The 2006-07 budget and family policy.
McDonald, Peter
Pre-budget statements by the Prime Minister and other leading
politicians aroused hopes that the 2006-07 budget would favour families
with children. These expectations were not realised.
**********
On 18 April 2006, the Prime Minister, John Howard delivered an
address to the Menzies Research Centre that detailed the
government's approaches to family policy. (1) Several of his
statements are notable. First, he reiterated the principle of
'horizontal equity'. That is, in recognition of the costs of
children and of their social benefit, a family with children should have
a lower tax burden than a couple without children (or a single person)
on the same income level:
At a time when there is general dismay at our relatively low fertility
rate, what possible public policy justification can there be for
affording precisely the same tax treatment to a couple without
children on $80,000, compared with a couple with two children on the
same income?
Consistent with the principle of horizontal equity, he went on to
reject the characterisation of family benefits as 'middle-class
welfare' and said that a taxation system that fails to recognise
the costs of raising children is a taxation system 'without a
social vision'. He also rejected the characterisation of family
benefits as 'churning', the inefficient movements of cash out
of one pocket, through the government bureaucracy and back into another
pocket. This characterisation of family benefits had been made in
January 2006 by the Labor Party's Senator Chris Evans and was given
some prominence by the chief political journalist of the Australian
Financial Review, Laura Tingle, in the pages of that newspaper. (2)
Howard cited Peter Whiteford of the OECD as showing that Australia had
the lowest level of 'churn' of any OECD country and that
'many of the supposed solutions to churning favoured by the
Government's critics would likely have adverse distributional
consequences for low and middle income households'. In other words,
family benefits in Australia redistribute income; they do not simply
churn it. Finally, echoing the feminists of the 1970s (including the
1970s Coalition Minister for Social Security, Margaret Guilfoyle),
Howard said:
One of the distinguishing features of FTB [family tax benefit] is that
it is paid to the principal carer--overwhelmingly the mother. If
simply rolled into a reformed income tax system, the bulk of
individual tax cuts would go to men, financed by the withdrawal of
direct fortnightly payments to women. (3)
As I have espoused all of these principles in the pages of this
journal, (4) this speech, just three weeks before the budget, raised my
interest in what might follow in the budget.
Five days before the Prime Minister's speech, on 13 April
2006, the Coalition's Family Policy Group, 40 backbenchers led by
Howard's long-time associate, Alan Cadman, released a radical plan
for large new universal payments for all children aged under five years.
(5) This plan was consistent with what I had proposed in 2003 for
children under the age of five and had supported again in an appearance
before the House Standing Committee on Family and Community Services
(Balancing Work and Family reference) chaired by Bronwyn Bishop in
February 2006. (6) The Cadman plan included the abolition of the
controversial new childcare rebate, but this part of the proposal was
immediately rejected by the Treasurer.
On 30 April 2006, The Family First Senator, Steve Fielding,
supported the Cadman plan in a media release. (7) This prelude and
subsequent press speculation had led, by budget night, to a strong
expectation that this was to be a budget with further major improvements
in family benefits and that new benefits would be based on horizontal
equity and be targeted at middle-income families with children under the
age of five.
This expectation was not realised. Instead the budget provided
substantial tax cuts to high and low income earners and superannuation tax benefits that will be enjoyed by the old rather than by young
parents. Aside from relatively small tax cuts, middle-income earners
with young children received next to nothing. Those with three children
received an additional $5 per week. At comparatively little cost to
government, child care places in family day care and after school care
were uncapped; that is, like long day care, in future, they will be
funded according to demand.
Rather than a focus on middle-income families with young children,
the changes to benefits in the budget were essentially made in the
context of the welfare to work initiative and were identified as such in
a press release from the Minister for Employment and Workplace
Relations, Kevin Andrews. (8) The main change in the family benefit
system was the extension of the threshold for the receipt of the maximum
rate of Family Tax Benefit Part A to $40,000. Other welfare to work
changes included an increase in the level of rebate from ($235 to $600)
and an increase in the threshold for full receipt to $25,000 for the Low
Income Tax Offset, an increase in the 30 per cent tax threshold to
$25,000 and a reduction of the Medicare Levy phase-in rate from 20 cents
in the dollar to 10 cents. These are all measures that will provide
incentives for people on pensions and benefits, particularly sole
parents to move into work. However, Minister Andrews' press release
stretches the imagination somewhat by referring to families with a total
family income of up to $40,000 as middle-income families.
