首页    期刊浏览 2025年02月28日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Does intra-firm bargaining matter for business cycle dynamics?
  • 作者:Krause, Michael U. ; Lubik, Thomas A.
  • 期刊名称:Economic Quarterly
  • 印刷版ISSN:1069-7225
  • 出版年度:2013
  • 期号:June
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
  • 摘要:This idea has bearing for macroeconomic models that incorporate search and matching frictions in the labor market. Intra-firm bargaining is not an issue in the standard search and matching model of Shimer (2005), which uses the assumption of one-worker one-firm matches such that the scale of the firm is independent of the labor input. However, in frameworks that incorporate concave production and downward-sloping demand, (2) such as in the New Keynesian search and matching model of Krause and Lubik (2007), intra-firm bargaining would have to be taken into account through its effect on steady-state allocations and business cycle dynamics.
  • 关键词:Business cycles;Business enterprises;Collective bargaining;Labor market

Does intra-firm bargaining matter for business cycle dynamics?


Krause, Michael U. ; Lubik, Thomas A.


We analyze the aggregate implications of intra-firm bargaining in a fully fledged, yet simple, general equilibrium business cycle model with search and matching frictions in the labor market. The notion and relevance of intra-firm wage bargaining in such a setting was introduced to the labor economics literature in a classic article by Stole and Zwiebel (1996). (1) The central idea is that a firm is a web of bargaining relationships between its factors of production, or more narrowly and specifically, between the owners of the firm and the workers it employs. Under the assumption that labor contracts are nonbinding, that is, workers can quit any time and firms can lay off workers at will, wage determination can therefore be understood as an ongoing bargaining process within the firm. Before production takes place, and within a time period, both workers and the firm can revisit an existing wage negotiation. As Stole and Zwiebel (1996) have demonstrated, this intra-firm bargaining has implications for allocations whenever the scale of the firm changes non-linearly with its labor input. In this case, marginal revenue depends explicitly on the number of workers employed, which changes the incentives for a firm in a noncooperative bargaining setting. In particular, it leads to over-hiring compared to an environment where intra-firm bargaining does not play a role.

This idea has bearing for macroeconomic models that incorporate search and matching frictions in the labor market. Intra-firm bargaining is not an issue in the standard search and matching model of Shimer (2005), which uses the assumption of one-worker one-firm matches such that the scale of the firm is independent of the labor input. However, in frameworks that incorporate concave production and downward-sloping demand, (2) such as in the New Keynesian search and matching model of Krause and Lubik (2007), intra-firm bargaining would have to be taken into account through its effect on steady-state allocations and business cycle dynamics.

In this article, we thus demonstrate by means of a simple search and matching model how intra-firm bargaining implies a feedback effect in the bargaining process from a firm's marginal product to wage setting. The firm has an incentive to increase production in order to decrease the marginal product, and thus the wages of existing employees, in order to capture higher rents. In effect, the firm reduces the bargaining position of the marginal worker by over-hiring. This partial equilibrium scenario, however, implies a general equilibrium feedback effect in that it leads to an expansion in production and thus a higher surplus to be shared among more workers. With a tighter labor market, the additional hiring of firms improves the outside options of workers and thus raises their wage in general equilibrium.

The main contribution of this article lies in the analysis of business cycle dynamics in addition to the above steady-state effects. It is motivated by the observation that these feedback effects are not taken into account in many business cycle models that incorporate search and matching frictions, which may raise concerns as to the robustness of their results. When compared to a specification that neglects intrafirm bargaining, we find that the dynamic response of the economy to a productivity shock is barely affected. The response of unemployment is slightly magnified, depending on the degree of returns to scale and the elasticity of demand. Similarly, employment and vacancies rise slightly more than without taking intra-firm bargaining effects into account. In this respect, intra-firm bargaining plays a role as the bargaining position of workers improves by less than is mandated by the rise in labor market tightness. However, intra-firm bargaining does not affect the qualitative response of the economy and an overall effect on output is virtually nonexistent.

We interpret our findings to the effect that, in many circumstances, researchers may safely ignore intra-firm bargaining even when analyzing business cycle models with large firms that face decreasing returns or downward-sloping demand. This is not meant to imply that there may not be important and interesting effects on the steady state of a model. This has been explored, for example, by Ebell and Haefke (2003). However, if we falsely calibrate a model without this strategic feedback on wages to actual data where it is present, the mistake we make is likely to be small. We therefore conclude that intra-firm bargaining is not the driving force of significant cyclical dynamics.

The article closest to ours conceptually is Rotemberg (2008), who incorporates intra-firm bargaining issues in a New Keynesian model with search and matching frictions. While he conducts a quantitative analysis, it is based on comparative statics around the steady state. In contrast, we perform a full calibration-based business cycle analysis, where we attempt to match the key labor market stylized facts. Cahuc and Wasmer (2001) and Cahuc, Marque, and Wasmer (2008) are similar in spirit in that they work out in detail qualitatively how the partial equilibrium effects of intra-firm bargaining have general equilibrium feedback. They work with a continuous-time framework, whereas we use a discrete-time setting that is common in business cycle literature. More recently, Hertweck (2013) provides independent quantitative and qualitative evidence in a model with strategic wage bargaining that intra-firm bargaining effects are negligible for aggregate dynamics.

