Determinants of economic corruption: a cross-country comparison.
Ali, Abdiweli M. ; Isse, Hodan Said
In recent years, the detrimental effects of bureaucratic corruption
gained attention from development economists as well as international
financial institutions and policymakers. Corruption, which was
previously ignored and mentioned only with caution, has taken a center
stage. Nonetheless, corruption is not a new phenomenon. It is as old as
government itself. The current literature on corruption highlights its
harmful effects on growth (see Klitgaard 1988, Shleifer and Vishny 1993,
Mauro 1995, Cheung 1996, and Bardhan 1997). However, until recently the
growth literature did not adequately explain why corruption is low in
some countries and endemic in others. (1) The relevant analytical
problem is not to assess the harmfulness of corruption but why different
political systems foster different levels of corruption. We cannot
discern any useful prognosis from the literature on corruption so long
as the causes of corruption are not clearly identified. Moreover, the
empirical studies on the effects of corruption on economic growth are
besieged by endogeneity problems. Few of these empirical studies take
into account the possibility that economic growth or the lack of it can
increase or decrease the level of corruption.
This article seeks to fill that gap by identifying the determinants
of corruption and by examining the extent to which those factors--such
as education, political regimes, the type of the state, ethnicity,
judicial efficiency, political freedom, and the size of
government--explain differences in corruption across countries. When the
determinants of corruption are clearly identified, appropriate policy
conclusions can then be drawn from the analysis, and policymakers can
then design and implement measures to curb and control its harmful
effects.
Alternative Views of Corruption
The prevailing view is that corruption is harmful to economic
growth. Mauro (1995) finds that corruption lowers investment and,
consequently, economic growth. Using data from a large sample of
countries, he finds that corruption, red tape, and bureaucratic
inefficiency are negatively correlated with economic growth. Klitgaard
(1988) suggests that when political power translates corruptly into
economic gains, corruption redistributes resources from the poor to the
rich and encourages malfeasance and rent seeking. In corrupt societies,
government bureaucrats compete for positions of economic power and spend
their time and energy in the pursuit of rents. This rent-seeking
activity, in turn, affects the capacity of public institutions to
provide services. (2)
Corruption adversely distorts incentives and creates uncertainties
about the expected benefits of productive activities, forcing
entrepreneurs to undertake costly and inefficient loss-avoiding
behaviors. Shleifer and Vishny (1993) suggest that corruption is a tax
on economic activity that is more costly than legal taxes. Unlike
taxation, corruption is illegal and real resources are wasted to avoid
detection. The need to keep the transactions secret directs resources to
hard-to-detect activities with no regard for economic consequences.
Contrary to this prevailing view that corruption is harmful to
economic development, some studies suggest that it might be beneficial
and enhance efficiency. (3) Left (1964) long ago proffered that
corruption circumvents inefficient and cumbersome government
regulations. He argues that corruption mitigates the distortionary
effects of government policies and allows entrepreneurs to avoid
bureaucratic delays. A direct payment to corrupt officials reduces the
transactions cost of business and energizes corrupt civil servants who
would have otherwise engaged in delaying tactics. (4) Left also claims
that corruption generates a social benefit and serves as a mechanism for
political participation and influence for minorities and foreign
corporations. Left (1979: 328) remarks: "In most underdeveloped
countries, interest groups are weak, and political parties rarely permit
the participation of elements outside the contending cliques.
Consequently, graft may be the only institution allowing other interests
to achieve articulation and representation in the political
process."
Scott (1972) also argued that what is considered corruption in the
West is in fact a continuation of traditional gift giving in less
developed countries (LDCs). The imposition of Western values and
attitudes has transformed this traditional gift exchange in LDCs into
corruption. Tullock (1996) also claims that illicit payments are a
substitute for higher wages. Corruption therefore saves money for the
government that it would have otherwise paid in higher salaries. Lui
(1996) makes the case that what some people call corruption is nothing
but a fee for underpriced services. He suggests that corruption restores
the price mechanism and improves the allocation of resources in
distorted and heavily regulated markets.
