Characterizing the unusual path of U.S. output during and after the Great Recession.
Lecznar, Jonathon ; Sarte, Pierre-Daniel ; Sharp, Robert 等
The growth of the U.S. economy coming out of the 2007-09 Great
Recession has been relatively muted when compared to other economic
recoveries over the postwar period. Four and a half years into the
current recovery, the unemployment rate remains elevated at 6.6 percent,
while per capita gross domestic product (GDP) growth has consistently
fallen short of its historical average. One interpretation of current
economic conditions is that the U.S. economy continues to operate below
potential, and that one may soon expect a return to normal conditions
driven by increases in cyclical forces like productivity and employment.
Another view is that the tepid recovery following the Great Recession
has been driven by slower moving forces, and that a notable pick-up in
economic activity hinges on variables that tend to change more slowly
over time. This article investigates these two perspectives empirically
and finds evidence for the latter interpretation.
The focus of the article will be on U.S. per capita GDP, where
population is measured as the civilian non-institutional population
(i.e., non-military, non-inmates at institutions, 16 years of age and
over). As others have noted, the fall in per capita GDP that began in
the fourth quarter of 2007 was unprecedented in U.S. postwar history.
(1) In addition, the higher-than-trend growth rates that typically
characterize U.S. economic recoveries were notably absent following the
Great Recession: In fact, this was the only recession of the postwar
period for which, 16 quarters after its end, per capita GDP had yet to
reach its pre-recession peak.
To examine these observations objectively, we first perform some
statistical analysis on the per capita GDP time series. Using a range of
structural break tests and univariate representations of the process
governing U.S. GDP, we present evidence that the Great Recession may
have left a scar on the U.S. economy in the form of a long-lasting
decline in the level of GDP. Moreover, while we cannot conclusively
establish that U.S. per capita GDP growth has shifted to a lower trend,
we provide calculations that estimate the likelihood of realized growth
rates since the end of the Great Recession to be only 21 percent. To the
extent that the Great Recession was driven in part by financial factors,
these findings are consistent with work by Reinhart and Rogoff (2014)
that highlights the long-lasting effects of financially driven
recessions. Finally, we show that unlike every other recession in the
postwar period, the fall in and subsequent slow recovery of output
during and after the Great Recession cannot easily be explained by
shocks typical of the history up to that recession. In this respect, the
Great Recession is statistically unique among postwar recessions.
The next part of our analysis focuses on a decomposition of per
capita GDP. Since the definition of population used in this article
represents the potential workforce of the U.S. economy, our per capita
GDP series may be decomposed into the following labor market components:
labor productivity, the ratio of employment to the labor force, and the
labor force participation rate. (2) The time series behavior of these
components can then be further decomposed into different frequencies,
highlighting how their contributions to per capita GDP evolve more or
less slowly over time. These decompositions lead us to several
observations. First, labor productivity and the employment rate tend to
move with the business cycle, and although they experienced unusually
large negative shocks during the Great Recession, their behavior during
and after this recession was not qualitatively different from other
postwar recessions in that they soon began to recover. In contrast, the
labor force participation rate moves considerably slower over time, and
its behavior during and after the 2007-09 recession differs markedly
from that in previous recessions. In this sense, consistent with Stock
and Watson (2012), these simple decompositions show that nearly all of
the slow recovery in output coming out of the Great Recession stems from
a secular decline in the labor force participation rate. Remarkably, in
terms of deviations from slow-moving trends, the behavior of per capita
GDP and its components in the 2007-09 recession were not unlike that of
the other postwar recessions.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
This article is organized as follows. Section 1 examines several
different univariate characterizations of per capita GDP over the
postwar period and conducts a series of exercises that help put the
2007-09 recession and subsequent recovery in the context of previous
business cycles. Section 2 decomposes per capita GDP into subcomponents
in order to further explore key drivers of its behavior over time.
Section 3 concludes.
1. UNIVARIATE CHARACTERIZATIONS OF PER CAPITA GDP
Figure 1A illustrates the behavior of the natural logarithm of per
capita GDP over the postwar period, from 1948:Q1 to 2014:Q1, where
recessions are highlighted by vertical bars. Figure 1B zooms in on the
Great Moderation period, 1984:Q1 to 2014:Q1, which we will consider
separately since the nature of business cycles appears to be different
during this period. (3) The most recent recession clearly stands out as
unique in postwar data, both because of the size of the fall in the
level of GDP during the recession and because of the tepid growth rate
that characterizes the subsequent recovery. We will begin our analysis
by using two simple statistical characterizations of the process driving
per capita GDP growth to examine the extent to which the recent behavior
of per capita output appears unusual in the context of recessions in the
postwar era.
Deterministic Trend Model
From looking at Figure 1, a simple linear trend model appears to
provide a reasonable first-pass description of the process generating
per capita GDP prior to the beginning of the Great Recession in 2007:Q4,
[y.sub.t] = [alpha] + [mu]t + [[epsilon].sub.t], (1)
where [y.sub.t] denotes the natural logarithm of per capita GDP and
[[epsilon].sub.t] is a mean-zero error term. In Figure 1A, the logarithm
of per capita GDP indeed generally appears to have fluctuated around a
constant slope over the postwar period. In (1), [mu] then represents the
growth rate of per capita GDP while a captures its log level at some
initial date, in this case 1948:Q1.
