Monetary policy in a world of mobile capital.
Bernanke, Ben
The free movement of capital across borders has created, and will
certainly continue to create, enormous economic benefits. Capital flows
afford developing countries and other regions the means to exploit
promising investment opportunities while providing savers around the
globe the means both to earn higher returns and to reduce risk through
international portfolio diversification. Access to international capital
markets also permits nations to accumulate foreign assets in good times
and to deplete those assets or to borrow in bad times, mitigating the
effects on living standards of shocks to domestic income and production.
In recent years, global capital flows have attained record highs
relative to global income, reflecting both the powerful tendency of
capital to seek the highest return and a concerted international effort
to dismantle political and regulatory barriers to capital mobility.
In this article, I address the role of monetary policy,
particularly the choice of the exchange rate regime, in enabling
economies to take maximum advantage of the increasing openness and depth
of international capital markets.
The Trilemma
The discussion of monetary policy and capital flows almost
inevitably begins with the well-known trilemma, the observation that a
country can choose no more than two of the following three features of
its policy regime: (1) free capital mobility across borders, (2) a fixed
exchange rate, and (3) an independent monetary policy. (1) Various
combinations of these features have dominated world monetary
arrangements in different eras. Under the classical gold standard of the
19th century, the major trading countries chose the benefits of free
capital flows and the perceived stability of a fixed relation of their
currency to gold; of necessity, then, they largely abjured independent
monetary policies. Under the Bretton Woods system created at the end of
World War II, many countries renounced capital mobility in an attempt to
maintain both fixed exchange rates and monetary independence. Currently,
among the major industrial regions at least, we have collectively chosen
a regime that gives up fixed exchange rates in favor of the other two
elements.
The Case for Floating Exchange Rates
Is the international monetary regime that is in place today the
best one for the world? For the economically advanced nations that use
the world's three key currencies--the euro, the yen, and the
dollar--I believe that the benefits of independent monetary policies and
capital mobility greatly exceed whatever costs may result from a regime
of floating exchange rates. My view is widely, though not universally,
shared among economists and policymakers. In particular, what was once
viewed as the principal objection to floating exchange rates, that their
adoption would leave the system bereft of a nominal anchor, has proven
to be unfounded. Most countries today, including many emerging market
and developing nations as well as the advanced industrial countries,
have succeeded in establishing a commitment to keeping domestic
inflation low and stable, a commitment that has served effectively as a
nominal anchor.
A newer critique of floating exchange rates contends that exchange
rates are more volatile than can be explained by the macroeconomic fundamentals and, moreover, that this excess volatility has in some
cases inhibited international trade (Flood and Rose 1995, Rose 2000,
Klein and Shambaugh 2004). Like other asset prices, floating exchange
rates do indeed exhibit a great deal of volatility in the very short
term, responding to many types of economic news and, sometimes it seems,
to no news at all. Whether this very short-term volatility is excessive
relative to fundamentals (which are inherently difficult to observe and
measure) is debatable. In any ease, this short-term volatility seems
unlikely to have substantial effects on trade or capital flows, because
short-term fluctuations in exchange rates are easily hedged.
Exchange rates also exhibit long-horizon volatility, of course;
but, although the swings in the exchange value of the dollar over the
past 30 years have been large, so have been the changes in the global
macroeconomic environment. As key components of the international
adjustment mechanism, fluctuations in exchange rates and the associated
financial flows have often played an important stabilizing role. For
example, the sharp rise in the dollar in the late 1990s reflected to an
important degree a surge in U.S. productivity growth, which raised
perceived rates of return and attracted significant inflows of capital.
The capital inflows, the stronger dollar, and the associated rise in
imports worked together to permit increased capital investment in the
United States during that period, enabling production and incomes to
grow without overheating the economy or requiring a sustained rise in
interest rates. The value of floating exchange rates as shock absorbers
might make their adoption worthwhile even if their volatility did have a
chilling effect on trade. However, the sharp rise in trade volumes
relative to world gross domestic product in recent decades suggests to
me that, at least for the world as a whole, any such chilling effect has
likely been minor.
