the sum of the payouts to the creditors.
The trustee typically must sell all of the bankrupt
firm before distributing funds to creditors [11
U.S.C. 704(a) 1].
Chapter 11 Under Chapter 11 bankruptcy (reorganization), the
troubled firm's debts are reorganized: debt
maturities are lengthened, or interest rates or
principal amounts are reduced.
Creditors will only agree to a reorganization if
they believe that preserving the firm as a going
concern will produce larger payments than if the
firm is liquidated.
Corporate Bankruptcies are Overseen by Federal Courts
The operating arm of the bankruptcy courts is the
Justice Department's Trustee program, so that most
bankruptcies are largely handled by trustees.
Circumstances Under which a Firm Enters Bankruptcy
Voluntary When a firm's management petitions the court to
Bankruptcy place the firm in bankruptcy because it is unable
to pay all its creditors in full. A firm will file
for bankruptcy when unpaid creditors will otherwise
seize complimentary or going-concern assets.
Involuntary When a firm's creditors petition for bankruptcy.
Bankruptcy Creditors have incentive to seek a firm's
bankruptcy when they believe that other creditors
might seize complementary or going-concern assets
or that the firm might dissipate assets.
Automatic Stay Immediately, upon the filing of a bankruptcy
petition with the clerk of the bankruptcy court,
creditors' are prohibited ("stayed") from
attempting to collect on their claims.
The stay allows a government-appointed trustee to
ensure that assets of the bankrupt firm are
liquidated in a manner that maximizes the total pool
of funds available for creditor repayment. As a
result, the stay allows the trustee to produce a
better result for creditors in aggregate than if
creditors were simply acting in their own self
interest. The trustee can be thought of as solving a
joint action problem. Similarly, the stay is also
the means in bankruptcy by which creditors are
prevented from seizing going-concern assets.
Qualified financial contract (QFC) holders are
typically exempt from the automatic stay: They can
retrieve their collateral in the event of
bankruptcy.
Under bankruptcy law a number of financial
instruments are QFCs, including repurchase
agreements (repos), commodity contracts,
forward contracts, swap agreements, and
securities contracts.
Reasons for the QFCs exemption:
Observers worry that preventing QFC holders
from retrieving their collateral could create
systemic financial problems.
Some observers believe that QFCs are not
complementary with one another or with other
assets, and can be removed without undercutting the
troubled firm's going-concern value.
Priority Rules
In Liquidation Payouts coming from asset sales are divided among
creditors based upon the creditor's location in the
priority order, which is established in the
Bankruptcy Code.
Secured creditors are repaid from the assets
that secure their debts prior to payments to
unsecured creditors.
A secured creditor will be fully repaid if the
value of his security exceeds the amount he is
owed. If not, he joins unsecured creditors and
must depend on the sale of other assets for
repayment.
Unsecured claimants are paid based on the
following priority list (White 1998, 1):
First to be repaid are those owed any
administrative expenses produced by the
bankruptcy process.
Second, claims are given statutory priority,
such as taxes owed, rent, and unpaid wages
and benefits.
Third are unsecured creditors' claims, including
trade creditors' claims, long-term bondholders,
and holders of damage claims against the
bankrupt firm.
Last, equityholders receive any remaining funds.
In Payments to creditors and equityholders will often
Reorganization differ from those that would arise based simply on
priority rules, because reorganization payments
typically arise from negotiation between creditors
and equityholders (White 1998, 8).
Reorganization negotiations are driven by two
rules: 1) each class of creditors and
equityholders must consent to the bankruptcy plan
adopted in the negotiation, and 2) if the
negotiation produces no plan that is acceptable to
all classes, then the firm is liquidated and
payments are determined by the priority rules
listed above.
Because of the mutual consent requirement, some
classes can be expected to receive more than would
be expected if the priorities rules were strictly
followed. For example, if assets are insufficient
to repay all creditors, abiding by the priority
rule would mean equityholders could expect to
receive nothing.
But creditors are likely to allow equityholders to
receive payments in exchange for the investors'
agreement to a plan that allows reorganization
rather than liquidation, because the
reorganization preserves some going-concern value
for all classes. In other words, an equityholder
agreement isachieved by paying them more than they
would get if they held up the plan.
Debtor-in-Possesion (DIP) Loans
Loans made to a firm in reorganization,
post-bankruptcy filing.
Such loans are often senior to all pre-bankruptcy
debts.
Beyond the authority to, in some cases, make greater payments to
creditors than their priority might allow, the Dodd-Frank Act also
provides the FDIC with Treasury funding that might be used to make
payments to creditors. The Act provides that the FDIC can borrow, within
certain limits, from the Treasury. Immediately upon their appointment as
receiver of a firm, the FDIC can borrow 10 percent of the value of the
firm's pre-resolution assets. For a large financial firm, this
initial amount can be significant. In the Lehman failure, for example,
10 percent of assets would have amounted to $63.9 billion. Once the fair
value of the failing firm's assets is determined and a liquidation
and repayment plan is in place, the FDIC may borrow an additional 90
percent of the value of the firm's assets (with approval from the
Treasury). The Act provides that these funds are to be repaid to the
Treasury from the sale of the liquidated firm's assets. But,
importantly, the Act also specifies a means of repayment if such assets
are not sufficient for repayment, first by attempting to "claw
back" any "additional payments" (payments beyond what
would have been received in a liquidation) made to creditors, and, if
that is insufficient, by taxing all large bank holding companies and
other SIFIs (Dodd-Frank Act [section] 210(o)(i)(A)). (20), (21), (22)
The fact that assets might not be sufficient to repay the Treasury in
full, and that the legislation authorizes taxes (on large financial
firms) to repay the Treasury, implies that creditors may be repaid more
than the sum of funds generated by asset sales--more than they would
have been repaid in liquidation.
It seems likely that Congress intended to provide the FDIC with a
good bit of discretion to bypass strict priority as well as discretion
over whether to borrow Treasury funds in order to mitigate systemic
risk. For example, given the FDIC's ability to pay some creditors
more than they would receive in bankruptcy, these creditors may be less
likely to pass on losses to other firms, lowering the risk of a systemic
problem.