In the rest of the article we proceed as follows. We first provide a simple static example to develop some intuition about the implications of intra-firm bargaining. The subsequent section outlines the model under the assumption of decreasing returns to labor and matching frictions in the labor market. This allows us to disentangle the relevant effect without much complexity. We then add general equilibrium constraints, calibrate the model, and proceed to analyze the steady state and business cycle implications graphically and numerically. In Section 5, we discuss the similarities of the results to the case of monopolistic competition, and show the robustness of our findings to its inclusion alongside decreasing returns. The final section concludes and highlights some further connections to the literature.

1. THE SIMPLE INTUITION OF INTRA-FIRM BARGAINING

The gist of our analysis can be illustrated by means of a simple static example that abstracts from search and matching frictions. Consider a simple bargaining problem of a large firm that negotiates with each worker individually. Employed workers bargain over the wage w, with their outside option being unemployment that generates benefits b. The firm's bargaining position is given by the surplus that an additional worker generates, net of its outside option, which is the value of leaving the job unfilled. This outside option is zero.

Let the firm's price be p and its output y. The firm pays wage w and employs n workers. Its value is given by its revenue minus cost, which consists of the wage bill and the hiring cost:

V = py - wn. (1)

Consider value maximization with respect to employment:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)

where we allow for the price to depend on output, which in turn depends on labor input. This covers the cases of downward-sloping demand and concave production. Moreover, we take into account that the wage schedule depends on the level of employment, which is the source of the intra-firm bargaining problem. The first term in the brackets on the right-hand side would not be present if the firm were a price taker in the product market; without concavity in the production function, the partial derivative [partial derivative]y/[partial derivative]n would be independent of employment. If the firm were a price taker in the labor market, the first term in the second brackets would be absent. It would equal zero when firms can only hire one worker, or when the firm does not internalize the feedback from its employment choice to the wage schedule. The value of a marginal worker is therefore the difference between marginal revenue and marginal cost, mr(n) - mc(n), which we indicate as depending on the level of employment.

In a standard search and matching framework, wages are typically determined using the Nash bargaining solution, which maximizes the weighted product of the involved parties' surpluses. Given a worker's bargaining weight [eta], the solution would be

w - b = [[eta]/[1-[eta]]] [mr(n) - mc(n)]. (3)

Inserting the marginal cost term and taking account of the dependence of the wage on employment yields

w(n) = [eta] [mr(n) - [[partial derivative]w(n)/[partial derivative]n]] + (1 - [eta]) b. (4)

The wage is a weighted average of the firm's marginal revenue and the worker's outside option. The second term in brackets captures the effect from intra-firm bargaining. Marginal revenue is adjusted for the feedback of the employment choice on the wage, which in turn affects the optimal number of employees. (3) Stole and Zwiebel (1996) have shown that this prompts the firm to over-hire. This feedback effect crucially relies on the assumption that the firm's marginal revenue function is not independent of employment. Otherwise, as in the basic one-worker one-firm setup of Pissarides (2000) or Shimer (2005), the wage would not depend on n as mr(n) = p, for all n, and the firm would have no incentive to strategically adjust its marginal revenue schedule since hiring an additional worker would have no effect (Smith 1999).

2. A BUSINESS CYCLE MODEL WITH SEARCH FRICTIONS AND INTRA-FIRM BARGAINING

We now embed the above mechanism in a simple model in which production is characterized by decreasing returns to labor and firms are large in the sense that they employ multiple workers. This contrasts with the standard search and matching framework in which production originates in one-worker one-firm pairs. We assume an economy with a continuum of firms that use labor as the only input in production. The production function of a typical firm is given by

[y.sub.t] = [A.sub.t][n.sup.[alpha].sub.t], (5)

where 0 < [alpha] [less than or equal to] 1, and At is a stochastic productivity process common to all firms; [n.sub.t] is the measure of workers employed by the firm. We assume that all firms behave symmetrically, and consequently suppress firm-specific indices. With the total labor force normalized to one, aggregate employment is identical to firm-level employment. Unemployment is defined as

[u.sub.t] = 1 - [n.sub.t]. (6)

The labor market is characterized by search and matching frictions encapsulated in the matching function m([u.sub.t], [v.sub.t]) = m[u.sup.[xi].sub.t][v.sup.1-[xi].sub.t]. It describes the outcome of search behavior of firms and workers in that unemployed job seekers [u.sub.t] are matched with vacancies [v.sub.t] at rate m([u.sub.t], [v.sub.t]) to produce new employment relationships. 0 < [xi] < 1 is the match elasticity of the unemployed, and m > 0 describes the efficiency of the match process. Using the definition of labor market tightness [[theta].sub.t] = [v.sub.t]/[u.sub.t], the aggregate probability of filling a vacancy (taken parameterically by the firms) is q([[theta].sub.t]) = m([u.sub.t],[v.sub.t])/[v.sub.t]. The evolution of employment is then

[n.sub.t+1] = (1 - [rho])[[n.sub.t] + [v.sub.t]q([[theta].sub.t])]* (7)

0 < [rho] < 1 is the (constant) separation rate that measures inflows into unemployment.