The dashed lines in Figures 1A and 1B are the best-fit trend lines
given by the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of [alpha] and [mu]
both before and after the end of the Great Recession (2009:Q3). Tables 1
and 2 present findings from standard Chow tests that consider the
hypothesis that the Great Recession may have been associated with joint
changes in [alpha] and [mu]. Structural break tests for changes in
[alpha] and [mu] separately were also carried out. The results (not
shown) were similar to those we report in Tables 1 and 2. Table 1
considers the full sample while Table 2 considers only the Great
Moderation period. In each table, the Chow tests are carried out using
different break dates, from the beginning to the end of the recession as
defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). The tests
allow for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity in the residuals
"t and are reported as [chi square] statistics. Regardless of the
assumed break date, and over both sample periods, the tests
unambiguously reject the null hypothesis of no change in [alpha] and
[mu]. Observe that up to a given split date, the growth rate in per
capita GDP, [mu], averages around 1.9 percent (annualized) but falls
considerably lower, to well under 1.2 percent, after the assumed break
date.
It is important to note that this same method also suggests
structural breaks (at the 1 percent level) for both joint and separate
changes in [alpha] and [mu] in more than half of the other postwar
recessions. However, in the 2007-09 recession, the p-values for all
tests are less than [10.sup.-7]. Only the 1973 recession matches this
level of significance, and, in this case, the change in [mu] is actually
positive. In fact, in all other postwar recessions, either the p-values
for the results of the Chow test are several orders of magnitude larger
than those associated with the 2007-09 recession, or the change in [mu]
is positive rather than negative. Thus, while Chow-type structural
breaks were observed in many of the postwar recessions, the downward
shift in [mu] coupled with extremely small p-values make the structural
break of the 2007-09 recession somewhat unique.
Stochastic Trend Model
Findings from the simple structural break tests in the previous
subsection rely on (1) representing a reasonable data generating process
for per capita GDP. The [chi square] statistics shown in Tables 1 and 2
also rely on derivations that hold asymptotically rather than in finite
samples. A popular alternative model of per capita GDP instead
characterizes the series as having a stochastic trend,
[y.sub.t] = [y.sub.t-1] + [mu] + [[epsilon].sub.t]. (2)
Under this approach, the growth rate of per capita GDP, [y.sub.t] -
[y.sub.t-1] = [DELTA][y.sub.t], is seen as fluctuating around a
constant, as described by [mu] + [[epsilon].sub.t], where
[[epsilon].sub.t] is assumed to be independently and identically
(i.i.d.) distributed with mean zero. Importantly, in contrast to
equation (1), this stochastic process is such that disturbances,
[[epsilon].sub.t], have permanent effects on the level of GDP. Nelson
and Plosser (1982) argued that many economic series are in fact better
described as processes that allow shocks to have permanent effects
rather than effects that gradually subside over time. In practice, with
finite samples, Stock (1990) and Blough (1992) argue that the question
of whether per capita GDP is more accurately characterized as having a
deterministic time trend as in (1) or a stochastic trend as in (2) is
inherently unanswerable, so that both approaches are worth considering.
Regardless of the assumptions on the data generating process
governing per capita GDP, it remains the case that the Great Recession
appears unprecedented both in terms of its severity and its slow
recovery. To help formalize the notion of the "uniqueness" of
the 2007-09 recession, we ask two questions: First, given the set of
shocks observed in the postwar period, how likely was the realization of
the path characterizing per capita GDP from 2007:Q4 onward? Second, how
does this likelihood compare with that of previous recessions in U.S.
postwar history? In particular, were recessions preceding the most
recent downturn somewhat more plausible considering the history of
disturbances incurred up to that recession?
To answer these questions, in contrast to the previous subsection,
we explicitly take into account the fact that observations of per capita
GDP growth since the 2007-09 recession constitute a finite sample. Thus,
let us think of a given date around the start of the Great Recession,
denoted date s, from which we are trying to gauge the likely path
forward for per capita GDP. If date T represents the last date for which
we have an observation for per capita GDP, the exercise aims to give us
a sense of the likelihood of having observed the realized path
([y.sub.s], [y.sub.s+1], ..., [y.sub.T]), relative to all other possible
paths for per capita GDP, ([y.sup.*.sub.s], [y.sup.*.sub.s+1], ...,
[y.sup.*.sub.T]), given the history of shocks up to date s under the
null hypothesis that data is generated by (2). Note that there will be a
distribution of paths ([y.sup.*.sub.s], [y.sup.*.sub.s+1], ...,
[y.sup.*.sub.T]), and that the actual observed path ([y.sub.s],
[y.sub.s+1], ..., [y.sub.T]) will generally fall somewhere within that
distribution.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
To make matters concrete, let s denote 2009:Q3, the start of the
recovery. It is then possible to construct estimates of the paths
([y.sup.*.sub.s], [y.sup.*.sub.s+1], ..., [y.sup.*.sub.T]) by way of
bootstrapping, where the observed residuals ([[??].sub.1], ...,
[[??].sub.s-1]) from the model (2) are used to represent the unobserved
distribution ([[epsilon].sub.1], ..., [[epsilon].sub.s-1]) under the
bootstrap procedure. The sample of observed residuals, [[??].sub.t], t =
1, ..., s - 1, is obtained as [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII], where the OLS estimate [??] is simply the mean of
[DELTA][y.sub.t]. In this case, as indicated in Table 1, [??] is
approximately 1.9 percent. Figures 2A and 2B illustrate the properties
of the estimated residual, [[??].sub.t], from which we are sampling, and
which appear close to i.i.d. as assumed. To the extent that some small
degree of serial correlation characterizes [[??].sub.t], we consider a
slightly different variant of (2) later in the article.
