The Argentine straw man: a response to currency board critics.
Hanke, Steve H.
It is noticeable, on the one hand, that a large part of the best
work on Money is topical. It has been prompted by particular episodes,
by particular experiences of the writer's own time.
--Sir John Hicks (1967: 156)
Sir John certainly would have agreed that particular experiences
prompt faulty work on Money, as well. Argentina's recent crisis is
a case in point. It has spawned a deluge of commentary on alternative
exchange rate regimes. The majority of this writing (aimed at both an
academic and lay readership) contains elementary analytical and factual
errors. (1) The most oft-repeated and egregious errors are the
following:
* Argentina employed a currency board from April 1, 1991, until
January 6, 2002, that rendered the central bank, the Banco Central de la
Republica Argentina (BCRA), incapable of employing a domestic monetary
policy.
* The peso's one-to-one exchange rate with the U.S. dollar was
overvalued and made Argentine exports uncompetitive in world markets.
* The inflexible currency board and overvalued peso caused the
Argentine crisis. A three-part reform consisting of a peso devaluation,
"pesofication" of the economy, and a freely floating exchange
rate would reinvigorate the economy.
* Replacing the peso with the U.S.
dollar--"dollarization"--was and is an infeasible alternative.
The Currency Board Misnomer
To put an end to hyperinflation, Argentina inaugurated something
like a currency board system on April 1, 1991, by rechartering the BCRA.
Argentines called the system "convertibility." Convertibility
maintained a fixed exchange rate between the peso and its anchor
currency, the U.S. dollar, on the spot market. That nominal anchor
checked inflation: the consumer price index at the end of 2001 was about
where it was in 1994. (2)
The BCRA's charter allowed it to behave more like a central
bank than a currency board in many important respects. (3) A currency
board maintains a floor and a ceiling of 100 percent and 110 percent,
respectively, for the foreign reserve cover of its monetary liabilities.
Its net domestic assets are zero or frozen. Thus, a currency board
cannot sterilize foreign currency inflows, offset outflows, or use
discretionary monetary policy. The convertibility system had a floor
under the BCRA's foreign reserve cover, but no ceiling, and the
BCRA's net domestic assets were not frozen. Hence, the BCRA could
sterilize inflows of foreign currency and offset outflows.
The BCRA used the central banking powers in its charter liberally.
Indeed, in virtually every month of the convertibility system's
existence, the BCRA sterilized or offset changes in its foreign
reserves, and in most months after 1994, it did so aggressively. During
the system's life span, there was, on average, a negative
correlation between changes in net foreign and domestic assets on the
BCRA's balance sheet, with 59 percent of the changes in net foreign
assets being either sterilized or offset with changes in the BCRA's
net domestic assets (Hanke 2002a: 210). The offsetting was especially
dramatic in 2001. Foreign reserves fell by $12 billion over the course
of the year. This decline was offset 122 percent by increases in the
central bank's net domestic assets.
The above evidence demonstrates that, contrary to the musings of
most observers, the BCRA under convertibility maintained considerable
discretion, especially after 1994. In that period, the BCRA's net
domestic asset position was more than six times more volatile than that
of Chile's central bank, which clearly has an independent monetary
policy and has had a floating exchange rate since 1999.
Under convertibility, the BCRA retained additional central banking
powers, offering lender-of-last-resort facilities, adjusting reserve
requirements, and regulating the banking sector. Over the lifetime of
the system, the BCRA issued 1,588 new regulations via its Series A
circulars--a truly staggering rate of intervention in the banking
system.
The problems set in motion by Argentina's central bank were
exacerbated by Argentina's economic czar, Domingo Cavallo. His
policies caused convertibility to lose what little semblance it had to a
currency board system. With his appointment on March 20, 2001, the peso
risk premium--as measured by the spread between the 30-day Argentine
interbank lending rates in pesos and U.S. dollars--jumped 50 basis
points and rose in step with the confidence-defeating measures that were
the hallmark of his tenure (Hanke 2002a: 210-12). The significant upward
leaps in the peso risk premium began on April 25, 2001, when Cavallo
began his attack on convertibility. After ousting Governor Pedro Pou
from the BCRA on a pretext, Cavallo instituted forced debt swaps
(property confiscations), multiple exchange rates, new legislation to
change the peso's anchor from the dollar to a euro-dollar basket,
and the prohibition of internal convertibility. The higher risk premium
likewise reflected Cavallo's regular refrains about the beauty of a
floating exchange rate. The resulting higher interest rates put
Argentina's debt dynamics over the top, culminating in its
sovereign debt default on December 23, 2001.