With such a huge number of people of working age receiving welfare
benefits and pensions (about 2.5 million and, as a percentage of the
labour force ages, twice that of New Zealand), sound welfare to work
initiatives are welcome. Nevertheless, there remains a curiosity about
what happened to the family benefits for middle-income families. Were
they seen as being inflationary especially in association with the tax
cuts? Were they held back for next year? Or, are they off the agenda?
Finally, in his speech to the Menzies Research Centre, the Prime
Minister defended Family Tax Benefit Part B as 'additional support
for those families who desire to have one parent--usually the mother--at
home full time with children in their early years (my emphasis)'.
(9) Consistent with this emphasis on children in their early years,
Family Tax Benefit Part B has been criticised because it operates as a
work disincentive for parents who have near-to-adult children--it can
still be obtained with one 18-year-old dependent child. It is anomalous
to expect a sole parent to be working from the time her youngest child
turns six but at the same time to provide an incentive for a
married/partnered woman to remain at home until her youngest child turns
19. This is also bad policy in the context of welfare to work because
the single strongest determinant of the employment of sole parent women
is their level of attachment to the labour force at the time that they
became sole parents. Most sole parents were partnered before becoming
sole parents. Finally, if the father and the mother in a couple family
decide they will share the time out of the labour force by both working
part-time, a laudable choice when children are very young, they will not
receive Family Tax Benefit Part B even though one of them is always with
the child. (10) If their individual incomes are below $40,000, such a
couple will stand to benefit from the extension of the Low Income Tax
Offset but so will a similar couple without children. The Prime
Minister's emphasis on Family Tax Benefit Part B as a benefit to
families with children in the early years, raised some expectation of
change for those with older children. This could have been done by
'grandfathering', that is, by wiping out the benefit for all
future cases as is being done with the welfare to work initiatives.
However, the Cadman plan, released just before the Howard speech,
included the continuation of Family Tax Benefit Part B in its present
form. The budget made no change to Family Tax Benefit Part B and so this
payment will remain hotly debated.
Finally, there were no funds in the budget to support the
introduction of universal early childhood education for three and four
year olds. This reform has enormous community support and enormous
backing from those with expertise in early childhood development. The
policy is now in place in the countries with which we like to compare
ourselves, New Zealand, Canada and the United Kingdom. Early childhood
education has been placed on the agenda of the Council of Australia
Governments (COAG) and received a favourable nod at the last COAG
meeting. However, with no funding for this policy direction in the
2006-07 budget, we can expect to be waiting a long time yet before young
Australian children are given the same educational opportunities as
children in New Zealand and Canada.
References
(1) J. Howard, Transcript of the Prime Minister The Honourable John
Howard's Address to the Menzies Research Centre, Theatrette,
Parliament House, 18 April 2006
(2) L. Tingle, 'Trend to welfare state alarming',
Australian Financial Review, 12 January 2006
(3) J. Howard, op. cit.
(4) P. McDonald, 'Reforming family support policy in
Australia', People and Place, vol. 11, no. 2, 2003, pp. 1-15
(5) D. Shanahan and P. Karvelas, 'Childcare rebate must go,
say MPs', The Australian, 13 March 2006
(6) P. McDonald, op. cit., p. 12 and Commonwealth of Australia,
Hansard, House of Representatives Standing Committee on Family and
Community Services: Reference: Balancing Work and Family, Witness: Peter
McDonald, 15 February 2006
(7) S. Fielding, Family First Senator for Victoria, Media Release
SF/53, 30 April 2006
(8) Hon Kevin Andrews MP, Minister for Employment and Workplace
Relations, Media release, 114/06, 11 May 2006
(9) J. Howard, op. cit.
(10) Commonwealth of Australia, Hansard, op. cit.