The bootstrap algorithm proceeds as follows:
1. Let [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
represent a uniformly resampled version of [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], is treated as true in the bootstrap world.
2. Construct the estimated sample path [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] using the stochastic trend model, [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], where the starting value
[[??].sup.*.sub.s-1] is set to the observed value [y.sub.s-1].
3. Repeat Steps 1 and 2 many times to obtain a distribution of
estimated paths, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Figure 3 illustrates examples of four sample paths for
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], starting in
2009:Q3, generated by drawing disturbances from the period 1948:Q1 to
2009:Q2. Results reported in this section are ultimately based on sample
paths calculated from 50,000 Monte Carlo trials. Figure 4A then gives 95
percent confidence intervals for the path of per capita GDP starting in
2009:Q3, given the history of observed shocks and an estimated trend
growth rate of roughly 1.9 percent under the null. Two observations are
worth noting. First, under the null hypothesis of postwar average trend
growth, it is unlikely that today's level of GDP would be back in
line with that predicted by the pre-Great Recession trend. This finding
holds even when we take into account that, over 50,000 Monte Carlo
trials, some sample paths include some of the largest positive shocks to
per capita GDP in the postwar period experienced in succession. Second,
since 2009:Q3, the observed per capita GDP path has consistently grown
below the historical trend growth rate given by the slope of the median
(50th percentile) path predicted by the bootstrap simulations.
What if we had set s to be 2008:Q1, the first period of decline in
the Great Recession? Using (2), we can write per capita GDP at the end
of the recession, [y.sub.T], as
[y.sub.T] = [y.sub.s-1] + [mu](T - s + 1) + [T.summation over (j =
s)][[epsilon].sub.j], (3)
so that conditioning on [y.sub.s-1] and [mu], [y.sub.T] is
explained by the sequence of shocks [[summation].sup.T.sub.j=s]
[[epsilon].sub.j].
The 95 percent confidence intervals in Figure 4B indicate that the
fall in the level of per capita GDP experienced during the Great
Recession, together with the subsequent recovery, cannot plausibly be
explained by a sequence of bad shocks representative of historical data.
As mentioned earlier, recall that the 95 percent confidence intervals
illustrated in Figure 4B obtained from a large number of Monte Carlo
trials contain sample paths that include some of the worst shocks in
postwar data experienced in succession.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
One way to highlight the sense in which the Great Recession was
unique relative to other postwar recessions is to consider previous
recessions in the context of the bootstrapping exercise we have just
carried out. Thus, Figure 5 illustrates the results obtained from
carrying out analogous exercises with respect to the four most recent
recessions prior to 2007. On the whole, all previous recessions fall
within a 95 percent confidence interval generated by a resampling of
shocks up to that recession. Only the 1980-81 recession stands as
somewhat of an exception to these findings, but this is only because
this recession is followed very soon after by another one, and even in
this case, Figure 5 shows that per capita GDP returns to the 95 percent
confidence interval as soon as the second recession ends. Statistically,
therefore, the Great Recession stands as somewhat unique in the postwar
era in that, compared to previous recessions, its severity cannot easily
be explained by shocks incurred over the postwar period.