The fact that Argentina did not have a full-fledged, orthodox
currency board did not stop critics, as they dissected the Argentine
crisis, from pointing an accusatory finger at currency boards. Indeed,
some even claimed that Argentina had a "'pure currency
board" (Eichengreen 2002: 112). Paul Krugman (2001a), in
particular, lamented: "Because the currency board allows no
flexibility in monetary policy, policymakers cannot respond,
Greenspan-style, by opening the monetary spigots."
If the currency board critics had bothered to read the BCRA's
charter, examine its balance sheet, and recognize the flood of
regulations pouring from the pens of the central bankers, they would
have concluded that the convertibility law did not create a true
currency board. Instead, what Argentina really had was a central bank
with a pegged exchange rate and a domestic monetary policy,
distinguished by the unique feature of the convertibility of pesos into
dollars on demand. And like most central banks employing a pegged
exchange rate, the Argentine system proved vulnerable to conflicts
between the peg (the exchange rate policy) and domestic monetary policy
(Hanke 1998). A proper examination of the convertibility system would
have led any informed and objective observer to conclude that the rides
of the game contained in the BCRA's charter were flawed and that
garden-variety missteps by the authorities led to the system's
eventual demise.
It is worth noting that F. A. Hayek concluded in 1932 that critics
of the gold standard also attacked a straw man:
There has been much talk about the breakdown of the gold standard,
particularly in Britain where, to the astonishment of every
foreign observer, the abandonment of the gold standard was very
widely welcomed as a release from an irksome constraint. However,
it can scarcely be doubted that the renewed monetary problems of
almost the whole world have nothing to do with the tendencies
inherent in the gold standard, but on the contrary stem from the
persistent and continuous attempts from many sides over a number
of years to prevent the gold standard from functioning whenever it
began to reveal tendencies which were not desired by the country
in question. Hence it was by no means the economically strong
countries such as America and France whose measures rendered
the gold standard inoperative, as is frequently assumed, but the
countries in a relatively weak position, at the head of which was
Britain, who eventually paid for their transgression of the "rules
of the game" by the breakdown of their gold standard.
That the otherwise conservative managements of the central
banks deviated in a relatively lighthearted manner from the
traditional rules of monetary policy can be attributed to the
influence of new ideas on monetary policy, propagated by the
academic fraternity, which obtained wide circulation during the
postwar years [Hayek 1999: 153].
Hayek stressed that under a classical gold standard, as with a
currency board, the money supply should vary in a one-to-one
correspondence with changes in the monetary authority's net foreign
reserves. As sterilization of foreign currency inflows or offsetting of
outflows was an anathema for Hayek, so too are they for advocates of
currency boards.
The Overvaluation Canard
Currency board critics assert that the peso's one-to-one link
with the dollar under convertibility left the peso overvalued and made
Argentine exports uncompetitive, contributing to a general economic
malaise. Krugman (2000), for example, declared "Argentine producers
find themselves priced out of world markets." Martin Feldstein
(2002) agreed: "Because the exchange rate was fixed at too high a
level, Argentina exported too little and imported too much." Thomas
Willett (2002:52) also concluded that Argentina's recession was
deepened by the overvalued peso and the "inability of producers to
compete at home and abroad."
Does their story withstand examination? Argentina's exports
increased every full year during convertibility except 1999, when
Brazil, its largest trading partner, suffered a currency crisis. Even
during the first 11 months of 2001, exports were about 3.2 percent ahead
of exports during the same period in 2000 (Liskey 2001).
Argentina's export performance was relatively strong, out-pacing a
mere 0.9 percent real increase in world trade. Indeed, the export sector
was, at the time, one of the few bright spots in the Argentine economy.
If the rest of the economy had been growing as fast as the export sector
during 2000 and 2001, Argentina would not have experienced a recession.
In attempts to demonstrate the peso's overvaluation, some
observers asserted (on the basis of taxi tides from the airport or other
casual impressions) that prices were high in Buenos Aires, and that high
prices were evidence that the peso was significantly overvalued against
the dollar. A Union Bank of Switzerland survey of prices in 58 of the
world's largest cities found that for a weighted basket of 111
goods and services--including three categories of house rent--Buenos
Aires ranked 22nd, about midway between the most expensive city, Tokyo,
and the least expensive, Bombay. The survey also found that taxi rides
that were so expensive in Buenos Aires cost about 8 percent less than in
Rio de Janeiro (Union Bank of Switzerland 2000: 6, 19).