Reassessing the Relationship between Corruption and Economic Growth
Table 1 is a correlation matrix of the regression variables
presumed to affect economic growth. A detailed description of the data
is in the Appendix. The correlation coefficient for the relation between
corruption in the 1980s and the 1990s is 0.73, showing that corruption
was persistent over the years. Those countries with high levels of
corruption in the 1980s continued to have high levels of corruption in
the 1990s. Corruption breeds corruption, and the longer it persists the
more endemic it becomes. Table 2 provides descriptive statistics for the
regression variables. The mean and the median of corruption in the 1990s
are higher than those of the 1980s. However, there is no conclusive
evidence that corruption has increased worldwide in 1990s. The
corruption indexes for the 1980s and 1990s were provided by different
organizations. They cover different samples, and the nature and content
of the survey questions might have been quite different.
Table 3 summarizes the empirical results employing the following
core equation:
(1) Growth = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] (initial GDP) +
[[beta].sub.2] (population growth) + [[beta].sub.3] (education) +
[[beta].sub.5](other variables of interest) + [epsilon].
The control variables are standard in the literature. (5) They are
the initial GDP level, the secondary school enrollment rate, and the
population growth rate. Table 3 also includes dummy variables for Africa
and Latin America to account for continent-specific characteristics.
In Model 1 of Table 3, the corruption index for the 1980s is added
to the above specification as an additional variable of interest. The
coefficient of corruption is negative and highly significant when other
correlates of growth are included in the regression equation. However,
the prevalence of corruption can be a by-product of economic growth as
well as its cause. The possibility of corruption being a function of
economic growth creates an endogeneity problem. There is a plausible
argument that lower economic growth could lead to higher corruption or
higher corruption could lead to lower growth rate. Model 2 examines this
potential bias using a two-stage least-squares approach. To correct for
endogeneity, we used ethnolinguistic fractionalization as an
instrumental variable; a measure of ethnolinguistic fragmentation. (6)
The fractionalization index is frequently used in the growth literature
and measures the probability that two randomly selected persons from a
given country will not belong to the same ethnolinguistic group
(Easterly and Levine 1997, Mauro 1995). The higher the index the more
heterogeneous and fragmented the society and the lower the probability
that economic agents are treated equally and fairly.
Ethnolinguistic fractionalization is not correlated to economic
growth but is significantly and negatively correlated with corruption.
As shown in Table 1, the simple correlation coefficient between
corruption in the 1980s and ethnolinguistic fractionalization is 0.61,
while the correlation between corruption in the 1990s and
ethnolinguistic fractionalization is 0.63. The estimated results in
Model 2 indicate that corruption has a substantial explanatory power for
economic growth. The results in Model 2 suggest that the observed
negative correlation between corruption and economic growth might be the
consequence of higher corruption causing lower economic growth rather
than lower growth rates leading to higher levels of corruption. This
confirms Mauro's results that corruption causes lower economic
growth and not vice versa. However, when we re-estimated the regression
equation using other measures of ethnic fragmentation the results are
not conclusive. The inconclusiveness is due to the smallness of the
sample size of these other measures of ethnic fragmentation. The data on
other measures of ethnic fragmentation are available only for 38
countries. Angrist and Krueger (2001) suggest that researchers using
instrumental variables should work with large samples since instrumental
variables are consistent but not unbiased.
The idea that causation might go in both directions is still
plausible and more evidence might be required to come to a firm
conclusion. If countries with lower corruption levels grew faster, this
positive experience might lead them to fight corruption even more in the
future. Therefore, economic growth in one period should be negatively
correlated with corruption in the future. Following Gwartney, Lawson,
and Holcombe (1999), Model 3 tests that proposition using the average
annual growth rate from 1975 to 1985 as the dependent variable. The
model includes all the independent variables in Model 1, with corruption
in the 1990s replacing corruption in the 1980s as an additional
explanatory variable. If economic growth is correlated with future
corruption, this variable is expected to be negative and statistically
significant. (7) The coefficient of corruption in the 1990s is not
statistically significant. The lack of correlation between economic
growth from 1975 to 1985 and corruption in the 1990s suggests that
higher economic growth does not guarantee a lower corruption in the
future. The possibility that high-growth countries will exhibit lower
levels of corruption partly as a result of becoming richer is not
supported by the empirical results. However, if corruption is a
byproduct of economic growth as well as its cause, it would be quite
prudent not to attribute too much significance to economic growth in the
1980s or the 1970s as a causal factor for corruption in the 1990s.
Models 4 and 5 provide further evidence about the cause and effect
relationship between corruption and economic growth. It runs a
regression with an annual growth rate from 1990 to 1995 as the dependent
variable and corruption in the 1980s as the only independent variable.