One might argue that legislators' intention for providing the
FDIC with the authority to borrow from the Treasury was simply to allow
the FDIC the ability to move quicker than bankruptcy courts. By
providing an immediate source of funds, the FDIC could gather funds,
which it could then use to make payments equivalent to what would be
paid in bankruptcy. In this way creditors would not be denied access to
their funds for months or years (as in liquidation), and the FDIC could
slowly sell the assets of the failing firm such that fire sales are
avoided. Under such an arrangement, legislators could have required the
FDIC to immediately estimate the value of the failing firm's assets
(similar to the type of analysis currently performed by the FDIC when it
determines--and announces in a press release--the cost to the FDIC of a
bank's failure), and then limit itself to paying creditors no more
than their pro-rata share (given priorities) of this estimated amount.
Yet, Congress did not choose this course, i.e., it did not require the
FDIC to limit the sum of its payments to be no more than the estimated
value of the failing firm's assets. Instead it left the FDIC to
determine payments to creditors and authorized taxes on large financial
firms if payments exceed the liquidation value of assets. Therefore, it
seems clear that Congress intended for some creditors of a failing firm
to receive larger payments than bankruptcy allowed, as a means of
mitigating systemic risk.
Investors certainly realize that the OLA provisions provide the
FDIC with the authority to make larger-than-bankruptcy payments to
creditors. As a result, they will tend to under price risk-taking by
nonbank firms that might get OLA treatment and such firms will engage in
more risk-taking than if they did not enjoy the potential benefits of
receiving government aid. (23) Congress was aware that larger payments
would have this moral-hazard-exacerbating impact on firm risk-taking and
took steps to mitigate the impact in the OLA provisions of the
Dodd-Frank Act. Broadly, the legislation requires that the FDIC attempt
to liquidate SDFIs "in a manner that ... minimizes moral
hazard." (24) More specifically, the law calls on the FDIC to
ensure that any member of the management or the board of directors of
the failed firm who is deemed responsible for the failure is fired.
Similarly, the OLA provisions require the FDIC to "ensure that the
shareholders of a covered financial company do not receive payment until
after all other claims and the Fund are fully paid and ensure that
unsecured creditors bear losses ..." (25), (26) The provisions
requiring the removal of management and directors are likely to
encourage these corporate leaders to limit risk-taking. However, the OLA
contains provisions for certain creditors to receive better treatment
than they might in bankruptcy, even if some creditors suffer losses, so
that creditor oversight is likely diminished by the prospect of OLA
treatment.
Dealing With Systemic Risk in Failure Resolution: Exceptions to the
Automatic Stay
The class of financial contracts, which are exempt from the
automatic stay, are commonly referred to as "qualified financial
contracts" (QFCs). (27) Therefore, investors who are holding QFCs
have the ability to immediately terminate and net-out their contracts or
liquidate the collateral on their claims once a party has defaulted or
filed for bankruptcy. Today, under bankruptcy law, a number of financial
instruments are QFCs, including repos, commodity contracts, forward
contracts, swap agreements, and securities contracts. (28) The treatment
of QFCs in bankruptcy (and under OLA provisions) has been the focus of a
great deal of public debate.
A possible explanation for exempting QFCs is that the collateral
that typically backs QFCs is not directly tied to the defaulting
firm's going concern value. A primary objective of the automatic
stay in bankruptcy is to prevent the separation of complementary assets
(an important goal of the trustee in liquidation) or to preserve the
going-concern value of a firm (typically a goal in reorganization). QFCs
can be immediately closed out because the collateral backing them will
typically not be complementary to other assets of the firm, nor will QFC collateral be important to the firm's going-concern value. For
instance, collateral consisting of highly marketable or cash-like
securities (for example Treasury bills or mortgage-backed securities)
can be removed from the firm without necessarily undercutting the
firm's ability to produce loans or other financial products, since
the production of these products depends on such resources as the skill
of lending staff, staff contacts with possible borrowers, IT assets,
office space and equipment, and funding (liabilities) from which to make
loans. However, some argue that the collateral backing certain QFCs can
be firm-specific (e.g., a pool of mortgage cash flows used as repo collateral) and therefore not all QFCs should be treated equally
(Jackson 2011).
Another possible explanation for exempting QFCs is that the markets
in which QFCs trade are special, such that delaying creditor recovery
attempts in these markets (by imposing a stay on QFC counterparties) is
especially destructive, compared to staying creditors operating in other
markets. More specifically, proponents who hold this view seem to be
arguing that staying QFCs is more likely to create systemic problems
than staying the collection of other debts. This explanation for special
treatment--what we will call the "systemic risk"
rationale--appears to stand out as the argument used by policymakers
supporting the expansion of the list of QFCs that took place over
several decades through numerous reforms to the Bankruptcy Code. The
rationale offered by those supporting the exemption is that in a
fast-paced, highly interconnected market, a counterparty to a QFC may
need the proceeds from the contract to pay off other debts in a timely
manner. If this counterparty is unable to meet other obligations as a
result of having its contracts held up in bankruptcy, other firms
relying on that counterparty may become exposed and experience financial
distress, which could bleed to other counterparties, and so on, causing
a ripple effect and possibly "destabilizing" markets (Edwards
and Morrison 2005). (29)
Today, the transactions and agreements covered under the definition
of a QFC include a wide range of instruments. However, when the
automatic stay was first created as part of the new Bankruptcy Code in
1978, (30) only commodities and futures contracts were exempt. (31) At
the time, these protections were intended to "prevent the
insolvency of one commodity firm from spreading to other brokers or
clearing agencies and possibly threatening the collapse of the
market." (32) In the decades to follow, various reforms to the
Bankruptcy Code expanded the types of contracts classified as QFCs, as
well as expanding the types of collateral that could be used to back
them (see Figure 1 timeline).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Legislation enacted in 2005 and 2006 (33) expanded the safe harbor treatment significantly by broadening the definition of a QFC to such an
extent that it would capture any newly created derivatives product that
may otherwise not be explicitly included. (34) Moreover, the most recent
reforms also expanded contractual netting rights to allow for
"cross-product netting" of QFCs (Figure 1). Netting occurs
when a non-defaulting counterparty of a defaulting bankrupt firm is
allowed to offset debts it owes to the defaulting firm against debts
owed it by the defaulting firm. (35) Cross-product netting allows
contracts of differing types to be netted against one another, for
example a debt owed on a swap to be netted against a debt owed on an
option contract. Netting, whether the netting of like product contracts
or cross-product contracts, can reduce the credit exposure of firms that
use financial contracts. In turn, the chance that the bankruptcy of one
firm might lead to large losses for its financial contract
counterparties is reduced, which some observers argue could reduce
systemic risk (Jones 1999). (36)
Observers explain that the expansion of special treatment for QFCs
occurred in order to account for the considerable growth in the number
and diversity of complex financial products over the previous decade
(Jones 1999, Skadden 2010). These instruments grew in popularity as they
served as mechanisms for financial firms to insure and hedge against
risk, helping to reduce uncertainty and stabilize earnings. This
increasingly expansive protection for derivatives and repos was intended
to achieve the goal of "minimizing the systemic risks potentially
arising from certain interrelated financial activities and
markets." (37), (38)
Some Possible Weaknesses of Bankruptcy's QFC Exemption
The onset of the financial crisis led many observers to reexamine whether this systemic risk rationale was consistent with the events that
occurred when financial markets became severely stressed during the
recent financial crisis. Therefore, the idea that QFCs should be exempt
from the stay was revisited in the lead up to Dodd-Frank and ultimately
addressed in the OLA. The systemic risk argument is the prominent
justification given by those supporting the expansion of the special
treatment given to QFCs. However, there is another cohort, which argues
that any reduction in systemic risk, because of QFC exemptions, may be
offset by another form of systemic risk involving runs on repos (39) and
fire sales (40) of the collateral underlying closed-out derivatives
contracts (Edwards and Morrison 2005, Taylor 2010, Acharya et al. 2011).