There are other indicators that contradict the overvaluation story,
too. For example, The Economist's Big Mac Index indicates that the
peso, before its devaluation, was 2 percent undervalued. Although the
Big Mac Index, as well as more sophisticated estimates of equilibrium
exchange rates, should be treated with skepticism, a recent study using
data from 1993 to 1999 indicates that the peso was always within 6
percent of its so-called fundamental equilibrium real exchange rate
(Hristov 2001).
To determine whether claims about the overvaluation of the peso
before the abandonment of convertibility were justifiable, I computed an
equilibrium exchange rate for the peso on the basis of the relative
movements of prices in Argentina and the United States. First, I
recentered producer price indexes from Argentina and the United States
so that the index number for April 1991 (the beginning of
convertibility) would be 100 for each index. (4) The ratio of the index
numbers multiplied by the base period exchange rate (in this case, 1)
gives the equilibrium exchange rate for any subsequent date. I then
subtracted the actual exchange rate (in all cases, 1) from the
equilibrium exchange rate prediction to obtain the peso's
hypothetical deviation from its equilibrium exchange rate.
I then used the same method to compute an equilibrium exchange rate
on the basis of consumer price indexes in both economies. (5) The
results from the consumer price indexes tell a much different story from
that told by the producer price indexes. But to use consumer price
indexes for an equilibrium exchange rate calculation is to commit a
serious analytical error. Because international arbitrage is responsible
for bringing an exchange rate into line with its purchasing power parity level, the relevant prices to consider in a equilibrium exchange rate
calculation are those of traded goods. Consumer price indexes include a
number of nontraded goods that are exempt from the forces of arbitrage,
whereas traded goods generally account for the lion's share of
producer prices condensed into an index. Accordingly, the predictions
made using producer price indexes more closely reflect an equilibrium
exchange rate. The results of my calculations are displayed in Figure 1.
It is clear that, using the producer price indexes, there is no merit to
the overvalued peso story.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The Devaluationists
Having conjured up news of a fire, the devaluationist bucket
brigade set out to douse the flames. For them, a peso devaluation,
pesofication of the economy, and a floating exchange rate would save the
day.
Ricardo Hausmann (2001) took the lead, advocating "first,
dedollarization of the foreign debt, the financial system and the
domestic contractual environment; second, a floating exchange rate
anchored by strict inflation targets." Michael Mussa (2001) and
Paul Krugman (2001b) concurred. And while Martin Feldstein (1999) once
observed that Argentina had "stayed competitive because its
domestic producers lowered the cost of Argentine goods by increasing
productivity," he now wrote, "A market-determined floating
exchange rate is the only way to avoid these [competitiveness]
problems" (Feldstein 2002).
Needless to say, the bucket brigade's water turned out to be
gasoline. President Duhalde chose to abandon the convertibility system
by decree on January 6, 2002, "pesofy" the economy and bank
balance sheets asymmetrically, and float the peso on February 12, 2002.
It is important to stress that the Duhalde devaluation was more than a
garden-variety devaluation because he violated the convertibility
law's redemption pledge--the government's legal obligation to
redeem 1 peso for 1 dollar. Even though the Argentine courts
subsequently ruled, in September 2002, that the pesofication of the
economy and devaluation were illegal, a confiscation of peso
holders' property (i.e., the central bank's dollar reserves of
$17.8 billion) occurred in January 2002 (Hanke 2003).
The devaluation did indeed push Argentina's trade account into
surplus--making imports three times more expensive will do that. Exports
fell in dollar terms by 4.5 percent from 2001 to 2002, while imports
imploded, shrinking by 55.7 percent over the same period.
Before the suspension of internal convertibility (the corralito)
and the asymmetric pesofication of bank balance sheets, the Argentine
banking system was robust. Extensive foreign ownership, regulations that
required a high level of capital, and prompt action to close insolvent
banks made the banking system much stronger than it was when the tequila
crisis hit in 1995, rendering it one of the healthiest in Latin America
(Powell 2003: 16, n. 24). The Duhalde administration, however, reversed
all that when it decreed the asymmetric pesofication of bank balance
sheets. Under the terms of pesofication, dollar reserves were seized
from banks and converted into pesos at the rate of 1.4 pesos per dollar.
Bank loans made in dollars were converted into pesos at one peso per
dollar in a populist move to reduce consumers' personal debt
service cost. Finally, bank deposits made in dollars were converted into
dollars at the 1.4 peso per dollar rate. Unable to withdraw their
deposits, Argentines have seen the losses on their deposits fluctuate
with each new decree and proposal for bailing out banks and depositors.
The impact of those measures on the banking sector was considerable. The
windfall loss from the measures immediately following their
implementation exceeded the capital of the consolidated banking system.
The confiscation of private property and the collapse of the
banking system (and ensuing credit crunch) have decimated the economy.