Figure 4 also shows that throughout the recovery period following
the 2007-09 recession, per capita GDP has consistently deviated from the
median path generated by (2) estimated up to 2007:Q4. Since 2009:Q3, the
average per capita GDP growth rate has hovered more than 0.75 percent
below the average growth rate prior to the Great Recession. One point of
view regarding this is that although GDP continues to evolve below
trend, it should be expected to revert back to its historical trajectory
at some future date. Another interpretation is that the trend growth
rate of GDP has decreased. A test of the latter hypothesis depends on
two key considerations: First, the greater the distance between the
observed growth rate and the growth rate under the null, the more likely
the null will be rejected. In this case, the observed growth rate during
the recovery period that started in 2009:Q3 is approximately 1.14
percent while the growth rate under the null was 1.9 percent. Second,
the longer the sample period over which the new growth rate is
calculated, the more confident we are of its estimate. In the case of
the Great Recession, we are roughly 4.75 years into the recovery, or 19
quarters.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
As an example, suppose that four quarters have elapsed since the
end of the Great Recession, and we now find ourselves in the midst of a
weak recovery in 2010:Q3. We want to know whether the observed weakness
is enough to reject the null of a growth rate at least as high as 1.9
percent given the stochastic trend model (2) and the history of observed
shocks up to the beginning of the recovery. To address this question, we
generate a distribution of estimated growth rates, b*, computed from
50,000 Monte Carlo trials of averages over samples of size 4,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], generated by the
bootstrap algorithm described above with s = 2009:Q3. The resulting
distribution is shown in the top left-hand panel of Figure 6. The left
p-value associated with a growth rate of 1.14 percent is roughly 35
percent under the null. In other words, our findings indicate a 35
percent probability of experiencing an average growth rate at least as
far below the pre-recession growth rate as 1.14 percent over four
quarters. Given standard critical values, we cannot reject the null of a
growth rate at least as high as 1.9 percent during the recovery. A 95
percent confidence interval in this case ranges from -2.15 percent to
5.91 percent.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
That said, it's now been 19 quarters since the end of the
recession. Therefore, the top right-hand panel of Figure 6 illustrates
the distribution of estimated growth rates analogous to our previous
scenario. With more observations over which growth rates are calculated
under the null hypothesis, the distribution of [[??].sup.*] tightens and
the left p-value associated with a 1.14 percent average growth rate
falls to 21 percent. In other words, there is now only a 21 percent
chance of observing a growth rate of 1.14 percent or below given
historical data. The associated 95 percent confidence interval now
shrinks to (.011, 3.764). The bottom two panels in Figure 6 show the
distributions, along with the corresponding sample sizes, needed to
generate left p-values of 5 percent and 1 percent given a growth rate of
1.14. At the 5 percent critical level, the weak recovery now
characterizing the U.S. economy and its disappointing growth rate would
have to persist for roughly 20 years before we could unambiguously
conclude that we had indeed switched to a new lower trend growth rate.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Initially, it appears that the current weak recovery would have to
last for quite a while before we could unambiguously conclude that there
has been a change in the trend growth rate. However, the relationship
between p-values and sample size is generally convex, which suggests
that when the sample size is small, a few more observations can
dramatically lower the left p-value of this test. In contrast, the size
of the sample under consideration has a relatively small impact when
there are many observations. Thus, for example, if the current situation
were to extend three and a half more years, there would be only a 15
percent chance of observing such weak circumstances under the null.
While not conclusive evidence of a change in trend growth, these
calculations nevertheless suggest a relatively low likelihood of having
observed the realized path of per capita GDP since 2009:Q3.
So far, we have examined the extreme cases of a pure deterministic
trend and a pure stochastic trend model. To the degree that Figure 2B
indicates a small degree of serial correlation in the error term of
equation (2), a more flexible representation of the data-generating
process is given by
[y.sub.t] = [y.sub.t-1] + [rho][DELTA] [y.sub.t-1]] + [mu] +
[[epsilon].sub.t], [y.sub.0] given. (4)
In this case, [rho][DELTA] [y.sub.t-1]] in (4) can be thought of as
an error correction term that introduces smoothness in how GDP growth
reverts back to trend following a shock, and thus also addresses
leftover serial correlation in "t in the simpler stochastic trend
representation (2). The properties of the estimated errors under this
more flexible representation will more closely resemble those of white
noise. Repeating the bootstrap exercises described in this section under
the more flexible model (4) does not substantively alter our
conclusions.
2. DECOMPOSING PER CAPITA GDP
The analysis thus far has provided simple calculations that
illustrate how the Great Recession stands as relatively unique in the
postwar landscape and suggest that a rapid improvement of the current
situation to levels expected from pre-recession trend is questionable. A
gradual increase in per capita GDP growth back toward historical trend
appears more plausible. However, even in the latter case, every new
quarter characterized by below trend growth adds weight to the argument
that the U.S. economy has switched to a lower trend growth rate.