The simultaneous termination and liquidation of numerous QFCs (which is
allowed by the exemption of QFCs from the stay) may lead to fire sales
and possibly further insolvencies. In Lehman's case, of their
930,000 derivatives counterparties, 733,000 sought to terminate their
contracts upon their bankruptcy filing. on September 15, 2008 (Miller
2009).
Additionally, some observers note that the 2005 bankruptcy laws,
which, among other things, extended QFC protections to repos backed by
all types of collateral, including all mortgage-related securities, may
have encouraged use of mortgage-backed securities as repo collateral
(Lubben 2010), and thereby contributed to losses during the financial
crisis (Skeel 2010, Government Accountability Office 2011). As Skeel
(2010) points out, mortgage values could have spiraled down even more
had AIG's counterparties been forced to sell a significant amount
of the mortgage-related securities they had posted as collateral on
their QFCs (which was avoided when AIG was bailed out).
The idea that QFC fire sales might result from their exemption is
not new. In fact, it appears to be what led the Federal Reserve to step
in and encourage private firms to come to the aid of Long-Term Capital
Management L.P. (LTCM), preventing it from entering bankruptcy (Edwards
and Morrison 2005). (41)
As discussed, the bankruptcy process can be long, but among other
things, this is intended to give the troubled financial firm and its
creditors the time to develop plans to salvage the value of the firm.
However, with the exemption from the stay, a large financial firm facing
possible default (because of a number of factors, such as a recent
credit downgrading or an overall crisis of confidence) has a strong
incentive not to file for bankruptcy since doing so would likely trigger
simultaneous termination of all QFCs (Skeel and Jackson 2012). Thus, a
troubled firm may put it off until the last moment and be forced into a
rapid liquidation that significantly depresses values to the detriment of other market participants. These arguments suggest that
bankruptcy's current treatment of QFCs may not be optimal.
Observers also find that the special treatment given to QFCs--in
order to prevent the perceived systemic risks that arise when these
instruments are subjected to the automatic stay--not only create a
different form of systemic risk, but weaken market discipline (Edwards
and Morrison 2005, Scott 2011). The special treatment awarded to QFC
counterparties in bankruptcy essentially places them ahead of all other
creditors in the bankruptcy repayment line, allowing QFC counterparties
to get out of their contracts when all other creditors cannot. As a
result, their incentive to monitor the debtor prior to bankruptcy and
base their pricing and investment decisions on the perceived risk of the
counterparty may be significantly reduced, increasing moral hazard
(Edwards and Morrison 2005, Roe 2011). It is argued that this leads to
market distortions whereby debtors favor short-term repo financing over
traditional sources of funding, encouraging a more fragile liability
structure (Edwards and Morrison 2005, Skeel and Jackson 2012). For
example, at the time of Bear Stearns' failure, a quarter of its
assets (approximately $100 billion) were funded by repos (Roe 2011). Roe
(2011) suggests that, without the priority given to these instruments in
bankruptcy, it is plausible that Bear would have financed a much larger
proportion of its assets with longer-term debt, which would have allowed
for a more stable funding structure during the financial turmoil.
Some observers who support these arguments maintain that QFCs
should be subject to the automatic stay provisions in the Bankruptcy
Code, although there are a range of views concerning the length of the
stay and whether all QFCs should be treated equally. According to Harvey
Miller (2009), lead bankruptcy attorney for the Lehman bankruptcy, the
automatic stay, as originally contemplated, is intended to provide a
firm with the "breathing space" to find a third party source
of liquidity or to carry out an "orderly, supervised wind down of
its business assets." Miller argues that, had the special treatment
given to QFCs not applied, Lehman's failure may have been avoided
and certainly would not have been as "systemically
challenging." For instance, Lehman suffered a significant loss of
value when nearly 80 percent of their derivatives counterparties
terminated their contracts upon their filing of bankruptcy (Miller
2009).
The OLA's One-Day Automatic Stay for QFCs
Given the controversy--with some experts arguing the exemption from
the stay is necessary to prevent systemic risk and others arguing that
the exemption creates systemic risk--it is natural that Congress chose a
solution that leaves the FDIC with discretion to determine the treatment
of QFCs for covered financial companies. Under Congress's solution,
QFCs are subject to a one-day automatic stay upon appointment of the
FDIC as receiver, whereas QFCs are subject to no stay in bankruptcy.
(42)
During the one-day stay under the OLA, the FDIC, as receiver of the
failing financial company, must quickly identify how to manage the
SIFI's QFC portfolio. The one-day stay is aimed at addressing fears
associated with a failing firm's QFC counterparties cancelling
their contracts all at once and driving asset prices down. Instead,
counterparties' rights to cancel their contracts are put on hold
for one day while the FDIC determines how to treat these contracts. The
FDIC has this same type of authority when dealing with bank failures.