Indeed, industrial production fell by 10.6 percent during 2002, and
consumer confidence reached an all-time low. And that is not the end of
the story. In the interest of promoting its often-neglected strategic
engagement with Latin America, the Bush administration urged the IMF to
bail out Argentina in January 2003. The IMF complied by rolling over $6
billion in Argentine debt.
By turning a blind eye toward the Duhalde government's theft
and the utter collapse of the Argentine economy, which has sent millions
into abject poverty, the Bush administration jettisoned the principle of
property rights--a principle whose importance was clearly stated in the
2003 Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers. Chapter 6,
"A Pro-Growth Agenda for the Global Economy," states:
"Institutions that protect property rights are central for economic
growth" (Council of Economic Advisers 2003: 237). Moreover, it
states that countries that fail to enforce the rule of law and private
contracts will fail to qualify for U.S. bilateral assistance through the
President's new Millennium Challenge Account.
The Argentine economy is beginning to show superficial signs of
recovery, but those short-term benefits have been achieved at the cost
of future growth. Neopopulist policies have promoted capital
consumption. In 2002, depreciation exceeded investment by 6.5 percent of
GDP, and is expected to do so by at least 4.5 percent of GDP this year
(Mondino 2003: 44). While capital consumption might give temporary
relief, it portends a more comprehensive future collapse (Hayek 1984).
The Case for Dollarization
The case for dollarization--the liquidation of the central bank and
replacement of the peso with the dollar--is stronger today than ever.
Dollarization, combined with off-shore banking, could give Argentina the
confidence it so desperately needs. Argentina has never had a stable
central bank-issued currency (della Paolera and Taylor 2001). Since the
central bank was established in 1935, the peso has depreciated against
the dollar by a factor of about 9,000,000,000,000. Understandably,
Argentines do not trust the peso. Indeed, Argentines continue to
dollarize the economy spontaneously and unofficially at a rapid rate. In
2001, the greenbacks circulating in Argentina totaled $28 billion, and
in 2002 the total grew to $35 billion. This $7 billion increase exceeded
the dollar value of new peso base money emitted over the same interval.
To eliminate the possibility of more Argentine monetary mischief and
restore confidence, the central bank should be liquidated, its power to
issue currency should be repealed, and private Argentine banks should be
allowed to issue U.S. dollar-denominated notes (Hanke 2003).
Critics, however, have dismissed dollarization as a viable
alternative. Willett (2002: 59) argues that the "debate over
dollarization was like a discussion about alternative types of cosmetic
surgery while the disfigured accident victim was bleeding to
death." Anne Krueger of the IMF, when asked about the dollarization
option for Argentina at a press briefing on January 11, 2002, responded,
"Well, my understanding at the moment is that [dollarization] is
technically unfeasible. So I don't think the authorities are
thinking about it; I don't think we are thinking about it"
(Krueger 2002). The IMF crushed the possibility of dollarization with
its bureaucratic weight and made a sham of its declared policy to foster
local ownership of economic policies.
Yet, the facts did not support the IMF's position. On January
10, 2002, the central bank had "pure" foreign reserves equal
to $14.75 billion and 3.93 billion pesos in overdrafts and rediscounts
to banks that were fully collateralized by publicly traded securities
assessed at market value. Unless the central bank was cooking the
books--or the IMF knows something that we don't--those two
categories of assets would have been more than adequate to cover the
central bank's 17.92 billion in outstanding peso liabilities at the
one peso-one dollar exchange rate, making dollarization a feasible
option (Hanke 2002b, 2002c).
Conclusion
The Argentine crisis was not caused by the failure of a currency
board, but by its absence. Currency board critics attacked a straw man.
What Argentina needs is stable money and limited government; those goals
can best be achieved through dollarization coupled with free banking,
protection of property rights, and fiscal accountability.
(1) Not all of the works on the Argentine crisis suffer from these
egregious errors. See Calvo, Izquierdo, and Talvi (2002), Powell (2003),
and Schuler (2003) for a sampling of that literature. As for the faulty
literature, I will limit the citations to a sample of writings that are
most representative.
(2) Key economic and financial indicators for Argentina from 1989
to 2002 are collected in Schuler (2003: Table 1).
(3) For an early appraisal of the convertibility system's
central bank-like features and the problems that might (and did) ensue,
see Hanke, Jonung, and Schuler (1993: 72-76) and Hanke (1991).
(4) The Argentine producer price index is from the Ministry of
Foreign Relations; the U.S. producer price index is from the Bureau of
Labor Statistics (index of all manufactured goods).