The coefficient of corruption in the 1980s is -0.67 and is highly
significant, which indicates a strong negative correlation between
corruption in an earlier period and the GDP growth rate in a later
period. When the regression is reversed, and corruption in the 1990s
becomes the dependent variable and GDP growth rate from 1975 to 1985 as
the sole independent variable, the coefficient of GDP growth rate is
negative but statistically insignificant.
The empirical results in Models 4 and 5 indicate that higher
corruption leads to lower economic growth but economic growth has no
effect on future corruption. This finding suggests that economic growth
by itself will not lead to lower corruption. It also indicates that
fighting corruption needs clear and explicit policy measures. For
economic growth to take place, an environment less conducive to
corruption and malfeasance should be a priority.
Model 6 investigates the possibility that corruption affects
economic growth indirectly through the investment channel. The
corruption coefficient is negative and statistically insignificant when
the ratio of investment to GDP is used as the dependent variable. This
result contradicts Mauro's findings that corruption is a tax on
capital investment. Campos, Lien, and Pradhan (1999) and Wedeman (1996)
found similar results and suggested some possible explanations. Wedeman
(1996) argues that while correlation between corruption and the ratio of
investment to GDP might be strong for some countries with little
corruption, it loses its statistical significance for countries with
higher levels of corruption. Therefore, certain kinds of corruption
might have more importance for investment decisions than the overall
level of corruption.
Predictive Content of Corruption for Growth
In this section, the predictive content of corruption for growth is
investigated using the Granger-Causality test, which helps determine
whether the corruption index contains additional information about
subsequently realized growth rates beyond what is already contained in
the past history of actual GDP growth rates. The Granger-causality
equations explain how much of the current GDP growth rate can be
explained by past GDP growth rates and whether adding lagged values of
corruption can improve the explanation. The GDP growth rate is
Granger-caused by corruption if corruption helps in the prediction of
the GDP growth rate or if the coefficients on lagged corruption are
statistically significant.
Consider the following regressions:
(2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where G is the growth rate of GDP, C is corruption, and e is a
disturbance term. Corruption Granger-causes growth if [[lambda].sub.a]
[not equal to] [a.sub.2k] [not equal to]0. In that case, corruption
provides information about the subsequently realized GDP growth rates
beyond what is already contained in the past history of actual GDP
growth rates. Similarly, GDP Granger-causes corruption if
[[lambda].sub.b] [not equal to] [a.sub.3k] [not equal to] ask 0. In that
case, GDP growth rates have information about corruption beyond what is
already contained in the past history of corruption.
The results of the Granger-causality test are reported in Table 4.
As the table shows, corruption Granger-causes the GDP growth rate,
implying that corruption has information about the subsequently realized
GDP growth rate beyond what is already contained in the past history of
the GDP growth rate. In contrast, GDP fails to Granger-cause corruption
and has no predictive content beyond what is already contained in the
past history of corruption.
Determinants of Corruption: The Empirical Evidence
Model 7 of Table 3 regresses the corruption level of the 1990s on
some independent variables that we consider relevant in explaining the
difference in corruption levels across countries. Corruption in the
1980s is added as an additional explanatory variable because the other
determinants of corruption can easily be affected by that variable.
Clearly there is some persistence in corruption. The coefficient of
corruption in the 1980s is positive and highly significant. Most of the
coefficients of the other explanatory variables are also significant at
the 5 percent level.
The coefficient of education is negative and significant at the 1
percent level. Evaluating the effect at the sample mean, the estimated
coefficient indicates that a one-unit increase in secondary school
enrollment reduces corruption by 0.508 percent. The rule of law also has
a noticeable impact on corruption. For example, a one-unit increase of
the rule of law is associated with a decline of corruption by 0.18
percentage points.
The size of government is positively and significantly correlated
with the level of corruption. The coefficient of GOV in Model 7 shows
that a 10 percent increase of the size of government is associated with
about a 2 percent increase in the level of corruption. The coefficient
of foreign aid is also positive and highly significant. Foreign aid
strengthens the predatory power of the government and thus undermines
the emergence of the private sector. Since foreign aid is fungible, it
tends to increase government consumption. It creates opportunities for
the government to proliferate, which in turn increases the level of
corruption. The interaction term between foreign aid and government
expenditure shows that the marginal effect of government expenditure on
corruption increases with the level of foreign aid.
Political freedom is negatively correlated with corruption;
however, the correlation coefficient of political freedom is not
significant at the conventional level. The effect of freedom on
corruption appears in the economic freedom coefficient. The coefficient
of economic freedom is negative and significant at the 5 percent level.