To provide further insight into per capita GDP over the postwar
period, and in particular its unusual behavior throughout the Great
Recession and the subdued recovery that followed, we now decompose per
capita GDP into several components and examine the behavior of each of
these components individually. Thus, throughout this section, we will
work with the following decomposition of per capita GDP:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (5)
where [y.sub.t] is real per capita GDP, [p.sub.t] is the civilian
non-institutional population (i.e., non-military, non-inmates at
institutions, 16 years of age and over), [e.sub.t] is employment, and
[l.sub.t] is the labor force, all in logarithm form. (4) We may think of
the decomposition in (5) as (roughly) capturing different forces in the
economic environment, namely technological considerations that affect
primarily labor productivity, demographic and other structural labor
market considerations that have a direct bearing on labor force
participation, and other labor market factors that affect the
unemployment rate. (5) Our objective will be in part to assess how the
different components in (5) have contributed to per capita GDP growth
during the recessions and recoveries of the postwar period.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
In any decomposition of the type in (5), one issue is that the
different components making up the series of interest may move at
different rates, each potentially having different implications for the
series' short- and medium-run forecasts. Thus, let each of the
components making up per capita GDP follow a univariate stochastic
process, [y.sub.t] - [e.sub.t] = [THETA](L)[[epsilon].sub.ye,t],
[e.sub.t] - [l.sub.t] = [THETA](L)[[epsilon].sub.el,t], and [l.sub.t] -
[p.sub.t] = [THETA](L)[[epsilon].sub.lp,t], where the Sts represent
identically and independently distributed disturbances to the individual
component series. We then have that
[y.sub.t] - [p.sub.t] = [THETA](L)[[epsilon].sub.ye,t] +
[THETA](L)[[epsilon].sub.el,t] + [THETA](L)[[epsilon].sub.lp,t], (6)
where GDP per capita at any date t reflects the realization of
current, and potentially past, disturbances to the individual component
series. Suppose now that labor force participation,
[THETA](L)[[epsilon].sub.lp,t], moves relatively slowly over time while
the ratio of employment to the labor force,
[THETA](L)[[epsilon].sub.el,t], moves more rapidly. Then a fall in per
capita GDP induced by a large shock to labor force participation might
imply a relatively slow adjustment back to historical conditions when
compared to the case in which the fall in GDP is caused by a shock to
the unemployment rate.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Figure 7 illustrates the decomposition of per capita GDP depicted
in (5) along with the recession periods indicated by vertical lines.
Several observations stand out. First, the slope (or growth rate) of log
per capita GDP generally appears to mimic the slope of log labor
productivity. Second, there are nevertheless notable variations in GDP
growth over particular periods that are evidently influenced by
variations in the unemployment and labor force participation rates.
Third, of the latter two variables, the unemployment rate appears to
fluctuate with the business cycle, while variations in the labor force
participation rate tend to occur more slowly over time.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
Taken together, these observations suggest important variations in
the way per capita GDP has behaved historically. Thus, in a recent
effort to construct long-horizon forecasts of average growth using a
univariate framework, Muller and Watson (2013) allow for flexibility in
the univariate process governing per capita GDP by allowing the data to
be generated by a mix of empirical representations capturing different
aspects of its slow moving components. This assumption, in effect, may
be thought of as capturing the idea that different components of per
capita GDP, which behave noticeably different from each other, play
roles of varying importance at different times.
Figures 8 through 10 illustrate the decomposition in (5) during
select recessions and recoveries of the U.S. postwar period, using the
starting quarter of each recession to normalize the component series.
(6) On the whole, the fall in per capita GDP during recessions tends to
be reflected mostly in a fall in the ratio of employment to the labor
force. In contrast, recoveries are generally associated with a pickup in
labor productivity. In fact, labor productivity tends not to fall
dramatically even during recessions, reflecting the fact that technology
is almost always improving. Therefore, the decomposition in (5) reveals
that, during most downturns, falling per capita GDP can be accounted for
primarily by decreases in [e.sub.t] - [l.sub.t] and not the other
components.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
More recently, however, this pattern has changed. The 2001 and
2007-09 recessions are the only recessions of the postwar period in
which the labor force participation rate fell noticeably during both the
recessions and subsequent recoveries, dragging down GDP per capita even
after the recessions ended. Moreover, the 2007-09 recession and
subsequent recovery is the only episode in the postwar period in which,
four years after the end of the recession, GDP per capita had yet to
reach its pre-recession peak. However, the behavior of labor
productivity in the last two recessions does not differ markedly from
the other postwar recessions.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
Trends and Cycles
As mentioned earlier, the various components in our decomposition
of per capita GDP contribute differently to the aggregate series. Labor
productivity, for instance, mostly contributes a steady increase over
time, or an upward "trend," to GDP per capita. That said, the
term "trend" is somewhat charged and can mean very different
things in different contexts.
For the purposes of this article, we will mainly take the approach
of thinking in terms of particular frequencies of a series of interest.
Following the literature on business cycles and NBER practice, the
business cycle component of a series will be defined as the component
made up of cyclical frequencies corresponding to periods less than eight
years. The remaining slower moving components, made up of cycles with
periods greater than eight years, may be thought of as one definition of
"trend." Since the period, p, of a cycle is given by
2[pi]/[omega], where [omega] is its frequency, and eight years
represents 32 quarters, business cycle frequencies are then given by
[omega] [member of] [[pi]/16,[pi]] when using quarterly data.
Conversely, "trend" frequencies are given by [omega] 2 [0,
[pi]/16).
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
Definition 1 The trend of per capita GDP corresponds to its
component cycles with frequencies [omega] [member of] [0, [pi]/16).
The motivation underlying this approach is in part that slower
moving cycles are thought to be generally determined by forces outside
policymaking, such as ongoing technological progress or changes in
demographics. From Figure 7, it is likely the case that the bulk of the
contributions of labor productivity to per capita GDP occur at
frequencies lower than business cycle frequencies. Contributions of
labor productivity to the business cycle component of per capita GDP,
relative to those of the other two components, however, may nevertheless
be significant.