Firms maximize profits by choosing employment next period and vacancies to be posted, subject to the firm-level employment constraint. This job creation comes at a flow cost c > 0. The Bellman equation is

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)

V(x) is the value of the firm, [[beta].sub.t] is the time-varying discount factor, and w([n.sub.t]) is the wage schedule, which will be determined below. The notation indicates that the wage of the marginal worker potentially depends on the existing number of workers in the firm. The first-order conditions are

c = [[mu].sub.t](1 - [rho])q([[theta].sub.t]), (9)

[[mu].sub.t] = [E.sub.t]/[[beta].sub.t]V'([n.sub.t+i]), (10)

where [[mu].sub.t] is the Lagrange-multiplier on the employment constraint (7). The corresponding envelope condition is

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)

The presence of the derivative of the wage schedule reflects the impact of intra-firm wage bargaining. When choosing employment, firms take into account how an additional worker affects their bargaining position and thus wage setting.

We define the value of the marginal job J([n.sub.t]) = V'([n.sub.t]), and rewrite the envelope condition using [partial derivative][n.sub.t+1]/[partial derivative][n.sub.t] = (1-[rho]) from the law of motion (7):

J([n.sub.t]) = [alpha][A.sub.t][n.sup.[alpha]-1.sub.t] - w([n.sub.t]) - [[partial derivative]w([n.sub.t])/[partial derivative][n.sub.t]] [n.sub.t] + (1 - [rho])[E.sub.t]/[[beta].sub.t]J ([n.sub.t+1]). (12)

With constant returns to scale, [alpha] = 1, the marginal product of labor is [A.sub.t] (the "one-worker one-firm" case), and the wage is independent of the firm's current employment level. The equation then reduces to the one in Pissarides (2000).

Combining this with the first-order conditions results in a vacancy posting, or job creation, condition:

c/q([[theta].sub.t]) = (1 - [rho])[E.sub.t][[beta].sub.t]J([n.sub.t+1]), (13)

which can alternatively be written as

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (14)

To gain some intuition, suppose firms anticipate an increase in productivity [A.sub.t+1]. This raises the present value of profits and thereby the marginal benefit of hiring more workers at given marginal cost c/q([[theta].sub.t]). Other things being equal, more vacancies are posted, and [n.sub.t+1] is expected to be higher, which, in turn, reduces expected marginal product of labor until equality is restored.

This adjustment is affected by two additional channels. The first takes place within the firm, hence the label intra-firm bargaining. Adding a worker reduces the effective bargaining power of current workers and thus their wage. Assuming [E.sub.t][partial derivative]w([n.sub.t+1])/[partial derivative][n.sub.t+1] < 0, which we will show below to be true, this amplifies the incentive to post vacancies and employment increases further. In order to determine the quantitative significance of this effect, we need to solve for the equilibrium wage schedule w([n.sub.t]), which is done below. The other channel is a feedback effect that arises in general equilibrium. As all firms post more vacancies, aggregate vacancies increase, the labor market tightens, and it becomes more costly to recruit additional workers with the rise in c/q([[theta].sub.t]). Therefore, employment in each firm increases by less than it would if [[theta].sub.t] were constant.

Determining the Wage Schedule

Wages are determined based on the Nash bargaining solution: Surpluses accruing to the matched parties are split according to a rule that maximizes the weighted average of the respective surpluses. Denoting the workers' weight in the bargaining process as [eta] [member of] [0, 1], this implies the sharing rule

[W.sub.t] - [U.sub.t] = [[eta]/[1 - [eta]]] [J.sub.t], (15)

where [W.sub.t] is the asset value of employment, [U.sub.t] is the value of being unemployed, and [J.sub.t] is, as before, the value of the marginal worker to the firm. (4)

The value of employment to a worker is described by the following Bellman equation:

[W.sub.t] = [w.sub.t] + [E.sub.t][[beta].sub.t][(1 - [rho])[W.sub.t+1] + [rho][U.sub.t+1]]. (16)

Workers receive the wage [w.sub.t], and transition into unemployment next period with probability [rho]. The value of searching for a job, when currently unemployed, is

[U.sub.t] = b + [E.sub.t][[beta].sub.t][[f.sub.t](1 - [rho])[W.sub.t+1] + (1-[f.sub.t](1 - [rho]))[U.sub.t+1]]. (17)

An unemployed searcher receives benefits b and transitions into employment with probability [f.sub.t] (1 - [rho]). The job finding rate [f.sub.t] is defined as f ([[theta].sub.t]) = [[theta].sub.t]q([[theta].sub.t]) = m([u.sub.t], [v.sub.t])/[u.sub.t], which is increasing in tightness [[theta].sub.t]. It is adjusted for the probability that a completed match gets dissolved before production begins next period.

We substitute these equations into the sharing rule (15) and, after some algebra, find the wage equation

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (18)

Because of the presence of the derivative of the wage schedule on account of intra-firm bargaining, this is a first-order differential equation, the solution of which is

w([n.sub.t]) = [[alpha][eta]/[1 - [eta](1-[alpha])]] [A.sub.t][n.sup.[alpha]-1.sub.t] + [eta]c[theta] + (1 - [eta]) b. (19)

The derivative with respect to employment is given by

[partial derivative]w([n.sub.t])/[partial derivative][n.sub.t] = - [(1 - [alpha])[alpha][eta]/[1 - [eta] (1 - [alpha])]] [A.sub.t][n.sup.[alpha]-2.sub.t] < 0, (20)

which, when inserted into (18), verifies the validity of the solution.