The empirical results also indicate that federalism reduces corruption.
The coefficient of the type of the state in Model 7 is significant at
the 10 percent level. Two dummy variables are also included in Model 7
to account for continent specific characteristics. The dummy variable for Africa is positive and insignificant, while the dummy variable for
Latin America is negative and significant.
Most of the indicators we used to explain variations in corruption
across countries reflect an overall impression of how well countries are
governed in a very general sense. If so, they will be correlated with
corruption, itself subjectively measured. A more interesting and
informative test would include more objectively measured determinants of
corruption. Therefore, in Model 7, the per capita GDP growth rate is
also included as an additional explanatory variable. The coefficient of
the per capita GDP growth rate is negative but statistically
insignificant.
The empirical results are consistent with the theory that higher
judicial efficiency, higher level of schooling, greater economic
freedom, smaller government, less foreign aid, and decentralized government will lower corruption. Ethnicity has no significant impact on
corruption. The implications of these results are obvious. Those poor
countries with large and cumbersome bureaucracies, weak and inefficient
judicial systems, and poor educational systems can reduce corruption and
increase their growth potential by improving their legal systems,
investing in education, reducing the size of the government, reducing
dependence on foreign aid, and decentralizing the power of the state.
Conclusion
The social and economic costs of corruption recently gained
attention from the development literature. The literature on corruption
emphasized the deleterious effects of corruption on investment and
economic growth. However, until recently no attempt has been made to
elaborate the determinants of economic corruption. In this article,
education, judicial efficiency, the size of government, political and
economic freedom, foreign aid, ethnicity, and the type of the political
regime are used to explain cross-country differences in corruption.
Corruption is found to be negatively and significantly correlated with
the level of education, judicial efficiency, and economic freedom. It is
positively and significantly correlated with foreign aid and the size of
government. An interesting result of this study, which might need
further analysis, is the effect of foreign aid on corruption. The
coefficient of foreign aid is positive and highly significant. The
fungibility of foreign aid exacerbates the negative effect of big
government on growth. The interaction term between foreign aid and
government expenditure in Model 7 of Table 3 suggests that the marginal
effect of government expenditure on corruption increases with the level
of foreign aid.
The findings of this study also indicate that those countries that
enjoyed a substantial growth rate for the past two decades are those
that developed legal, institutional, and educational measures that
encouraged bureaucratic honesty and discouraged corruption and
malfeasance. The political implications of the study are clear. Efforts
should be directed to the establishment of good education, efficient
legal systems, smaller and decentralized government, and less dependence
on foreign aid. Corruption is encouraged not only by the importance of
government as the provider of goods and services but also as the
producer of a plethora of confusing and contradictory regulations.
Resources should thus be marshaled to expand opportunities for
employment in the private sector.
Corruption flourishes in an environment of unrestrained
bureaucracy. It can be contained when the laws of the land are
vigorously enforced. Moreover, when the administration or the political
order is considered as illegitimate, the social pressures against acts
of corruption become less important. Corruption can therefore be
effectively curtailed by an administration that enjoys an enduring
legitimacy.
Appendix: Description, Source, and Relevance of the Variables
AID: Effective development assistance (EDA) measures official aid
flows as the sum of grants and the grant equivalent of official loans.
The grant equivalent of a financial inflow is the amount that, at the
time of its commitment, is not expected to be repaid--that is, the
amount subsidized through below-market terms at the time of commitment.
Corruption 1980s: The corruption level in the 1980s. It measures
the extent to which high government officials are likely to demand
special payments. It is from the Political Risk Services of Syracuse,
New York, a private firm that publishes "country risk factors"
and sells them to interested parties. The data on corrup80 is available
only from 1982 to 1990. The index ranks countries in the scale of 0 to
6, where 0 means the highest level of corruption and 6 the lowest. We
reversed the scale and converted the original ranking of 0 to 6 into a
scale of 0 to 1.
Corruption 1990s: The corruption level in the 1990s. It is from
Transparency International (a coalition against corruption in
international business transactions). This index is based on
international surveys of business people and reflects their impressions
and perceptions of the countries surveyed. The index is available from
1995 to 1999, and ranks countries on a scale of 0 to 10. For conformity,
we reversed the scale and converted the original rankings into a scale
of 0 to 1.