The presumption in favor of allowing the market to determine the
exchange rates among the major currencies is strengthened by the fact
that a consensus about the appropriate levels at which to peg these
currencies would be difficult to obtain. A poor choice of the rates at
which currencies would trade could condemn one or more regions to
unwanted inflation and the other regions to economic stagnation for a
transition period that could easily last several years. The United
Kingdom suffered the consequences of a poor choice of peg when it
returned to the gold standard after World War I, because an overvalued pound reduced British exports and significantly worsened the
country's unemployment problem. The United Kingdom faced analogous
problems 65 years later, when it entered the European exchange rate
mechanism (ERM) in 1990 at a parity that again disadvantaged British
exports and contributed to Great Britain's worst recession in the
past 20 years. Nor were these macroeconomic costs compensated for by
greater external stability; in both episodes, doubts about the
sustainability of the peg generated speculative attacks that ultimately
forced the pound off its fixed rate.
Overall, the case for floating exchange rates among the United
States, Japan, and the euro zone seems to me to be compelling. For
smaller industrial countries, the case for floating rates may in some
instances be less clear-cut, for example, when the bulk of a
country's trade is with a single, large trading partner. Generally,
though, my sense is that the benefits of floating exchange rates exceed
the costs for these countries as well.
Resolving the Trilemma for Developing Countries
Much more controversial is the question of how developing and
emerging market countries should resolve the trilemma. Some might argue
against these countries' choosing to allow free capital mobility on
the grounds that rapid reversals in international capital flows have
induced balance-of-payments crises and difficult domestic adjustments
for them in the past. But even those most concerned about potential
instability in international capital flows would have to admit that
comprehensive capital controls, if applied for any extended period,
might solve one problem at the cost of creating a more serious
one--namely, the inhibition of growth and development that occurs when
nations lack access to international capital markets. At best, then,
restrictions on capital mobility should be viewed as a temporary
expedient, a second-best or third-best solution to the problems
presented by flawed or immature institutions in a nation at early or
intermediate stages of development. In the medium run, the better
approach--admittedly, one not always so easy to implement--is to commit
to making the nation's legal, regulatory, and fiscal framework
stronger and more transparent. If foreign investors are thus reassured
that their capital will be employed efficiently and its returns
repatriated smoothly, the risks of capital flow reversals under a regime
of free capital mobility should be much reduced.
If we agree that every country should set a goal of achieving at
least some degree of capital mobility, then the trilemma for developing
countries ultimately boils down to the choice between flexible exchange
rates (and the associated independence of monetary policy) and fixed
rates (which do not allow monetary independence). In the remainder of
this article I will focus on that choice. I should acknowledge
immediately that to state the choice as one of "fixed versus
floating" is to oversimplify. Both regimes are actually broad
categories, each of which contains a number of variants. Fixed exchange
rates are almost never irrevocably fixed. For example, crawling pegs
allow the rate to be adjusted in a controlled manner, while some
putatively fixed rates are actually reset at frequent intervals, either
as an instrument of policy or under external pressure. So-called hard
pegs, including currency boards and dollarization, may draw credibility
from various institutional impediments to changing the rate; but even
full dollarization can be reversed, as Liberia proved in 1982. (2)
Floating exchange rates cover an even wider range of policy behavior
than fixed rates--from full reliance on the foreign exchange market for
the determination of the exchange rate to a carefully managed float.
So what should developing countries do about the exchange rate?
Theory suggests that any group of countries whose economic structures
and trade linkages satisfy the requirements of an optimum currency area,
in the sense of Mundell (1961), would be well served by fixing the
exchange rates among their currencies or, even better, by forming a
currency union. (3) However, in practice, empirical analyses have
generally been unsuccessful at identifying multicountry regions of any
size that meet the criteria for an optimum currency area. Indeed, some
studies have concluded that even the United States and the European
Union, the largest currency unions, are themselves not optimum currency
areas. (4) Plausibly, political rather than economic
considerations--namely, the desire to form a more perfect
union--underlay the decisions of each of these entities to adopt a
common currency.
European economic integration has been motivated to a significant
degree by a desire to make a repeat of the destructive conflicts of the
20th century impossible. In the fledgling United States, the desire to
strengthen the central government was a principal reason behind
Alexander Hamilton's advocacy of a common currency and common
national debt. Recent research has pointed out the interesting
possibility that the formation of a currency union, by promoting trade
and economic integration among its members, may lead the criteria for an
optimum currency area among the participating countries to be satisfied
after the fact even if not before (Frankel and Rose 2002). Of course, to
justify a currency union on this basis requires the ability to forecast
how linkages among the participants will evolve under the common
currency--a difficult undertaking indeed.