For given employment, intra-firm bargaining increases the wage by virtue of the scale factor 1/ [1 - [eta](1 - [alpha])] > 1. The addition of a worker to the workforce implies a higher value to the firm as it lowers the marginal product of all incumbent workers. A new worker has therefore a higher value to the firm than just his marginal product because he contributes to lowering the firm's wage bill. By the logic of bargaining, the surplus is split, and workers get their share in terms of a higher wage. However, for the very reason that adding workers reduces the wage bill, firms post more vacancies to increase employment. This lowers the marginal impact of adding workers, which falls in [n.sub.t]. Thus, workers' marginal product declines with employment and hence their wage. Equation (19) gives the overall effect of the declining marginal product on the wage, corrected for intra-firm bargaining. (5)

The wage schedule can be used in the job creation condition (14) to yield

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)

The effects of intra-firm bargaining are captured by the term [1/[1 - [eta](1 - [alpha])]; which reflects the firm's internalization of the feedback from employment on the wage. It exerts a level effect in that the marginal benefit from adding workers is perceived to be higher. This induces more job creation. For the case of constant returns, [alpha] = 1, the equation collapses to the usual form, and intra-firm bargaining is irrelevant. However, our argument has so far relied on partial equilibrium reasoning from the perspective of the firm. We will analyze the general equilibrium feedbacks both on the steady-state allocation and on the model's adjustment dynamics below.

Wage Determination without Intra-Firm Bargaining

We assume from the outset that firms internalize the dependence of the wage schedule on employment (see [8] and [11]). This allows them to act strategically and extract rents from workers. Alternatively, assume that firms behave myopically by taking the wage of their incumbent workforce as given when choosing employment. This amounts to setting [partial derivative][w.sub.t]/[partial derivative][n.sub.t] = 0 in the firms' problem. In this case, the value function of the firm is

J([n.sub.t]) = [alpha][A.sub.t][n.sup.[alpha]-1.sub.t] - wt + (1 - [rho])[E.sub.t][[beta].sub.t]J([n.sub.t+1]). (22)

Following the same steps as outlined above, we find the corresponding wage equation

[w.sub.t] = [eta][alpha][A.sub.t][n.sup.[alpha]-1.sub.t] + [eta]c[theta]t + (1 - [eta])b, (23)

and the job creation condition

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (24)

When comparing the two job creation conditions, the only algebraic difference is the term multiplying the marginal product of labor, namely (1 - [eta]) < (1 - [eta])/[1 - [eta](1 - [alpha])] * Intra-firm bargaining scales the marginal product of labor and thereby introduces an additional incentive for vacancy posting. The wage equations and job creation conditions under both scenarios will be the reference points from which we evaluate the general equilibrium effects of intra-firm bargaining.

Closing the Model

We assume that all workers belong to a representative household that insures its members perfectly against income risk implied by the two states of employment and unemployment. By means of a complete internal asset market, incomes are pooled in such a way that all households choose the same level of consumption. (6) Assuming a CRRA-utility function for the household, we can thus construct an implied stochastic discount factor

[[beta].sub.t] = [beta][[c.sup.-[sigma].sub.t+1]/[c.sup.-[sigma].sub.t]], (25)

which firms use to evaluate future revenue streams. 0 < [beta] < 1 is the household's subjective discount factor, and [sigma] > 0 is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution; [c.sub.t] is the household's consumption, which draws from production as described by the social resource constraint

[c.sub.t] = [y.sub.t] - c[v.sub.t]. (26)

Total hiring costs c[v.sub.t] are subtracted from gross production as resources are lost in the search process.

3. THE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM EFFECTS OF INTRA-FIRM BARGAINING

This simple search and matching model with concave production provides a laboratory for analyzing the qualitative and quantitative effects of intra-firm bargaining. We proceed in two steps. We first compute the model's steady state and compare allocations across the two wage-setting assumptions. This discussion parallels the results in Cahuc and Wasmer (2001). In the second step, we study the dynamic behavior of the model and the implications for business cycle statistics.

In order to fix a baseline for the model's quantitative analysis, we calibrate the parameters to typical values found in the literature. (7) We set the discount factor [beta] = 0.98 and choose [sigma] = 1. The mean of the technology process At is normalized to one. We assume that the input elasticity [alpha] = 2/3, which is roughly the labor share in U.S. aggregate income. The separation rate is fixed at a value of [rho] = 0.1, which is a midpoint of the range of values used in the literature. The match elasticity [xi] is calibrated at 0.4 based on the empirical estimates in Blanchard and Diamond (1989), while the match efficiency parameter m = 0.4 is chosen to generate an unemployment rate of roughly 8 percent to 10 percent for the different model specifications. To be consistent with this, we fix vacancy creation costs c at 0.1. The benefit parameter b, which captures the outside option of the worker, is set to 0.4 as in Shimer (2005). Finally, the Nash bargaining parameter is set at [eta] = 0.5. (8)

Steady-State Effects

The model's first-order conditions can be reduced to a two-equation system in unemployment u and vacancies v. The first equation is the Beveridge curve, and is derived from the employment accumulation equation (7) in steady state, after substituting the expression for the firm-matching rate q([theta]) and unemployment n = 1 - u. After rearranging, this results in a relationship between v and u:

v = [[[rho] (1 - u)/(1 - [rho])mu].sup.1/1 - [xi]] u. (27)

It is straightforward to show that this relationship is downward-sloping and concave in v-u space.