Economic Freedom: Measures the extent to which economic agents are
free to use the market mechanism for the allocation of resources and the
extent to which property fights are protected. The index ranks countries
on a scale of 0 to 10, where 10 indicates the highest level of economic
freedom and 0 the lowest. For conformity, we converted the original
ranking of 0 to 10 into a scale of 0 to 1. This index is from Gwartney
and Lawson (1997) and covers more than 100 countries.
Ethnicity: The domination of one ethnic group in the polity of a
country creates differential access to power. Less powerful political
ethnic groups or minorities resort to corruption for leveling the
political and economic landscape. In ethnically diverse societies, the
obligation of a bureaucrat is sequential: first to his close kin, then
to his ethnic group, and then maybe to his country. Thus, highly
fragmented societies are likely to be more corrupt than homogenous societies. We converted the original ranking of 0 to 100 into a scale of
0 to 1. The index is from Mauro (1995) and Easterly and Levine (1997).
Government Expenditure Share of GDP: Economic corruption is defined
as the sale of public office for a private gain. Big governments create
opportunities for corruption. The larger the size of the bureaucracy,
the more likely that more bureaucrats will put their offices up for
sale. In LDCs, the modern private sector is embryonic and the state
assumes the primary role of allocating and distributing resources. The
larger the relative size and scope of the public sector, the greater the
likelihood of corrupt behavior.
Growth of Real GDP per Capita (90-95, 75-95, 75-85): World
Development Indicators, the 1998 edition (hereafter WDI98).
Political Freedom: An index that measures the level of political
freedom. The index ranks countries on a scale of 0 to 7. The higher the
score the lower the level of political freedom. We reversed the scale
and converted the original ranking of 0 to 7 into a scale of 0 to 1.
When the media is independent and free from government control, and
citizens are allowed to freely express their opinion about the affairs
of the state, governments become more transparent and corruption easily
exposed. Thus, politically open societies tend to be less corrupt.
Furthermore, when the political order is undemocratic and is perceived
by the public as an illegitimate entity, social pressures against the
acts of corruption are of little significance. Stealing from the
oppressor is not as tainted as stealing from the public treasury. The
political freedom index is from the Freedom House and is compiled
annually since 1972.
Rule of Law: Reflects the degree to which the citizens of a country
are willing to accept the established institutions to make and implement
laws and adjudicate disputes. It also measures the extent that countries
have sound political institutions, strong courts, and orderly succession
of powers. Cheung (1996) attributes the pervasiveness of corruption in
LDCs to the weakness and the absence of institutional safeguards--that
is, to a lack of well-defined and firmly enforced private property
rights. It is from the Political Risk Services of Syracuse, New York,
and ranks countries on a scale of 0 to 6. This index is available only
for the 1982-90 period. Again, the original ranking is converted into a
scale of 0 to 1.
The level of corruption depends on the extent to which the laws of
the land are binding and enforced. Corrupt officials are rational
welfare maximizers. They weigh the pecuniary benefits from corruption
against its cost. The personal cost of corruption is the loss of a job
and the jail-time if caught and persecuted. Individuals will act
corruptly so long as the perceived gains from corruption outweigh the
costs. The probability of detection is lower the more lackadaisical the
judicial system is. Judicial laxity reduces the opportunity cost of
being corrupt. Hence, countries with strict laws and efficient judicial
systems tend to be less corrupt and vice versa.
Secondary School Enrollment Rate in 1975: Measures the percentage
of school-age population that was enrolled in secondary schools in 1975.
A higher level of education fosters a sense of nationalism and instills
pride and civic duty in the citizenry. It also raises the public's
awareness of their rights for the services of the bureaucrats.
Generally, most of the citizens in LDCs are not aware that they are
entitled to the services of the bureaucrats. Scott (1972: 15) succinctly
described this lack of awareness in developing countries:
The bureaucrat is a high school or university graduate.., who deals
often with illiterate peasants for whom government, let alone its
regulations, is a mystifying and dangerous thing. In approaching a
civil servant, the peasant is not generally an informed citizen
seeking a service to which he is entitled, but a subject seeking to
appease a powerful man whose ways he cannot fathom; where the modern
citizen might demand, he begs or flatters.
In developing countries there is a confusion of the
bureaucrat's private rights and his public responsibility. The
bureaucrat hardly distinguishes when he is acting in a public capacity
providing services as a matter of duty, from when he is acting in a
private capacity providing personal services. That attitude is
attenuated by the ignorance of the general public. Thus, the higher the
level of education, the lower the level of corruption.