Under the OLA, during this short period, the FDIC has the option to
retain the QFCs in receivership, transfer QFCs to another financial
institution (to an outside acquirer or to abridge company created by the
FDIC), or reject the QFCs. (43) However, in all instances, the FDIC must
retain, reject, (44) or transfer all of the QFCs with a particular
counterparty and its affiliates. (45), (46)
Each action taken by the FDIC has different implications for QFC
counterparties of the debtor, as well as the failing firm. Retaining the
QFCs in receivership is most similar to bankruptcy in that after the
one-day stay expires, QFC counterparties may terminate or net-out their
contracts. (47) What differs significantly from bankruptcy, but is very
similar to the FDIC's resolution process for depository institutions, is the FDIC's ability to transfer or reject QFCs. If
the FDIC chooses to transfer all of the QFCs with a particular
counterparty and its affiliates to a third party (including a bridge
company), the counterparty is not permitted to exercise its rights to
terminate or close out the contract. (48) This awards the FDIC an
opportunity to possibly preserve the value of the contracts by removing
the ability of counterparties to terminate contracts early and sell off
the collateral at fire sale prices (Cohen 2011). Moreover, a QFC
counterparty may find that their contracts are held with a new, and
presumably more stable, counterparty or a temporary bridge bank
following the one-day stay and, therefore, may have no incentive to
terminate (in addition to the fact that it has no ability to terminate),
leaving the market undisrupted by their original counterparty's
failure while also maintaining what are possibly valuable hedge
transactions. Finally, the FDIC may reject (or repudiate) the QFCs of a
given counterparty to the debtor, effectively closing them out at the
current market value, if they determine that they are somehow burdensome
or doing so would otherwise promote orderly administration. (49)
However, counterparties may recover, from the FDIC, any damages suffered
as a result of the FDIC's rejection of QFCs. (50)
Possible Weaknesses of OLA's One-Day Stay
Some commentators find that the one-business-day stay does not
provide the FDIC with sufficient time to identify the potential
recipients of the failed firm's derivatives portfolio (Skeel 2010,
Bliss and Kaufman 2011, Summe 2011). Given this time constraint coupled
with the "all or nothing" approach to the treatment of QFCs
(where the FDIC must retain, reject, or transfer all QFCs with a
particular counterparty) and the potential systemic risks from its
failure to protect a SIFI's QFCs, some suggest that the FDIC is
highly likely to transfer all QFC contracts of a given counterparty to a
bridge financial institution (i.e., protecting or guaranteeing them in
full) (Skeel 2010). After all, if the FDIC does not protect all
contracts, then the non-defaulting counterparties may close out and
liquidate their contracts upon the expiration of the one-day stay,
effectively resulting in the systemic problems previously discussed
related to the QFC exemption--closing out the contracts and selling
collateral at fire sale prices. Thus, even if various QFC counterparties
have differing risk exposures to the defaulting firm, they are all
likely to be treated the same and "bailed out." If
counterparties believe that their QFCs are likely to be protected by
placement in a well-funded bridge company, they are likely to provide
more funding (or provide lower-cost funding) to a risky firm than they
otherwise would. Further, counterparties may care little about the
differing risks associated with the various types of QFCs, because all
QFCs of a given counterparty are treated the same. Therefore, while
bridge company placement of QFCs may limit systemic risk, it is likely
to do so at the cost of increasing moral hazard.
In response to the concern that a one-day stay is likely to lead to
the protection of most QFCs, some observers, such as Thomas Jackson,
author of a proposal to create a new chapter in the Bankruptcy Code
tailored to the resolution of SIFIs (Chapter 14), proposes an extension
of the duration of the automatic stay for QFCs to three days. Jackson
and others argue that a longer stay duration will give the FDIC
additional time to make an informed decision regarding how to handle the
failing firm's QFC portfolio (Jackson 2011). Jackson's
three-day stay appears to be an attempt to balance the desire to give
the FDIC more time, against the danger of producing QFC counterparty
failures. (51)
Moreover, the protections for derivatives contracts have broadened
over the last several decades and this legislation does not account for
the differences across QFC products (such as between repos and swaps),
or the types of collateral backing QFCs, which some observers believe
should be considered. For instance, several observers find that special
treatment (i.e., exemption from the stay) should be limited to
derivatives collateralized by highly liquid collateral, such as
short-term Treasury securities, since there is little reason to assume
that such instruments are important for the going-concern value of the
bankrupt firm (Herring 2011, Jackson 2011). In Jackson's 2011
Chapter 14 proposal, highly liquid, or otherwise highly marketable,
instruments with no firm-specific value remain exempt from the stay so
that creditors who rely on the immediate availability of their funds can
get them back quickly and without disruption upon the failure of a firm.
On the other hand, the exemption is removed (i.e., the stay would apply)
for less liquid instruments, such as CDS, in an effort to prevent these
creditors from running on the troubled firm. Clearly, there remains a
good bit of controversy about the best way to handle the QFC exemption,
in both bankruptcy and the OLA, with no obvious best solution.
3. CONCLUSION
While bankruptcy probably provides the ideal failure resolution
mechanism for most corporations, it may not be optimal for some
financial firms (i.e., SIFIs). Financial firms are typically more
heavily dependent on short-term funding, often including a heavy
reliance on QFCs, and their balance sheets are opaque. Because of this
dependence on short-term funding, a long stay, while the bankruptcy
process plays out, is likely to result in financial difficulties for
some of the troubled firm's counterparties. Moreover, DIP funding,
which is the usual means of keeping a troubled, but viable, firm alive
during reorganization, is likely to be quite difficult to arrange, given
the opacity of most financial firms. Because of these weaknesses,
handling a SIFI through bankruptcy is likely to result in significant
risks to financial stability. Policymakers are therefore understandably
reluctant to allow SIFIs to enter bankruptcy, given that these risks can
be mitigated through bailouts. But bailouts, or the expectation that
they could be forthcoming, drive down economic efficiency by
exacerbating moral hazard problems.
In an effort to address these difficulties, the OLA was created
with the explicit goals of mitigating risk to the financial system and
minimizing moral hazard. Specifically, the OLA adjusts the way that QFCs
are handled and how creditors are paid out. Despite the attempt to
achieve these well-founded goals, because they are conflicting, reducing
one inevitably leads to an increase in the other. The one-day QFC
exemption does not clearly resolve potential risks to financial
stability and it also does not go far to ameliorate the moral hazard
problem that is apparent when giving QFCs special treatment.