The second steady-state relationship is derived from the job creation condition (21). Substitution and rearrangement results in the following expression:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (28)

for which no closed-form solution in terms of v is available. We note, however, that this equation defines the steady-state value of [theta] = v/u, so that this is a linear function in v - u space, namely v = [theta] x u. Consequently, the two curves intersect once, so that the model delivers a unique steady-state equilibrium. We solve the steady-state job creation condition numerically for our baseline calibration. (9) The two curves determining the steady state are depicted in Figure 1. The graph also contains the job creation curve that neglects the feedback from intrafirm bargaining, which is derived from (24).

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Steady-state equilibrium is at the intersection of both curves, which yields an unemployment rate of 8.5 percent. Without intra-firm bargaining, the job creation schedule is flatter and tilts downward, resulting in steady-state unemployment of 10 percent. This confirms the result by Stole and Zwiebel (1996), subsequently refined by Cahuc and Wasmer (2001), Ebell and Haefke (2003), and Cahuc, Marque, and Wasmer (2008), that intra-firm bargaining leads to over-hiring. Firms have an incentive to add more employees since the wage paid to all workers is declining in employment. This effect is mitigated by the feedback that hiring has on unemployment, as it raises labor market tightness and thus marginal hiring costs c/q([theta]). Overall, the levels of vacancies and employment are higher in the intra-firm bargaining case since firms can generate higher surplus by diluting the effective bargaining power of their workers. (10)

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

The same reasoning can be illustrated with an alternative description of the steady state. We use the Beveridge curve to substitute out n in the wage equation (19), from which we derive a relationship between w and [theta], labeled the "wage curve." The job creation condition can be rewritten in a similar way. Both schedules are depicted in Figure 2. We also plot the two schedules for the specification in which intra-firm bargaining is neglected. The graph shows that both wage and tightness are lower compared to the baseline with intra-firm bargaining. (11) Recall that, for given labor market tightness [theta], higher employment allows a firm to reduce wages paid to workers and to increase overall profits. However, when all firms act in this manner, labor market tightness rises both due to more vacancy postings and a decline in unemployment. The overall effect on the wage is positive, so that intra-firm bargaining raises wages in general equilibrium, which Figure 2 illustrates.

Adjustment Dynamics and Business Cycle Statistics

We now turn to an analysis of the effects of intra-firm bargaining on the dynamic properties of the model. In order to do so, we linearize both the baseline specification and the model that neglects intra-firm bargaining around their respective steady states. Strictly speaking, this analysis conflates two effects: the differences in steady state, and the differences in the coefficients in the dynamic model. It is quite conceivable that models with identical steady states can have different dynamic properties. Similarly, differences in responses (which are themselves measured in percentage deviations from the steady state) have to be interpreted with care as they are relative to different steady states. This implied error in our framework is likely to be small since the differences in steady states are small. (12)

The resulting linear rational expectations models are solved using standard techniques. We first compare dynamic adjustment paths toward the steady state after a productivity disturbance. Second, we contrast their predictions for business cycle statistics based on simulated data. In order to describe the stochastic properties of the model we have to calibrate the technology process. We assume that productivity [A.sub.t] follows an AR(1) process with autoregressive coefficient [[rho].sub.A] = 0.90, and that it is driven by a zero mean innovation [[epsilon].sub.t] with variance [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[epsilon]] = [0.007.sup.2]. This value is chosen to replicate the observed U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) standard deviation of 1.62 percent.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

The impulse response functions for both specifications are depicted in Figure 3. Two observations stand out immediately. First, the model exhibits an almost complete lack of internal propagation. The behavior of GDP follows virtually in its entirety the adjustment path of the productivity process. This observation has been emphasized by Krause and Lubik (2007) and is a corollary to the Shimer (2005) argument that the standard search and matching model is unable to replicate the volatility of unemployment and vacancies. Second, and more importantly for our discussion, the responses are remarkably similar in terms of shape, size, and direction. A persistent 1 percent increase in productivity raises current production and future marginal products of labor. This raises the value of jobs, and thus vacancies posted, per the job creation condition (21). This leads to increased employment in the following period (see equation [7]). Workers experience a rise in wages on account of higher productivity and labor market tightness. However, wages rise by less than productivity because of the strategic hiring decisions by firms. Thus, intra-firm bargaining does not change the basic dynamics of search and matching, but it (slightly) modifies its strength.

We also compare business cycle statistics computed from simulations of the two model specifications. The results are reported in Table 1. The baseline model is calibrated so as to replicate the standard deviation of U.S. GDP; the standard deviations of all other variables are then measured relative to this value. The overall impression is that the cyclical properties of the model with and without intra-firm bargaining are virtually identical. There is no difference in the behavior of output, which has already been apparent from the impulse response functions. However, when intra-firm bargaining is neglected, unemployment, vacancies, and tightness are roughly 10 percent less volatile than in the baseline case. When compared to the corresponding business cycle facts for the U.S. economy, both models fall woefully short: The latter statistics are off by a factor of 10, and the wage is 50 percent more volatile than in the data.