Type of State (Federal or Unitary System): Decentralization and
vertical separation of powers reduces corruption and creates multiple
veto powers along vertically competing jurisdictions. It makes collusion
among corrupt officials difficult to enforce. However, Shleifer and
Vishny (1993) claimed that centralized corruption is preferable to
decentralized corruption for efficiency purposes. They claim that the
devolution of power from central to regional governments multiplies
opportunities of corruption. They suggest that decentralized governments
with decentralized bribe-taking mechanisms increase the cost of
bureaucratic corruption. The cost of corruption becomes excessive when
different levels of the government set their bribes independently.
Federalism as a hierarchical separation of powers can therefore either
increase corruption or keep it in check. We use a binary variable that
takes 0 if a country is a centralized unitary state and 1 if it is a
decentralized federal system.
TABLE 1
CORRELATION MATRIX OF THE REGRESSION VARIABLES
GDP ETH-
INV GPOP 75 SECE POL GOV NICITY
INV 1.00
GPOP -0.08 1.00
GDP75 0.02 -0.02 1.00
SECE 0.12 -0.72 -0.69 1.00
POL 0.10 -0.65 0.39 0.63 1.00
GOV -0.18 0.45 0.22 -0.28 -0.24 1.00
ETHNICITY -0.11 0.33 -0.29 -0.33 -0.36 0.01 1.00
LAW 0.26 -0.52 0.53 0.73 0.59 -0.18 -0.33
STATE -0.11 -0.15 0.14 0.13 0.10 -0.03 0.28
CORRUP80 -0.29 0.73 -0.44 -0.75 -0.55 0.36 0.61
CORRUP90 -0.19 0.57 -0.57 -0.72 -0.53 0.16 0.63
ECO 0.57 -0.71 0.38 0.82 0.57 -0.35 -0.59
CORRUP CORRUP
LAW STATE 80 90 ECO
INV
GPOP
GDP75
SECE
POL
GOV
ETHNICITY
LAW 1.00
STATE 0.25 1.00
CORRUP80 -0.07 -0.22 1.00
CORRUP90 -0.84 -0.13 0.73 1.00
ECO 0.62 0.21 -0.83 -0.79 1.00
NOTES: INV: investment; GDP75: initial GDP: CORRUP80: corruption level
in the 1980s; CORRUP90: corruption level in the 1990s; LAW: index of
judicial efficiency; SECE: secondary school enrollment rate in 1975;
GOV: government expenditure share of the GDP; POL: index of political
freedom; GPOP: population growth rate; ETHNICITY: index of
ethnolinguistic fractionalization; STATE: the type of the state
(federal vs. unitary state); ECO: economic freedom.
TABLE 2
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS FOR THE REGRESSION VARIABLES
Standard Obser-
Mean Median Deviation Maximum Minimum vations
RPGDP 1.028 1.236 2.462 7.206 -6.314 114
INV 0.223 0.226 0.066 0.421 0.087 116
GPOP 2.025 2.478 1.179 5.219 -0.148 118
GDP75 3.068 2.000 3.414 23.00 0.000 118
SECE 0.199 0.120 0.209 0.860 0.001 118
POL 0.373 0.330 0.486 1.000 0.000 117
GOV 1.806 1.013 3.498 18.36 -4.437 114
ETHNICITY 0.399 0.370 0.302 0.930 0.000 117
LAW 7.162 7.000 2.230 10.00 2.000 68
STATE 0.128 0.000 0.336 1.000 0.000 117
CORRUP80 5.211 6.342 3.271 10.00 0.000 86
CORRUP90 7.420 7.722 3.887 10.00 0.000 57
ECO 5.112 5.710 2.30 9.880 1.120 92
NOTES: RPGDP: real per capita GDP; other variables are defined in
Table 1.