Balanced Growth
In considering the decomposition (5), it is useful to think about
balanced growth implications. In particular, we can think of balanced
growth theory as providing long-run relationships that should broadly
hold between the variables depicted in (5). Thus, suppose that output,
[Y.sub.t], is produced by way of the technology
[Y.sub.t] = [A.sub.t][K.sup.[alpha].sub.t][([Z.sub.t][E.sub.t]).sup.1-[alpha]], 0 < [alpha] <1,
where [A.sub.t] denotes multifactor productivity, [K.sub.t] is the
capital stock, [E.sub.t] is labor input, and [Z.sub.t] represents a
composition effect that increases the productivity of labor. Further,
let [L.sub.t] and [P.sub.t] denote the labor force and population
respectively, and let the growth rate of a given variable, [x.sub.t], be
given by [g.sub.x]. Then, along a balanced growth path, where ratios of
variables are constant, we have that
[g.sub.Y] = [g.sub.A] + [alpha][g.sub.K] + (1 - [alpha])([g.sub.Z]
+ [g.sub.E]).
But, along a balanced growth path, [g.sub.Y] = [g.sub.K], so the
above equation simplifies to
[g.sub.Y] = (1/[1 - [alpha]])[g.sub.A] + ([g.sub.Z] + [g.sub.E]).
In the long run, it must also be the case that
[g.sub.E] = [g.sub.P] = [g.sub.L].
From (5), we have that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
or, using the balanced growth relationships,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (7)
Ultimately, therefore, per capita GDP growth follows labor
productivity growth, and both are determined by technological
parameters. Beyond this observation, it is also important to recognize
that balanced growth calculations, where we may think of (1/[1 -
[alpha]]) [g.sub.A] + [g.sub.Z] as an al ternate definition of trend,
are only informative in terms of long-run relationships. This represents
a single frequency in the frequency domain, frequency zero, among all of
the periodic variations that make up per capita GDP. Put another way,
the mean growth rate is (in a sense) a single cycle of infinite period
among all of the cycles that make up per capita GDP growth.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
Definition 2 The trend of per capita GDP is (1/[1 -
[alpha]])[g.sub.A] + [g.sub.Z].
In practice, we tend to be concerned with more than the long run,
and there may be a range of slow-moving variations in per capita GDP
outside frequency zero on which policy may nevertheless have very little
effect. Demographic changes underlying changes in labor force
participation might be an example of such variations. It is in this
sense that the definition of trend in terms of frequencies corresponding
to periods longer than eight years is potentially useful. In particular,
a "gap" between [y.sub.t] - [p.sub.t] and [alpha] + [(1/[1 -
[alpha]])[g.sub.A] + [g.sub.Z]]t, for some constant [alpha], may be one
that is expected to close very slowly or more rapidly depending on the
source of the shock and the frequency at which it moves. So, if the
labor force participation rate, [l.sub.t] - [p.sub.t], experiences a
negative shock, we might expect [y.sub.t] - [p.sub.t] to fall short of
[alpha] + [(1/[1 - [alpha]])[g.sub.A] + [g.sub.Z]]t for a relatively
long period, with policy having very little ability to quicken the
closing of this gap.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
Finally, there is an alternative definition of "gap" that
is more model-based, defined as the deviations of sticky price
allocations from flexible price allocations in a setting with nominal
rigidities. To work with this definition, one must take a stance on the
degree of price stickiness and the nature of the shocks affecting the
economy at a given time. Comparisons with this more formal notion of
trend, while important, are beyond the scope of this article.
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
Trends and Cycles in the Decomposition of GDP
Figures 11 and 12 illustrate the trend and cyclical components of
the different per capita GDP components in (5). The decomposition into
trend and business cycle components is carried out using a
Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter with smoothing parameter of 1,600, given
the quarterly data. Note that, because of the linearity of the HP
filter, the trends of each of the per capita GDP components add up to
trend per capita GDP, and likewise for the cyclical components. (7) The
figures suggest that most of the variation in labor productivity and the
labor force participation rate is driven by slow-moving cycles (with
periods greater than eight years), while variations in the unemployment
rate are more frequent. This is particularly evident in Figure 12, where
the deviations from trend in the labor force participation rate indeed
appear small.
[FIGURE 16 OMITTED]
Figures 13 through 17 illustrate the same decomposition as those in
Figures 8 through 10, but are presented in terms of cycles and trends.
Annualized growth rates for each of the series in Figures 8 through 10
are now broken down into contributions from "cyclical" and
"trend" components. Examination of Figure 13, which
illustrates the 1953 recession, reveals that the trend behavior of the
series shown in the left-hand panel matches well with textbook balanced
growth calculations described in the previous subsection. Trend log per
capita GDP and log labor productivity have the same slope (i.e., grow at
the same rate), while the trend unemployment and labor force
participation rates stay relatively constant. This observation also
applies to the 1957, 1960, 1980, 1981, 1990, and 2001 recessions. The
slopes of labor productivity vary somewhat, ranging from 1.6 percent in
the 2001 recession to 2.7 percent in the 1960 recession. However, the
recessions of the 1970s, and especially that of 2007 shown in Figure 17,
present a different story. In the most recent recession in particular,
while labor productivity has steadily trended upward in a way typical of
the postwar period, the labor force participation rate has clearly
trended downward, noticeably dragging the growth rate of per capita GDP
down from that of labor productivity. Remarkably, the behavior of the
series' cyclical components, depicted in the right-hand panel of
Figure 17, appears relatively similar to that of other postwar
recessions. Put another way, at business cycle frequencies, the Great
Recession is not so dissimilar to other postwar recessions. Its
"uniqueness" resides almost entirely in slow-moving components
of per capita GDP, in this case mostly the labor force participation
rate. For the current recovery period, a small negative output gap
relative to trend still persists.