Besides countries well-suited for a currency union, a second group
of countries that might conceivably be better off with a fixed exchange
rate, at least for a time, are the very poorest and least developed
countries that may lack the institutional infrastructure to effectively
operate an independent monetary policy. In these countries, a hard peg
or even the adoption of the currency of a major trading
partner--sometimes known as dollarization, although the term also refers
to cases in which the currency adopted is one other than the dollar--may
be policy options worth considering. (I want to be clear that I am
speaking generally and am not advocating that other countries adopt the
U.S. currency.) Although dollarization has the advantage of making
monetary policy essentially automatic and should be an effective device
for controlling inflation, one is struck by the fact that so few
countries have chosen this approach. Costs of dollarization include the
loss of revenue from money creation and the reduced ability of the
central bank to serve as a lender of last resort. But perhaps the most
important impediment to dollarization is that, in giving up their own
currency, the country's citizens may feel that they are losing an
important symbol of their nation's sovereignty and pride.
For other developing and emerging market countries, I would argue
that the best course is generally to let the exchange rate float freely
and to make low and stable inflation a principal focus of monetary
policy. As I have already suggested, this approach makes the targeted
inflation rate, and not the exchange rate or some other variable, the
nominal anchor of the system. An important reason for making the
inflation rate (more precisely, the price level) the nominal anchor is
that the general price level is more directly linked to economic welfare
than is the exchange rate. Domestic price stability improves the
operation of markets, reduces the costs associated with economizing on
money holdings and with changing prices, lessens distortions associated
with imperfect indexing of the tax system and the accounting system, and
aids long-term planning. As I have also already noted, concerns about
the feasibility of this approach have been put to rest by the experience
of the past decade or so. Central banks in many countries, with either
an explicit or an implicit inflation target, have demonstrated the
capacity to keep inflation low and stable. Indeed, recent research
suggests that the combination of an inflation target, central bank
independence, and a market-determined exchange rate tends to reduce
variability in both inflation and output, even in small open economies
such as Finland and New Zealand (Truman 2003). To be clear, a focus on
domestic inflation does not imply that policymakers must entirely ignore
the exchange rate; particularly in small open economics, stabilization
of the domestic price level may entail some "leaning against the
wind" with respect to exchange rate movements because of their
influence on domestic prices. This behavior does not imply that exchange
rate stabilization is an independent objective, however, and should
price stability and exchange rate stability come into conflict, it is
the latter that should be jettisoned.
In contrast to floating rates, fixed exchange rates--rather than
being a mechanism for reducing macroeconomic instability--have often
been a source of instability. Historically, governments have often
defended their fixed parity even after the overvaluation of the exchange
rate became obvious, leading to losses of foreign exchange reserves, a
balance-of-payments crisis, and difficult domestic adjustments. Some
observers have suggested that the solution to this problem is to tie the
government's hands even more forcefully by imposing a harder
peg--for example, by means of a currency board or dollarization. But
market participants know that promises to maintain a fixed rate are
almost never irrevocable, and so a speculative attack is always possible
(as Argentina recently learned, for example). Another strategy for
deterring speculative attacks on a fixed exchange rate is to build a
"war chest" of foreign currency reserves. To be effective in
today's world of highly mobile capital, the war chest may have to
be sizable indeed; and for countries with large government debts and
high domestic interest rates, holding great quantities of low-yielding
reserves can have serious fiscal consequences. In any case, strategies
to increase the defensibility of the peg ignore the broader issue of the
role of the exchange rate in macroeconomic adjustment. For an individual
country, forcing adjustment to a misvalued exchange rate through
domestic price changes is likely to be far more difficult and costly
than an adjustment occurring through exchange rate depreciation or
appreciation. For the world as a whole, macroeconomic adjustment may
likewise be impeded if economically important countries attempt to
maintain pegs at levels that differ from those dictated by fundamentals.