TABLE 3
CORRUPTION, INSTITUTIONS, AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
RPGDP RPGDP
Independent RPGDP RPGDP 7585 9095
Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
C 4.784 7.828 5.849 -0.325
(5.595) (6.331) (6.616) (-1.54)
GPOP -0.0556 -0.1286 -0.1666
(-0.249) (-0.574) (-0.795)
GDP75 -0.456 -0.7976 -0.5813
(-3.508) (-4.683) (-4.243)
SECE 0.8063 -0.7727 0.5479
(0.576) (-0.497) (0.4007)
CORRUP80 -0.1853 -1.0282 -0.67
(-2.108) (-3.858) (-2.54)
CORRUP90 -0.4997
(-0.343)
AFRICA -2.8545 -2.4908 -2.339
(-5.582) (-5.553) (-5.6187)
LATIN -1.7975 -1.2879 -1.5571
AMERICA (-4.462) (-2.926) (-3.896)
SOCIALIST -0.9409 -0.7927 -0.7425
(-4.462) (-2.926) (-3.896)
RPGDP7585
LAW
GOV
AID
GOV*AID
POL
ETHNICITY
STATE
ECO
RPGDP
Sample 83 79 57 83
Method of Estimation OLS 2SLS OLS OLS
R-Squared 0.540 0.428 0.458 0.167
Independent CORRUP90 INV/GDP CORRUP90
Variables (5) (6) (7)
C -0.0656 0.1861 3.129
(-1.118) (5.042) (7.00)
GPOP
GDP75
SECE -0.508
(-2.158)
CORRUP80 -0.0738 -0.2621
(-1.196) (-6.024)
CORRUP90
AFRICA 0.3398
(1.129)
LATIN -0.0276
AMERICA -2.379)
SOCIALIST -1.109
(-2.379)
RPGDP7585 -0.072
(-0.91)
LAW -0.1813
GOV (-1.939)
0.1883
(2.912)
AID 0.6435
GOV*AID (1.880)
0.0237
(1.794)
POL -0.2302
(-0.471)
ETHNICITY -0.453
(-1.100)
STATE -0.2493
ECO (-1.848)
-0.269
RPGDP (-2.471)
-0.0362
(-0.694)
Sample 78 70 57
Method of Estimation OLS OLS OLS
R-Squared 0.01 0.051 0.913
NOTE: t-statistics are in parentheses.
TABLE 4
GRANGER-CAUSALITY TEST RESULTS
[[lambda].sub.a] [A.sub.1]
-0.034 (-2.62) -0.18 (-5.43) F-Statistic Prob.
3.14783 0.04988
[[lambda].sub.b] [A.sub.2]
-0.105 (-0.89) -0.06 (-1.07) F-Statistic Prob.
0.29241 0.74748
NOTE: [A.sub.1] = [[summation of].sub.k=1] [a.sub.2k], and
[A.sub.2] = [[summation of].sub.k=1] [a.sub.3k]; t-values are in
parentheses.
(1) The new empirical research on the determinants of corruption
attempts to determine the causes of corruption and concentrates mostly
on cross-country analyses. See, for example, the studies by Ades and
DiTella (1997); LaPorta et al. (1997); Treisman (1999a, 1999b); Fisman
and Gatti (1999); and Swamy et al. (2001).
(2) For a detailed description of the harmful effects of rent
seeking, see Krueger (1974), Buchanan, Tullock, and Tollison (1980), and
Bhagwati (1982).
(3) "Countries like Thailand and South Korea may have been
riddled with graft; their economies powered ahead regardless.
Italy's corruption did not stop it from drawing level with
relatively virtuous Britain in GDP per head. And, in states which
suppressed the normal workings of the market, bribery could sometimes
seem to be a blessing; it could release goods trapped at the border by a
corrupt customs officer, or set a price for a service the government had
foolishly offered for free" (The Economist, 1909: 50).
(4) The fact that corruption is pervasive in low-growth countries
of Africa and Latin America contradicts these arguments. Actually,
bribery gives corrupt bureaucrats an incentive to create more red tape
to extract bigger bribes and to extort more payments for the provision
of their services.
(5) For a detailed discussion of the control variables, see Levine
and Renelt (1992) and Barro (1996).
(6) In addition to ethnolinguistic fractionalization, we used other
measures of ethnic fragmentation. These include the percent of
population not speaking the official language, the percent of population
not speaking the most widely used language, and the probability that two
randomly selected individuals speak different languages. For a further
description of those variables, see Easterly and Levine (1997).
(7) Gwartney, Lawson, and Holcombe (1999) used this method to
evaluate the effect of economic freedom on growth.
References
Ades, A., and Di Tella, R. (1997) "The Causes and Consequences
of Corruption: A Review of Recent Empirical Contributions."
Institute of Development Studies Bulletin 27: 6-12.
Angrist, J. D., and Krueger, A. B. (2001) "Instrumental
Variables and the Search for Identification: From Supply and Demand to
Natural Experiments." Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(4):
69-85.