(5) The Argentine consumer price index is from the Ministry of
Foreign Relations; the U.S. consumer price index is from the Bureau of
Labor Statistics (CPIU, all urban consumers, all items).
References
Calvo, G.; Izquierdo, A.; and Talvi, E. (2002). "Sudden Stops,
the Real Exchange Rates and Fiscal Sustainability: Argentina's
Lessons." Inter-American Development Bank, 11 March
(www.iadb.org/res/publications/pubfiles/pubS-146.pdf).
Council of Economic Advisers (2003) "The Annual Report of the
Council of Economic Advisers." In Economic Report of the President.
Washington: Government Printing Office.
della Paolera, G., and Taylor, A. M. (2001) Straining at the
Anchor: The Argentine Currency Board and the Search for Macroeconomic Stability, 1880-1935. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER.
Eichengreen, B. (2002) Financial Crises and What to Do About Them.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Feldstein, M. (1999) "A Self-Help Guide for Emerging
Markets." Foreign Affairs 78 (March/April): 93-109.
--(2002) "Argentina's Fall." Foreign Affairs 81
(March/April): 8-14. Hanke, S. (1991) "Argentina Should Abolish its
Central Bank." Wall Street Journal, 25 October.
--(1998) "How to Establish Monetary, Stability in Asia."
Cato Journal 17 (3) (Winter): 295-301.
--(2002a) "On Dollarization and Currency Boards: Error and
Deception." Journal of Policy Reform 5 (4): 203-22.
--(2002b) "Questions the IMF is Obliged to Answer."
Financial Times, 17 January.
--(2002c) "Questions Remain Unanswered." Financial Times,
6 February.
--(2003) "A Dollarization/Free-Banking Blueprint for
Argentina." In J. Dean, D. Salvatore, and T. Willett (eds.) The
Dollarization Debate, 387-400. New York: Oxford University Press.
Hanke, S. H.; Jonung, L.; and Schuler, K. (1993). Russian Currency
and Finance. London: Routledge.
Hausmann, R. (2001) "A Way Out for Argentina." Financial
Times, 30 October: 23.
Hayek, F. A. ([1932] 1984) "Capital Consumption." In R.
McCloughry (ed.) Money, Capital and Fluctuations: Early Essays, 136-58.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, F. A. ([1932] 1999) "The Fate of the Gold
Standard." In S. Kresge (ed.) The Collected Works ofF. A. Hayek.
Vol. 5: Good Money Part I: The New World, 153-68. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Hicks, J. R. (1967) Critical Essays in Monetary Theory. New York:
Clarendon Press.
Hristov, K. (2001) "FEER and Currency Boards: Evidence from
the '90s." Paper presented at the Centre for Central Banking
Studies (Bank of England) Conference on Exchange Rates, 26 November.
Revised version (January 2003) available from author at the Bulgarian
National Bank.
Krueger, A. (2002) "Transcript of a Press Briefing
(Teleconference) on Argentina." Washington: International Monetary
Fund (11 January) (www.imf.org/external/np/tr/2002/tr020111.htm).
Krugman, P. (2000) "The Shadow of Debt." New York Tinws,
22 November: 27.
--(2001a) "A Latin Tragedy." New York Times, 15 July: 15.
--(2001b) "A Cross of Dollars." New York Times, 7
November: 23. Liskey, T. D. (2001) "Argentina Final Oct. Trade
Surplus $605M vs. $587M Prelim." Dow Jones News Service newswire, 7
December.
Mondino, G. (2003) "The Cost of a Neo-Populist
Experiment." Latin Finance, April/May: 43-44.
Mussa, M. (2001) "Fantasy in Argentina." Financial Times,
12 November: 23.
Powell, A. (2003) "The Argentine Crisis: Bad Luck, Bad
Management, Bad Politics, Bad Advice." In S. M. Collins and D.
Rodrik (eds.) Brookings Trade Forum 2002, 1-59. Washington: Brookings
Institution.
Schuler, K. (2003) "Argentina's Economic Crisis: Causes
and Cures." Staff Report, Office of the Vice Chairman, Joint
Economic Committee, U. S. Congress (www.house.gov/jec).
Union Bank of Switzerland (2000) "Prices and Earnings Around
the Globe: An International Comparison of Purchasing Power."
Zurich: Union Bank of Switzerland.
Willett, T. (2002) "Crying for Argentina." Milken
Institute Review, Second Quarter: 50-59.
Steve H. Hanke is Professor of Applied Economics at the Johns
Hopkins University and a Senior Fellow at the Cato Institute. The author
thanks Kurt Schuler for his comments and Matt Sekerke for research
assistance.