Additionally, the ability to pay some creditors more than they would be
likely to receive in bankruptcy may reduce systemic risk, but at the
cost of increasing moral hazard. In conclusion, the threat of a
SIFI's failure, or the failure itself, presents policymakers with a
daunting challenge that neither bankruptcy nor the OLA seems capable of
fully resolving.
REFERENCES
Acharya, Viral V., Barry Adler, Matthew Richardson, and Nouriel
Roubini. 2011. "Resolution Authority." In Regulating Wall
Street: The Dodd-Frank Act and the New Architecture of Global Finance,
edited by Viral V. Acharya, Thomas F. Cooley, Matthew Richardson, and
Ingo Walter. Hoboken, N. J.: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 213-40.
Acharya, Viral, Thomas Cooley, Matthew Richardson, and Ingo Walter.
2009. "Chapter 6, Taxing Too-Big-to-Fail Institutions: The Current
Proposals." In Real-Time Recommendations for Financial Reform. New
York University: The NYU Stem Working Group on Financial Reform
(December).
Bernanke, Ben S. 2009. Testimony of Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman of
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, to the U.S. House
of Representatives Committee on Financial Services, October 1. Available
at www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20091001a.htm.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2010. Remarks on "The Squam Lake Report:
Fixing the Financial System" at the Squam Lake Conference, New
York, June 16. Available at
www.federalreserve.govinewsevents/speech/bernanke20100616a.htm.
Bliss, Robert R., and George G. Kaufman. 2011. "Resolving
Large Complex Financial Institutions: The Case for Reorganization."
Available at www.richmondfed.org/conferences_and_events/research/2011/pdf/bankruptcy_workshop_2011_bliss_paper.pdf.
Bliss, Robert R., and George G. Kaufman. 2006. "Derivatives
and Systemic Risk: Netting, Collateral, and Closeout." Journal of
Financial Stability 2 (April): 55-70.
Boul, Harry. 2006. "Repeat Filings under BAPCPA: Stays,
Multiple Discharges and Chapter 20." ABI Committee News Volume 4,
Number 6 (December). Available at
www.abiworld.org/committees/newsletters/consumer/vol4num6/RepeatFilings.html.
Bris, Arturo, Ivo Welch, and Ning Zhu. 2006. "The Costs of
Bankruptcy: Chapter 7 liquidation versus Chapter 11
Reorganization." The Journal of Finance 61 (June): 1,253-303.
Cohen, Hollace T. 2011. "Orderly Liquidation Authority: A New
Insolvency Regime to Address Systemic Risk." University of Richmond
Law Review 45 (May): 1,143-229.
Duffle, Darrell. 2011. How Big Banks Fail, and What to Do About It.
Princeton, N. J.: Princeton University Press.
Edwards, Franklin R., and Edward R. Morrison. 2005.
"Derivatives and the Bankruptcy Code: Why the Special
Treatment?" Yale Journal on Regulation 22 (January): 101-33.
Government Accountability Office. 2011. "Bankruptcy: Complex
Financial Institutions and International Coordination Pose
Challenges." U.S. Government Accountability Office, Report to
Congressional Committees, GA0-11-707 (July). Available at
www.gao.gov/assets/330/321213.pdf.
Gruenberg, Martin J. 2012. Remarks to the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago Bank Structure Conference, Chicago, May 10. Available at
www.fdic.govinews/news/speeches/chairman/spmay1012.html.
Herring, Richard J. 2011. The Meeting of the Systemic Resolution
Advisory Committee of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,
Washington, D.C., June 21. Available at
www.fdic.gov/about/srac/11JuneMeetingMins.PDF.
Jackson, Thomas. 2011. "Bankruptcy Code Chapter 14: A
Proposal." Hoover Institution Resolution Task Force, February 2012.
Available at http://media.hoover.org/sites/default/files/documents/Bankruptcy-Code-Chapter-14-Proposal-20120228.pdf.
Jessup, Clifton R., Jr. 1995. "Should the Automatic Stay Be
Abolished?" The ABI National Symposia Series, ABI Bankruptcy Reform
Study Project. Alexandria, Va.: American Bankruptcy Institute (June).
Available at www.abiworld.org/abidata/online/symposium/stay.html.
Jones, Douglas H. 1999. "Statement of Douglas H. Jones, Senior
Deputy General Counsel, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, on
Bankruptcy Reform Legislation, Committee on Banking, United States
Senate, March 25,1999." Available at
www.fdic.govinews/news/speeches/archives/1999/sp25mar99b.html.
Krimminger, Michael. 1999. "Insolvency in the Financial
Markets: Banks, Hedge Funds and Other Complications." Banking
Policy Report, January 18.
Lubben, Stephen J. 2010. "The Bankruptcy Code Without Safe
Harbors." American Bankruptcy Law Journal 84: 123-38.
Mengle, David. 2010. "The Importance of Close-Out
Netting." ISDA Research Notes Number 1.
Miller, Harvey R. 2009. "Too Big to Fail: The Role for
Bankruptcy and Antitrust Law in Financial Regulation Reform."
Testimony before the Subcommittee on Commercial and Administrative Law,
House of Representatives, Committee on the Judiciary, October 22.
Morgan, Donald P. 2002. "Rating Banks: Risk and Uncertainty in
an Opaque Industry." American Economic Review 92 (September):
874-88.
Roe, Mark J. 2011. "The Derivatives Market's Payment
Priorities as Financial Crisis Accelerator." Stanford Law Review 63
(March): 539-90.
Scott, Kenneth. 2011. "A Guide to the Resolution of Failed
Financial Institutions: Dodd-Frank Title H and Proposed Chapter
14." Stanford Law School. Available at
http://media.hoover.org/sites/default/files/documents/ken-scott-guide-to-resolution-project.pdf (May).
Skadden. 2010. "The Dodd-Frank Act: Commentary and
Insights." Available at
www.skadden.com/sites/default/files/publications/Skaddeninsights_Special_Edition_Dodd-Frank..Actl_6.pdf.
Skeel, David A. 2010. "Bailouts, Bankruptcy or Better?
Resolution Authority II." In The New Financial Deal: Understanding
the Dodd-Frank Act and its (Unintended) Consequences. Hoboken, N. J.:
John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 129-52.
Skeel, David A., and Thomas Jackson. 2012. "Transaction
Consistency and the New Finance in Bankruptcy." Columbia Law Review 112 (February).