[FIGURE 17 OMITTED]
While the trend labor force participation rate has fallen
significantly since the start of the last recession, thereby mitigating
the strength of the subsequent recovery in per capita GDP, a word of
caution is in order. As mentioned earlier, the HP filter-based
decomposition of a given series into business cycle and trend components
tends to be biased toward the end of the sample, and it typically takes
two years or more for the trend decomposition to settle. Because of
this, one still might suspect that the large decline in the labor force
participation rate can, in fact, be explained to a degree by cyclical
factors related to the recession. If this were the case, our suggestion
that the unusual behavior of output can be explained by secular changes
in its components would be tenuous. However, the HP filter-based trends
of the labor force participation rate, defined as component cycles with
periods greater than eight years, are very similar to those calculated
by Kudlyak (2013) using demographic information including age, gender,
and cohort effects. In other words, a considerable portion of low
frequency variations in the labor force participation rate are
essentially explained by demographic factors; for example, one might
attribute part of the recent low frequency decline in the labor force
participation rate to the slow movement into retirement of the baby
boomers. (8) If, as Kudlyak's article indicates, demographic
factors are driving the decline in labor force participation, one might
expect the recovery of labor force participation-and therefore per
capita GDP-to be protracted, with little room for improvement from
policymakers. (9)
[FIGURE 18 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 19 OMITTED]
Counterfactual Labor Force Participation Rates
This subsection further investigates the extent to which the recent
decline in the trend labor force participation rate has potentially
contributed to the tepid recovery of per capita GDP following the Great
Recession. Specifically, we carry out a counterfactual exercise in
which, similar to Erceg and Levin (2013), the trend labor force
participation rate flattens out after 2007:Q4. In this exercise, the
counterfactual trend labor force participation rate is defined relative
to low frequency variations isolated by the HP filter. A comparison of
this counterfactual labor force participation rate series to the actual
one is shown in Figure 18.
In any counterfactual calculation of this type, changing the labor
force series, [LF.sub.t], to reflect a different trend path for the
labor force participation rate means that we must also change either the
employment series, [E.sub.t], the unemployment series, [U.sub.t], or
both, so that the identity [LF.sub.t] = [E.sub.t] + [U.sub.t] continues
to hold under the counterfactual. (10) We consider two polar cases: an
"optimistic" case in which all of the additional labor force
participation is matched by an increase in employment, and a
"pessimistic" case in which the extra labor force
participation is reflected by increased unemployment. Thus, the
pessimistic case might be interpreted as one in which the distinction
between being out of the labor force and being unemployed is not
substantive for the counterfactual increase in labor force
participation. In contrast, the optimistic case might be interpreted as
one in which the counterfactual increased labor force participation
assumes away any labor market mismatch issues or other forces that could
potentially produce mismatched or discouraged workers who then leave the
labor force.
The resulting implications for (HP filter-based) trend GDP per
capita are shown in Figure 19. (11) In the pessimistic case, as
expected, when the counterfactual increase in the labor force
participation series is simply matched by increased unemployment, the
path of per capita GDP is unaffected, but the ratio of employment to the
labor force falls.
In the optimistic case, a flattening out of the trend labor force
participation rate after 2007:Q4 results in a gain of roughly 0.8
percent in per capita GDP growth during the recovery beginning in
2009:Q3. In a sense, this figure represents an upper bound on what a
flattening out of the labor force participation rate after the Great
Recession might have implied for per capita GDP growth. At the same
time, to the degree that the current recovery in per capita GDP has
fallen short of historical trend growth by roughly 1 percent, a
considerable portion of that difference may be accounted for by the
behavior of the trend labor force participation rate. In principle, the
implications of a flattening of the trend labor force participation rate
lie somewhere between the two cases depicted in Figure 19.
3. CONCLUDING REMARKS
A simple decomposition of per capita GDP traces the unusual
behavior of output during and after the Great Recession to a large and
steady decline in the labor force participation rate. The magnitude and
persistence of this decline are unprecedented in U.S. postwar history,
much as the fall in per capita GDP that accompanied the Great Recession
was unprecedented. Moreover, the fact that the labor force participation
rate moves slowly over time, at frequencies much lower than those
characterizing business cycles, presaged a muted recovery from the
2007-09 recession relative to other recoveries throughout the postwar
period. The persistently slow recovery of per capita GDP might continue
to cause concern and potentially warrants further inquiries into the
factors-particularly demographic ones-that drive fluctuations in the
labor force participation rate. Such inquiries could help determine
whether government policy can and should be used to raise the rate of
economic growth in the years ahead.