In terms of contemporaneous correlations, both specifications produce identical results. The models are reasonably successful in matching unemployment correlations. A benchmark statistic is the correlation between unemployment and vacancies. The model-implied value of -0.58 is not too far away from the value in U.S. data of -0.95. However, the models produce perfect correlation between the wage, [theta], and output, which is inconsistent with the data. Overall, these results support the impression that a model with intra-firm bargaining is essentially observationally equivalent to one without. An empirical, likelihood-based test of both specifications would find it very difficult to distinguish between the two alternatives as they exhibit identical co-movement and only minor differences between variable-specific volatilities. While intra-firm bargaining is a conceptually compelling idea, and quite conceivably relevant at the firm level, we conclude that it does not have a significant effect on aggregate dynamics.

4. MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND INTRA-FIRM BARGAINING

An alternative source of declining marginal revenue is downward-sloping demand in an environment with monopolistically competitive firms. Even with linear production, firms would feel compelled to expand hiring since they can capture rents by moving down the demand curve. The assumption of price-setting monopolistic competitors has been used, for instance, in New Keynesian models of output and inflation dynamics with search and matching in the labor market. Key examples are Krause and Lubik (2007) and Trigari (2009).

We assume that output of a representative monopolistically competitive firm is linear in labor, [y.sub.t] = [A.sub.t][n.sub.t], and that each firm faces a downward-sloping demand function for the product variety it produces, [y.sub.t] = [([p.sub.t]/[[bar.p].sub.t]).sup.-[epsilon]][Y.sub.t], where [Y.sub.t] is aggregate demand, and [[bar.p].sub.t] is the aggregate price level, both taken as given by the firm; [epsilon] > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between competing varieties, and Pt is the individual firm's price. The firm's real revenue is then given by

([p.sub.t]/[p.sub.t]) [y.sub.t] = [A.sup.[epsilon]-1/[epsilon].sub.t] [Y.sup.1/[epsilon].sub.t] [n.sup.[epsilon]- 1/[epsilon].sub.t]. (29)

The asset equation for the value of a marginal job can be derived following the same steps as before:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (30)

Note that despite linear production, marginal revenue responds to changes in employment, which opens the possibility of intra-firm bargaining.

The asset equation for workers remains unchanged, and so does the sharing rule. We can consequently derive a wage equation as before:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (31)

The solution to this differential equation is

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (32)

It is straightforward to verify that this expression corresponds to the wage equation (19), derived under concave production, if [alpha] = [[epsilon] - 1]/[epsilon]. However, this neglects the general equilibrium feedback effect from the aggregate demand condition, captured by [Y.sub.t], which both parties in the bargaining process take as given. Substituting [Y.sub.t] = [y.sub.t] = [A.sub.t][n.sub.t], i.e., assuming a symmetric equilibrium, results in

[w.sub.t] = [epsilon]-1/[epsilon] [eta]/1 - [eta]/[epsilon] [A.sub.t] + [eta]c[[theta].sub.t] + (1 - [eta])b. (33)

The aggregate wage equation is now independent of employment (on account of constant returns in production), but the feedback effect from intra-firm bargaining modifies the productivity coefficient. If intra-firm bargaining is neglected, this coefficient is [epsilon] - 1/[epsilon] [eta] < [epsilon] - 1/[epsilon] [eta]/1 - [eta]/[epsilon].

This wage equation can be used to derive the job creation condition, which closely parallels (21):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (34)

Since the employment equation (7) is unaffected by the presence of monopolistic competition, we can describe the steady-state solution by references to Figures 1 and 2. In the former graph, the shape of the curves is unaffected, there is a unique equilibrium, and intra-firm bargaining results in over-hiring as the job creation curve tilts downward when intra-firm bargaining is neglected. Similarly, the steady-state relationships depicted in Figure 2 remain the same qualitatively. In the literature, the substitution elasticity-is often calibrated with a value of 11, which implies a steady-state markup of 10 percent. Given our baseline specification with [eta] = 0.5, the intra-firm bargaining feedback coefficent is 1/(1 - [eta]/[epsilon]) [approximately equal to] 1.05, which is negligible with respect to steady-state values and dynamics.

5. A FINAL GENERALIZATION

Concave production and downward-sloping demand do not produce substantial effects of intra-firm bargaining on their own for plausible calibrations. We therefore combine both elements from before in the simple search and matching framework. Following the steps outlined earlier, the wage equation that takes into account the feedback from intra-firm bargaining is

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (35)

The job creation condition is

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (36)

The specification without intra-firm bargaining results in the same equations, the difference being the denominator of the term pre-multiplying the marginal product of labor. The scale factor that measures the feedback from intra-firm bargaining is now [1/1 - [eta](1 - [alpha] [[[epsilon]-1]/[epsilon]])]. This factor is increasing in [eta], decreasing in [alpha], and decreasing in [epsilon]. In other words, intra-firm bargaining affects steady-state allocations and business cycle dynamics more in economies in which workers enjoy higher bargaining power (large [eta]), the labor share of income is small (low [alpha]), and markets are not very competitive (low [epsilon]). (13)

We illustrate the role of intra-firm bargaining in the extended model by a few numerical examples, which are reported in Table 2. We compute various model statistics for variations of the parameters affecting the scale factor. In particular, we contrast our baseline calibration with a high worker bargaining parameter ([eta] = 0,9), a lower labor share ([alpha] = 0,5), and inelastic demand ([epsilon] = 2). We first note that for an extreme parameterization, shown in the right-most column, the scale factor goes up to 3, compared to a baseline of 1.25. That this implies stronger effects of intra-firm bargaining is confirmed by the percentage increase of steady-state employment and wage over the case when intrafirm bargaining is neglected, as the percentage change is monotonically related to the scale factor. For baseline bargaining power, the change in employment is, however, fairly small, but more substantial for wages. With higher worker bargaining power, these numbers increase dramatically. What the percentages hide, however, are the actual steady-state levels. The second row in the table shows that employment actually falls with increases in the scale factor.