Summe, Kimberly. 2011. "An Examination of Lehman
Brothers' Derivatives Portfolio Post-Bankruptcy and Whether
Dodd-Frank Would Have Made Any Difference." Available at
http://media.hoover.org/sites/default/files/documents/Kimberly-Summe-Dodd-Frank-20110421.pdf.
Taylor, John B. 2010. "Defining Systemic Risk
Operationally." In Ending Government Bailouts as We Know Them,
edited by George Shultz, Kenneth Scott, and John B. Taylor. Stanford
University: Hoover Institution Press, 33-57.
White, Michelle J. 1998. "Corporate Bankruptcy." In The
New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, edited by Peter
Newman. Macmillan Press. Available at http://weber.ucsd.edurmiwhite/.
Yim, Soo J., and William J. Perlstein. 2001. "The Effect of
Proposed Amendments to U.S. Insolvency and Banking Laws on Transactions
Involving Securities, Commodities and Other Financial Contracts."
Presentation prepared in connection with the American Bar Association
2001 Spring Meeting Section of Business Law Business Bankruptcy
Committee Forum on Derivatives And Proposed Financial Contract Netting
Legislation, March 24.
(1.) According to Boul (2006): "Traditionally, the automatic
stay has served to 'prevent dismemberment of the (bankruptcy]
estate and insure its orderly distribution.' SEC v. First Financial
Group, 645 F.2d 429, 439 (5th Cir.1981), citing S. Rep. No. 95-989, 95th
Cong., 2d Sess. 50 (1978); H.R.Rep. No. 95-595, 95th Cong., 2d Sess. 341
(1977), U.S.Code Cong. & Admin. News 1978, pp. 5787, 5836, 5963,
6297, 6298. In that capacity, the automatic stay serves the interests of
both the debtor and the creditors of the bankruptcy estate. For the
debtor, it provides a 'breathing spell' by 'stopping all
collection efforts, all harassment, and all foreclosure actions.'
S. Rep. No 95-989, 95th Cong., 2d Sess. 54-55 (1978); H.R. Rep. No
95-595, 95th Cong., 1st Sess. 340 (1977), U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.
News 1978, pp. 5787, 5840, 5841, 5963, 6296, 6297. However, the stay
also serves the interest of creditors, insofar as it 'eliminate[s]
the impetus for a race of diligence by fast-acting creditors.' SEC
v. First Financial Group, at 439. The stay ensures that assets are
distributed according to the order of priorities established by
Congress. Id, at 341."
(2.) Note that if the troubled firm had only one creditor, there
would be no need for bankruptcy since that one creditor would always
take actions that maximize complementarities and going-concern value.
Only in the case where there are many creditors, who, because of their
large number, cannot easily coordinate with one another, is bankruptcy
necessary.
(3.) One might imagine that an ideal solution--when a firm has
suffered losses such that its capital level is low and default seems
likely, but it could be profitable with a lower debt load--one that
requires no intervention by bankruptcy courts or government agencies, is
for the firm to gather new funding by issuing new equity shares. The new
funding could be used to purchase new, profitable assets that will
increase revenues available to service debt (lowering the ratio of debt
to assets) and reduce significantly the chance of default. This course
may be impossible, however, because of the so-called "debt overhang problem" and, as a result, bankruptcy and the reorganization of
debt may be the only course available. Because of the overhang problem,
existing equityholders will not vote in favor of a new equity issuance.
They will not do so, at least in many cases, because most or all of the
benefit flows to the debtholders by improving the market value of their
debt, and the existing equityholders will suffer dilution because future
earnings must be shared with the new equityholders (Duffle 2011, 43-4).
The likelihood that new issues of equity might offer a solution is
further reduced by an "adverse selection problem." Weak firms
issuing new equity, and especially those firms whose assets are opaque,
i.e., financial firms, will have to offer to sell shares at a very low
price, because equity investors are likely to conclude, based on the
fact that the firm wishes to issue new shares, that the firm is in
exceptionally poor health (even worse health than it really is). As a
result, existing shareholders will suffer a great deal of dilution and
vote against new issues.
(4.) There is no clear consensus about the definition of
"systemic risk" (See Taylor 2010). For purposes of this
article, we will define systemic risk as "the risk that the failure
of one large institution would cause other institutions to fail or that
a market event could broadly affect the financial system rather than
just one or a few institutions" (Government Accountability Office
2011).
(5.) The apparent worsening of the 2008 financial crisis following
Lehman's entrance into bankruptcy provides, for many observers, an
illustrative example of the deleterious effect of resolution by
bankruptcy for large financial firms. Yet there is some debate about the
conclusions one should draw from the Lehman experience. Some observers
maintain that the cascading losses following Lehman's bankruptcy
filing were not a result of troubles or anticipated troubles related to
the bankruptcy process itself, but were instead the result of a shock to
market expectations and therefore to the risk assessments of those who
had previously anticipated that Lehman, and firms like Lehman, would
certainly be bailed out (see Testimony from Skeel before the
Subcommittee on Commercial and Administrative Law, Committee on the
Judiciary, U.S. House of Reps., October 22, 2009). Available at
http://judiciary.house.gov/hearings/pdf/Skee1091022.pdf.
(6.) The OLA gives the FDIC authority to operate the company
"with all of the powers of the company's shareholders,
directors and officers, and may conduct all aspects of the
company's business." Dodd-Frank Act [section] 210(a)(1)(B).
(7.) Dodd-Frank Act [section] 204(a) and [section] 210(a)(9)(E).
(8.) Dodd-Frank Act [section] 210(d)(2). Under [section]
210(d)(4)(A) additional payments (in excess of what would be received in
bankruptcy) are authorized only with approval of the Treasury Secretary
and only if determined to be necessary or appropriate to minimize losses
to the receiver.
(9.) 11 U.S.C. [section] 362
(10.) In the remainder of the article, for the sake of simplicity,
we will typically replace the phrase Chapter 7 bankruptcy with
"liquidation" and the phrase Chapter 11 bankruptcy with
"reorganization." We will use the phrase "orderly
liquidation" or the acronym OLA when referring to a Dodd-Frank
Orderly Liquidation Authority process.
(11.) 11 U.S.C. 704(a)1
(12.) The airline industry provides many well-known examples of
reorganization, in which planes continue to fly and contracts are
renegotiated with creditors and employees.