REFERENCES
Blough, Stephen R. 1992. "The Relationship between Power and
Level for Generic Unit Root Tests in Finite Samples." Journal of
Applied Econometrics 7 (July-September): 295-308.
Erceg, Christopher, and Andrew Levin. 2013. "Labor Force
Participation and Monetary Policy in the Wake of the Great
Recession." International Monetary Fund Working Paper WP/13/245
(July).
Fujita, Shigeru. 2014. "On the Causes of Declines in the Labor
Force Participation Rate." Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Rap Special Report (February).
Gordon, Robert J. 2010. "Okun's Law and Productivity
Innovations." American Economic Review 100 (May): 11-15.
Kudlyak, Marianna. 2013. "A Cohort Model of Labor Force
Participation." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
99 (First Quarter): 25-43.
Muller, Ulrich, and Mark Watson. 2013. "Measuring Uncertainty
about Long-Run Predictions." Mimeo, Princeton University.
Nelson, Charles, and Charles Plosser. 1982. "Trends and Random
Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series: Some Evidence and
Implications." Journal of Monetary Economics 10: 139-62.
Reinhart, Carmen, and Kenneth Rogoff. 2014. "Recovery from
Financial Crises: Evidence from 100 Episodes." American Economic
Review 104 (May): 50-5.
Stock, James H. 1990. "'Unit Roots in Real GNP: Do We
Know and Do We Care?' A Comment." Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy 32 (January): 63-82.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 2012. "Disentangling the
Channels of the 2007-09 Recession." Brooking Papers on Economic
Activity 44 (Spring): 81-156.
We wish to thank Marianna Kudlyak, Steven Sabol, Zhu Wang, and Alex
Wolman for their comments. We also thank Mark Watson for helpful
discussions. The views expressed in this article are those of the
authors and do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. All errors are our own.
E-mail:
[email protected];
[email protected].
(1) For a detailed account that disentangles the various channels
underlying the 2007-09 recession, see Stock and Watson (2012).
(2) At times, for convenience given our decomposition, we refer to
the ratio of employment to the labor force as the employment rate,
although this differs from the more conventional use of the term to
denote the ratio of employment to population.
(3) Aside from changes in volatility of key macroeconomic
aggregates, see Gordon (2010) on shifts in various properties of U.S.
business cycles over the Great Moderation period.
(4) This decomposition, which lies at the core of our analysis, is
a natural one but is by no means the only potentially useful
decomposition of GDP. Other non-structural decompositions that can shed
insight into the Great Recession might include a breakdown by GDP
components in a VAR, a breakdown by regions highlighting the role of
housing, or a separation into nominal GDP and inflation.
(5) Note that [e.sub.t] - [l.sub.t] is simply one minus the
unemployment rate.
(6) To economize on space, we do not illustrate these
decompositions for every postwar recession but the observations we
highlight tend to hold across all business cycles.
(7) Because the HP filter is a two-sided filter, estimation of the
trend is biased toward the end of the sample. Depending on the nature of
the data-generating mechanism, it takes roughly two years for estimation
of the trend to settle.
(8) See Fujita (2014) for a detailed explanation of the causes
underlying declines in the labor force participation rate.
(9) The decomposition we study, being an identity, is not
necessarily inconsistent with the notion of financial factors having
played a key role in the way the Great Recession played out. However,
one expects that the productivity subcomponent of this decomposition,
among all three subcomponents, might have been most influenced by such
factors, rather than the labor force participation rate where
demographics clearly have a role. Indeed, productivity and employment
experienced a more pronounced decline relative to other recessions, but
these components appear to have recovered at a pace not too different
from that of other recessions.
(10) Here, the behavior of population is taken as given so that a
counterfactual labor force series is easily constructed by multiplying
the counterfactual labor force participation rate by population.
(11) In these calculations, trend labor productivity is assumed to
be unchanged.
Table 1 1948:Q1-2013:Q4
Split Date
2008:Q1 2008:Q4 2009:Q2 2009:Q3
[alpha] Before Split -3.853 -3.852 -3.850 -3.849
[alpha] On and After -3.118 -3.455 -3.527 -3.513
Split
[mu] Before Split 1.904 1.899 1.892 1.888
([dagger])
[mu] On and After 0.558 1.085 1.198 1.175
Split ([dagger])
[chi square](2) * 137.32 * 180.87 * 123.46 * 111.04
Notes: ([dagger]) in annualized growth rates; Critical [chi square]
(2) value: 1% 9.21 *
Table 2 1984:Q1-2013:Q4
Split Date
2008:Q1 2008:Q4 2009:Q2 2009:Q3
[alpha] Before Split -3.188 -3.185 -3.182 -3.180
[alpha] On and After -2.917 -3.066 -3.098 -3.092
Split
[mu] Before 1.977 1.946 1.905 1.882
Split ([dagger])
[mu] On and After 0.558 1.085 1.198 1.175
Split ([dagger])
[chi square](2) * 218.21 * 219.58 * 78.33 * 54.84
Notes: ([dagger]) in annualized growth rates; Critical [chi square]
(2) value: 1% 9.21 *.