An increase in the scale factor also has a monotonic effect on the percentage change in the standard deviation of labor market tightness. For a given parameterization, the inclusion of intra-firm bargaining improves the predictive power of the model as far as the volatility of key labor market variables is concerned. However, this scale effect again masks the fact that with high [eta] and low [epsilon] the standard deviation of [theta] is implausibly low. We conclude that the combination of concave production and downward-sloping demand can increase the strength of the feedback effect of intra-firm bargaining. From a pure calibration perspective, there is, however, a tradeoff between "maximizing" the intrafirm bargaining effect and the plausibility of key model predictions. For empirically relevant parameter values, the intra-firm bargaining effect still remains negligible as far as business cycle dynamics are concerned.

6. CONCLUSIONS

Intra-firm bargaining yields a strategic incentive for firms to expand employment in order to weaken their workers' bargaining position. This increases employment and raises wages in general equilibrium because lower unemployment and higher vacancies raise workers' outside options, thereby offsetting the partial equilibrium effect. While this is a conceptually compelling story of hiring behavior at a microeconomic level, we have shown in this article that the aggregate effects of intrafirm bargaining are negligible in a standard search and matching framework with concave production and downward-sloping product demand.

The results in this article should not be taken to imply that we regard intra-firm bargaining as irrelevant per se. The specification that combines both sources of declining marginal revenue product shows that somewhat extreme, but still plausible calibrations can imply large effects. This raises a few questions for further research. Given aggregate data, do the restrictions implied by intra-firm bargaining help with parameter specification? Specifically, the bargaining parameter [eta] is difficult to pin down. Furthermore, it is often difficult to fit the behavior of the marginal product of labor, which might be ameliorated by the inclusion of the scale factor. A related question is to what extent it is possible to distinguish between the two specifications in aggregate data. Hertweck (2013) contains some effort in this direction using a structural VAR. A second line of research delves deeper into the production side. Cahuc, Marque, and Wasmer (2008) show that intra-firm bargaining has different effects with capital and heterogenous labor. Depending on the bargaining power of workers, it may actually lead to underemployment. Their analysis, however, is restricted to the steady state only.

REFERENCES

Andolfatto, David. 1996. "Business Cycles and Labor-Market Search." American Economic Review 86 (March): 112-32.

Blanchard, Olivier J., and Peter Diamond. 1989. "The Beveridge Curve." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1989 (1): 1-76.

Cahuc, Pierre, and Etienne Wasmer. 2001. "Does Intrafirm Bargaining Matter in the Large Firm's Matching Model?" Macroeconomic Dynamics 5 (November): 742-7.

Cahuc, Pierre, Francois Marque, and Etienne Wasmer. 2008. "A Theory of Wages and Labor Demand with Intra-Firm Bargaining and Matching Frictions." International Economic Review 49 (August): 943-72.

Ebell, Monique, and Christian Haefke. 2003. "Product Market Deregulation and Labor Market Outcomes." IZA Discussion Papers No. 957 (December).

Hertweck, Matthias S. 2013. "Strategic Wage Bargaining, Labor Market Volatility, and Persistence." B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 13 (October): 123-49.

Hosios, Arthur J. 1990. "On the Efficiency of Matching and Related Models of Search and Unemployment." Review of Economic Studies 57 (April): 279-98.

Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. "Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure." Journal of Financial Economics 3 (July): 305-60.

Krause, Michael U., and Thomas A. Lubik. 2007. "The (Ir)relevance of Real Wage Rigidity in the New Keynesian Model with Search Frictions." Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (April): 706-27.

Lubik, Thomas A. 2013. "The Shifting and Twisting Beveridge Curve: An Aggregate Perspective." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper 13-16.

Merz, Monika. 1995. "Search in the Labor Market and the Real Business Cycle." Journal of Monetary Economics 36 (November): 269-300.

Pissarides, Christopher A. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd ed. Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press.

Rotemberg, Julio J. 2008. "Cyclical Wages in a Search-and-Bargaining Model with Large Firms." In NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics 2006. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 65-114.

Shimer, Robert. 2005. "The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies." American Economic Review 95 (March): 25-49.

Smith, Eric. 1999. "Search, Concave Production and Optimal Firm Size." Review of Economic Dynamics 2 (April): 456-71.

Stole, Lars A., and Jeffrey Zwiebel. 1996. "Organizational Design and Technology Choice under Intrafirm Bargaining." American Economic Review 86 (March): 195-222.

Trigari, Antonella. 2009. "Equilibrium Unemployment, Job Flows, and Inflation Dynamics." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41 (February): 1-33.