(13.) Bear Stearns and AIG provide examples of financial firms that
received government aid prior to bankruptcy. In 2009, both General
Motors and Chrysler received aid from the federal government during
their reorganizations. Earlier cases of government aid include Penn
Central Railroad in 1970, Lockheed Aircraft in 1971, and Chrysler in
1980.
(14.) One might argue that there could be times in which government
aid is appropriate, for example if credit standards have become
inefficiently (or irrationally) strict, as in a financial panic. If
market participants believe that government aid will only be forthcoming
at such times, and will only provide the amount of funding that private
lenders would provide if they had not become irrationally strict, then
the expectation of government aid will not diminish private
investors' risk-monitoring efforts.
(15.) Using statistical analysis to measure firm opacity, by
comparing the frequency of bond rating disagreements, Morgan (2002, 876)
finds that banks and insurance firms are the most opaque of major
industry groups. Large nonbank SIFIs are likely to have a portfolio of
assets that are fairly similar to bank asset portfolios so can be
expected to be similarly opaque. Interestingly, Morgan notes that the
industry grouping "Other Finance and Real Estate" seems to be
among the least opaque, though, according to Morgan, this is likely
because the securities being analyzed for this group are
"asset-backed bonds backed by a pool of specific, homogeneous
assets 'locked' up in special purpose vehicles. This
structure, which reduces the risk of asset substitution, seems to make
the securities relatively safe and certain to outsiders" (2002,
877).
(16.) An alternative to bailouts or OLA that would address the
problem of a lack of DIP funding as a result of SIFI opacity is to allow
a troubled SIFT to enter reorganization, and permit the government to
make DIP loans to the bankrupt firm. The government could quickly
provide DIP funds to keep the firm operating but the bankruptcy process
could handle all other aspects of the resolution.
(17.) See Acting Chairman Martin J. Gruenberg's (2012)
presentation before the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Bank Structure
Conference for a discussion of how a bridge bank might be capitalized
and continue operations as a private entity.
(18.) Acting FDIC Chairman Gruenberg (2012) discussed the formation
of a bridge, and noted its advantages for protecting going-concern
(franchise) value: "... the most promising resolution strategy from
our point of view will be to place the parent company into receivership
and to pass its assets, principally investments in its subsidiaries, to
a newly created bridge holding company. This will allow subsidiaries
that are equity solvent and contribute to the franchise value of the
firm to remain open and avoid the disruption that would likely accompany
their closings ... In short, we believe that this resolution strategy
will preserve the franchise value of the firm and mitigate systemic
consequences."
(19.) http://edocket.access.gpo.gov/201/pdf/2011-1379.pdf; 4,211
(20.) The Dodd-Frank Act [section] 210(o) specifies that
assessments (taxes) to repay the Treasury are to be imposed on bank
holding companies with assets greater or equal to $50 billion and on
nonbank financial companies supervised by the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve (meaning nonbank SIF1s). Assessments are to be
sufficient to repay the Treasury within 60 months, with the opportunity
for extension if repaying in 60 months would have a "serious
adverse effect on the financial system." Assessments are to be
graduated based on company size and riskiness. When determining
assessment amounts, the FDIC, in consultation with the Financial
Stability Oversight Council, should take account of "economic
conditions generally affecting financial companies so as to allow
assessments to increase during more favorable economic conditions and to
decrease during less favorable economic conditions ... the risks
presented by the financial company [being assessed] to the financial
system and the extent to which the financial company has benefitted, or
likely would benefit, from the orderly liquidation of a financial
company under this title," and any government assessments already
imposed on the firm under such government programs as deposit insurance
or securities investor protection insurance.
(21.) The Dodd-Frank Act [section] 210(o)(1)(D)(i) prohibits the
FDIC from imposing claw backs on creditors who receive "additional
payments" if such payments are "necessary to initiate and
continue operations essential to implementation of the receivership or
any bridge financial company." The FDIC's implementing
regulation, at 12 CFR 380.27, seems to imply that a good portion of any
additional payments made by the FDIC will be for such essential purposes
so will be protected from claw back. Note that if all additional funds
could be clawed back, there might be little reason to be concerned about
the potential moral hazard problem created by FDIC payments. But, given
that the FDIC is likely to be prohibited from imposing claw backs on
some significant portion of payment recipients, the moral hazard concern
seems to be in play.
(22.) Analysts (Acharya et al. 2009, 31-2; Acharya et al. 2011,
10-1) have noted that it would be more appropriate to impose this tax
prior to any failure, and base the tax rate on a firm's riskiness.
Such a tax would discourage risk-taking. The current tax does not
discourage risk-taking, since the failing firm does not pay it. In fact,
because it is paid by survivors, it punishes, and therefore discourages,
caution.
(23.) Some authors, such as Jackson (2011), argue that a modified
bankruptcy procedure can address this excessive risk-taking weakness and
better resolve SIFIs. According to them, a system of established rules,
judicial oversight, and full public disclosure has a better chance of
both reducing bailouts and making the costs of them known than does a
non-bankruptcy resolution authority.
(24.) Dodd-Frank. Act [section] 204(a)
(25.) Dodd-Frank Act [section] 206(1-5)
(26.) The Dodd-Frank Act includes other provisions intended to
minimize moral hazard including 1) a requirement that SIFIs create
resolution plans ("living wills") to increase the likelihood
that they would be resolved through bankruptcy [Dodd-Frank Act [section]
165(d)]; and 2) a requirement that the FDIC have a plan in place, before
borrowing greater than 10 percent of the failing firm's asset, for
repaying the Treasury [Dodd-Frank Act [section] 210(n)(9)(B)I.
(27.) In the Bankruptcy Code, contracts exempt from the automatic
stay are referred to as "safe harbor contracts." The Federal
Depository Institution Act and the Dodd-Frank Act refer to the safe
harbor contracts as QFCs. Since safe harbor contracts and QFCs generally
refer to the same types of contract, we will use the term
"QFC" to refer to both, which is consistent with industry
practice.
(28.) The types of contracts exempt from the stay are listed in the
following sections of the Bankruptcy Code: 11 U.S.C. [section]
362(b)(6), (b)(7), (b)(17), 546, 556, 559, 560. All terms are defined in
11 U.S.C. [section] 101 with the exception of a "securities
contract," which is defined as "the purchase, sale, or loan of
a security, including an option for the purchase or sale of a security,
certificate of deposit, or group or index of securities (including any
interest therein or based on the value thereof), or any option entered
into on a national securities exchange relating to foreign currencies,
or the guarantee of any settlement of cash or securities by or to a
securities clearing agency" (11 U.S.C. [section] 741).