Bardhan, P. (1997) "Corruption and Development: A Review of
the Issues." Journal of Economic Literature 35: 1320-46.
Barro, R. (1996) "Determinants of Growth: A Cross-Country
Empirical Study." NBER Working Paper No. 5698.
Barro, R., and Lee, J. (1993) "International Comparisons of
Educational Attainment." Journal of Monetary Economics 32: 363-94.
Bhagwati, J. N. (1982) "Directly Unproductive Profit-Seeking
(DUP) Activities." Journal of Political Economy 90: 988-1002.
Buchanan, J. M.; Tullock G.; and Tollison, R., eds. (1980) Toward a
Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. College Station: Texas A & M
University Press.
Campos, J. E.; Lien, D.; and Pradhan, S. (1999) "The Impact of
Corruption on Investment: Predictability Matters." World
Development 27 (6): 105967.
Cheung, S. N. (1996) "Simplistic General Equilibrium Theory of
Corruption." Contemporary Economic Policy 14 (3): 1-5.
Easterly, W., and Levine R. (1997) "Africa's Growth
Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 112(4) 1203-50.
The Economist (1999) "Honest Trade: A Global War Against
Bribery." 16 January: 50.
Fisman, R., and Gatti R. (1999) "Decentralization and
Corruption: Cross-Country and Cross-State Evidence." Unpublished
manuscript. Washington: World Bank.
Gwartney, J., and Lawson, R. (1997) Economic Freedom of the World:
1997 Report. Vancouver, B.C.: Fraser Institute.
Gwartney, J.; Lawson, R.; and Holcombe, R. G. (1999) "Economic
Freedom and the Environment for Economic Growth." Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics 155: 642-63.
Klitgaard, R. (1988) Controlling Corruption. Berkeley: University
of California Press.
Knack, S., and Keefer, P. (1995) "Institutions and Economic
Performance: Cross-Country Tests of Alternative Institutional
Measures." Economics and Politics 7: 207-27.
Krueger, A. O. (1974) "The Political Economy of the
Rent-Seeking Society." American Economic Review 64: 291-303.
La Porta, R.; Lopez-De-Silanes, F.; Shleifer, A.; and Vishny, R.
(1997)"Trust in Large Organizations." American Economic Review
137(2): 333-38.
-- (1999) "The Quality of Government." Journal of Law,
Economics and Organization 15 (1): 222-79.
Left, N. H. (1964) "Economic Development Through Bureaucratic
Corruption." American Behavioral Scientist 8(3): 8-14.
-- (1979) "Entrepreneurship and Economic Development: The
Problem Revisisted." Journal of Economic Literature 17 (March):
46-64.
Levine, R., and Renelt, D. (1992) "A Sensitivity Analysis of
Cross-Country Growth Regressions." American Economic Review 82:
942-96.
Lui, F. T. (1996) "Three Aspects of Corruption."
Contemporary Economic Policy 14(3): 26-29.
Mauro, P. (1995)"Corruption and Growth." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 109: 681-712.
Shleifer, A., and Vishny R. (1993) "Corruption."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3): 599-617.
Scott, J. C. (1972) Comparative Political Corruption. Englewood
Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
Swamy, A.; Knack, S.; Lee, Y.; and Azfar, O. (2001) "Gender
and Corruption." Journal of Development Economics 64: 25-55.
Treisman, D. (1999a) "The Causes of Corruption: A
Cross-National Study." Unpublished manuscript, UCLA.
-- (1999b) "Decentralization and Corruption: Why Are Federal
States Perceived to be More Corrupt?" Paper prepared for the Annual
Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta
(September).
Tullock, G. (1996) "Corruption Theory and Practice."
Contemporary Economic Policy 14(3): 6-13.
Wedeman, A. (1996) "Looters, Rent-Scrappers, and Dividend
Collectors: The Political Economy of Corruption in Zaire, South Korea,
and the Philippines." Paper presented at the 1996 Annual Meeting of
the American Political Science Association, San Francisco (August).
Cato Journal, Vol. 22, No. 3 (Winter 2003). Copyright [C] Cato
Institute. All rights reserved.
Abdiweli M. Ali and Hodan Said Isse are economists with the
Commonwealth of Virginia and the Beydan Institute for Research and
Development. They thank W. Mark Crain, Gareth Davis, Bill Peach, and G.
Chris Rodrigo for helpful comments.