Tripier, Fabien. 2011. "The Efficiency of Training and Hiring with Intrafirm Bargaining." Labour Economics 18 (August): 527-38.

We are grateful for useful comments by Marios Karabarbounis, Christian Matthes, and Robert Sharp. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and should not necessarily be interpreted as those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. E-mail: [email protected]; [email protected].

(1) Their article takes inspiration from and shares many features with the seminal article by Jensen and Meckling (1976) on the theory of the firm from an organizational design perspective.

(2) Intra-firm bargaining under concave production has previously been studied by Smith (1999), Cahuc and Wasmer (2001), Cahuc, Marque, and Wasmer (2008), and Rotemberg (2008). The implications of downward-sloping demand schedules have been analyzed by Ebell and Haefke (2003) and also Rotemberg (2008).

(3) This expression is a partial differential equation that we can solve under parameteric assumptions for the marginal revenue function. We will demonstrate that the solution implies a wage schedule that in equilibrium scales the marginal revenue component of the wage schedule.

(4) In models with one-worker firms, the net surplus of a firm is usually given by [J.sub.t] - [V.sub.t], with [V.sub.t] the value of a vacant job. By free entry, [V.sub.t] is then assumed to be driven down to zero.

(5) In a sense, this setup can be interpreted from the perspective of insider-outsider theory: Firms are willing to expand employment and incur vacancy costs in order to reduce the bargaining power of insiders. What is crucial is that incumbents' wages are not protected by long-term contracts but are constantly renegotiated. The term "bargaining power" is of course used loosely in the sense that the Nash bargaining parameter [eta] is fixed.

(6) This assumption is standard in the literature following Merz (1995) and Andolfatto (1996). Note that the unemployed enjoy a higher level of utility than the working since they do not suffer the disutility of working.

(7) A more detailed discussion of the calibration of a closely related model can be found in Krause and Lubik (2007).

(8) Note that this violates the efficiency condition in Hosios (1990). We do not regard this as restrictive for our purposes since, as Cahuc and Wasmer (2001) have shown, the efficiency condition is modified under intra-firm wage bargaining. Moreover, we are not explicitly concerned with welfare considerations. Tripier (2011) discusses the implications of intra-firm bargaining on efficiency grounds in a model with hiring and training costs. He finds that intra-firm bargaining internalizes the thus created externalities.

(9) See Lubik (2013) for further discussion of the simple analytics of the search and matching model.

(10) The underlying mechanism is not a labor supply effect in the traditional sense, which would require increases in the wage in order to attract additional workers. More searchers find employment since the increase in vacancy postings increases labor market tightness, and thus increases the job-finding rate, which is enough to compensate the marginal unemployed worker for the lower wage rate.

(11) Since both schedules are affected under the different specifications, it may be conceivable that, say, the wage increased or decreased. Analytically, the schedules with and without IFB differ by a factor of 1/[1 - [eta](1 - [alpha])] that multiplies the marginal product of labor [alpha][An.sup.[alpha]-1]. The schedules thus shift both in the same direction. It is only for very small values of [theta] that such a reversal can occur.

(12) The conceptual background we have in mind is that a researcher might ask how much of an error he commits when neglecting intra-firm bargaining. The reason for this neglect might be difficulty in solving differential equations of the type (18), and the possibly burdensome underlying first-order conditions. Alternatively, a researcher may be interested in exploring the implications of myopic behavior by firms that ignores the strategic incentives to expand employment.

(13) This reasoning underlies Ebell and Haefke's (2003) finding that product market deregulation can have substantial employment and welfare effects. In fact, their implied values for the substitution elasticity is [epsilon] = 3.
Table 1 Business Cycle Statistics

                               Standard Deviations

                          u      v     [theta]     w      y

Intra-Firm Bargaining   0.78    0.95    1.55     0.98    1.62
Neglecting Intra-Firm   0.68    0.84    1.36     1.02    1.62
  Bargaining
U.S. Data               6.90    8.27   14.96     0.69    1.62

                                       Correlations

                          u      v     [theta]     w      y

u                       1.00   -0.58   -0.85     0.84   -0.86
v                               1.00    0.91     0.92    0.91
[theta]                                 1.00     0.99    0.99
w                                                1.00    0.99
y                                                        1.00

Table 2 Intra-Firm Bargaining: Robustness

                                           [eta] = 0.5

                                 [alpha] = 2/3    [alpha] = 2/3
                                 [epsilon] = 11   [epsilon] = 2

Scale Factor                          1.25             1.50
Employment w/ IFB                     0.92             0.88
Percent Increase due to IFB
  Employment                          3.7              6.0
  Wage                                30.6             48.4
Standard Deviation of [theta]
  Relative to Output                  1.60             1.90
  Percent Increase due to IFB         16.8             35.7

                                          [eta] = 0.9

                                 [alpha] = 2/3    [alpha] = 1/2
                                 [epsilon] = 2    [epsilon] = 2

Scale Factor                          2.50             3.08
Employment w/ IFB                     0.73             0.72
Percent Increase due to IFB
  Employment                          35.2             41.2
  Wage                                137              167
Standard Deviation of [theta]
  Relative to Output                  0.55             0.53
  Percent Increase due to IFB         52.8             60.6
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有