(29.) In a letter dated September 30, 1998, to Hon. George W.
Gekas, Chairman, Subcommittee on Commercial and Administrative Law,
Committee on the Judiciary, Robert Rubin, former Treasury Secretary,
argued that applying traditional insolvency laws, such as the stay, to
QFCs could cause a "possible domino effect that could turn the
failure of one market participant into a failure of the market."
See www.wilmerhale.com/files/Publication/eacecfbd-0400-4cb1-80a0-cf3a2c3f1637/Presentation/PublicationAttachment/29b1ce6d-1cel-4544-a3ec-63ecd65d11e1/Bankruptcy%20%20Derivatives%200utline%20-%20_final_pdf.
(30.) The stay existed as a fundamental feature of bankruptcy
before 1978. The Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978, however, created the
"automatic stay," which takes effect immediately upon the
filing of a bankruptcy petition. Prior to the Bankruptcy Reform Act of
1978, the stay typically took effect only after the grant of an
injunction by a court. Such grants were typical, but were often not
immediate, and certainly not automatic (Jessup 1995).
(31.) U.S.C. [section]362(b)(6)
(32.) See H.R. Rep. No. 97-420, at 2 (1982).
(33.) The Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005 (Pub. L. 109-8, 119 Stat. 23) and the Financial Netting
Improvements Act of 2006 (Pub. L. 109-390, 120 Stat. 2692).
(34.) The following language was added to the definition of
commodities, forward, repo, and securities contracts: "any other
agreement or transactions referred to" in the definition and
"any combination of the agreements or transactions referred
to" in the definition.
(35.) For example, in the simplest case of two contracts, the
non-defaulting firm is owed $1,000 by the bankrupt firm on, say, an
interest rate swap (derivative) contract, and owes the defaulting firm
$800 on a different interest rate swap contract. Under bankruptcy law,
the creditor firm may net the two contract debts such that the $800 it
owes the defaulting firm is cancelled (netted against the $1,000) and
the defaulting firm ends up owing only $200 to the non-defaulting firm.
The non-defaulting firm will have to wait for the bankruptcy process to
proceed before being repaid any portion of the remaining $200 it is
owed. This outcome is superior for the non-defaulting party compared to
the case in which netting were not allowed. Here the non-defaulting
party would be required to pay the defaulting party the $800 it owed,
but wait for the bankruptcy process to be completed before getting any
of the $1,000 defaulting party owes it. Of course, in reality, the
defaulting firm and the non-defaulting firm are likely to have many
contracts outstanding with one another at the time of default, all of
which might be netted (Mengle 2010).
(36.) This may have magnified the concentration of the derivatives
industry according to Bliss and Kaufman (2006, 67-8), who argue that
"by explicitly protecting these netting agreements, the 2005
bankruptcy changes reinforced the competitive advantage of the biggest
counterparties."
(37.) See Jones 1999.
(38.) "Immediate termination of outstanding contracts and
liquidation of collateral facilitates the acquisition of replacement
contracts, reduces uncertainty and uncontrollable risk, improves
liquidity and reduces the risk of rapid devaluation of collateral in
volatile markets" (Yim and Perlstein 2001, 3).
(39.) By "runs on repos" we mean when counterparties, en
masse, seize the collateral underlying these deposit-like instruments.
(40.) The phrase "fire sale" typically refers to the
possibility that the sale of an asset might yield a lower-than-typical
price if holders of one type of asset attempt to sell en masse. In
comparison, the "typical" (non-fire sale) price will result if
sales are distributed over time.
(41.) Krimminger (1999, 1) notes that, "[i]n the case of LTCM,
the absence of any mechanism under the Bankruptcy Code to
'slow' the liquidation of assets and collateral, [a power
granted to the FDIC under the Federal Deposit Insurance Act] and the
resulting 'dump' upon the markets, was a key motivation for
the pre-insolvency facilitation provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York."
(42.) The one-day stay lasts until 5:00 p.m. on the business day
following the date the FDIC is appointed as receiver. Therefore, the
"one-day" stay could last four days if the FDIC is appointed
as receiver on a Friday.
(43.) For the most part, the FDIC's powers under the OLA to
reject or transfer a QFC during their limited one-day stay are much like
the powers of the FDIC and bankruptcy trustees under the Federal Deposit
Insurance Act and the Bankruptcy Code, respectively, with the exception
that they are not supervised by a court nor do they receive counterparty
input (Skadden 2010).
(44.) In bankruptcy, only contracts or leases that are executory--a
contract where both parties have unperformed obligations--may be
rejected.
(45.) Dodd-Frank Act [section] 210(c)(9)(A). This is intended to
eliminate "cherry picking" (selective assumption and
rejection) of QFCs by the debtor.
(46.) This differs from the Bankruptcy Code's setoff provision, which allows a creditor to offset all obligations under a
single master agreement but not all of the contracts with a single
counterparty and its affiliates (Skeel 2010, Cohen 2011). When Lehman
filed for bankruptcy, they were a counterparty to 930,000 derivatives
transactions documented under 6,120 master agreements (Summe 2011).
(47.) If a nondefaulting counterparty has an unsecured claim after
terminating a QFC and liquidating any collateral, the claim would then
be subject to the same claims process as other unsecured creditors.
(48.)If the counterparty were to default at a later time on a
separate occasion, they may exercise their close-out rights.
(49.) Dodd-Frank Act [section] 210(c)
(50.) Damages are calculated as of the date of repudiation. The
word "damages" is defined as the "normal and reasonable
costs of cover or other reasonable measures of damages utilized in the
industries for such contract and agreement claims" Dodd-Frank Act
[section] 210(c)(3)(C).
(51.) While the three-day stay may not provide significantly more
time than one day to make such valuations, the Dodd-Frank requirement
that SIFIs create resolution plans or "living wills" and
provisions forcing swaps to be traded on exchanges could expedite the
QFC valuation process, improving the ability of the FDIC to make
appropriate decisions within a three-day stay period.
The authors would like to thank Kartik Athreya, Keith Goodwin,
Michelle Gluck, Trish Nunley, Jonathan Tompkins, Zhu Wang, and John
Weinberg for their insightful comments. The views expressed in this
article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
E-mails:
[email protected];
[email protected].