If fixed exchange rates bear such risks, what explains their
continued existence? One traditional argument in favor of fixed exchange
rates for developing countries focuses on their usefulness in so-called
heterodox programs for overcoming high inflation. (5) According to this
view, the advantage of fixing the exchange rate as one element of an
anti-inflation program (along with fiscal reforms and other policy
changes) is that fixing the rate is more visible, more credible, and
easier to explain than a commitment to stabilizing prices directly. Even
if we grant a role for a fixed exchange rate in combating high
inflation, however, this argument provides no rationale for fixing the
rate indefinitely. If the program is successful and the inflationary
psychology is broken, nothing prevents a transition from targeting the
exchange rate to targeting inflation. Two countries with chronic
inflation problems, Argentina and Brazil, did not experience a sustained
resurgence of high inflation when they abandoned fixed rates in recent
years. Brazil now targets inflation, and by some reports Argentina has
considered the option. Israel broke the back of its hyperinflation in
the mid-1980s with the aid of a fixed exchange rate but then made a
gradual and successful transition to inflation targeting. And, of
course, this argument provides no rationale for the use of fixed
exchange rates by countries, such as the East Asian emerging market
countries, that have not experienced episodes of high inflation.
An interesting recent explanation for the continued existence of
fixed exchange rates is the so-called fear-of-floating phenomenon (Calvo
and Reinhart 2000). According to this view, the poor credibility of
policymakers in some countries implies that the exchange rate, if left
unmanaged, would prove excessively volatile. High exchange rate
volatility could prove very harmful in these countries, for at least two
reasons. First, the openness of these economies to trade, coupled with
the fact that the exchange rate may serve as a focal point for inflation
expectations, may imply that exchange rate volatility translates quickly
into instability in consumer prices. Second, because firms and
households in these countries often borrow in foreign currencies but
receive revenues and incomes in the domestic currency, swings in the
exchange rate have major effects on the net worth of these borrowers. In
particular, a sharp devaluation, by raising the value of foreign
liabilities relative to domestic assets, might bankrupt large segments
of the economy, with severe financial and economic implications.
According to the fear-of-floating hypothesis, the severe consequences of
exchange rate volatility in these countries may lead policymakers to
manage their currencies quite closely to damp volatility, no matter what
the putative exchange rate regime.
If we assume that the fear-of-floating hypothesis accurately
describes behavior, what are the implications? Some have argued that,
given the unwillingness to float, countries would be better off
dollarizing or taking other measures to achieve a hard peg. This
approach would have the benefits (the argument goes) of making explicit
the country's implicit policy, making a disruptive devaluation less
likely, and, consequently, possibly reducing the risk premium that
borrowers in the country must pay to borrow abroad. I have already
expressed reservations about so-called hard pegs for developing
countries: Though less so than conventional pegs, they remain subject to
speculative attacks, and they may make domestic macroeconomic adjustment
more difficult. They also constrain the central bank's ability to
act as a lender of last resort in the event of a banking crisis.
Moreover, the small amount of available evidence does not favor the view
that a hard peg will significantly reduce the risk premium a country
must pay on international loans; for example, the dollarized nations of
El Salvador and Panama do not appear to be paying lower interest rate
premiums on their debt than other similarly situated countries.
Furthermore, to the extent that a hard peg encourages foreign-currency
borrowing, the costs of devaluation, should it come, may be greatly
increased.
One may also question whether the fear of floating is a permanent
and irremediable condition. An important underpinning of the
fear-of-floating argument is the idea that borrowing and lending in
international capital markets must take place only in a few key
currencies, condemning most countries to borrow in a currency other than
their own and exposing them to heavy losses in the event of a
devaluation (Eichengreen and Hausman 1999). In addition, because of
creditor mistrust, the borrowing that does take place must be mostly in
short-maturity instruments, greatly increasing the risk of a liquidity
crisis. Continuing the tradition of colorful nomenclature in
international economics, this hypothesis has been labeled "original
sin" because the need to borrow in foreign currencies and in
short-maturity instruments supposedly constrains all but the largest and
wealthiest countries regardless of economic policies and performance.
However, recent developments in international capital markets challenge
the inevitability of "original sin" (Eichengreen, Hausman, and
Panizza 2003; Burger and Warnock 2004). First, some small countries have
in fact been able to sell domestic-currency debt to foreigners (examples
include New Zealand, Poland, and South Africa). Second, some developing
countries have been able to establish active domestic credit markets in
which borrowing may take place in long-term, fixed-rate debt, providing
a partial substitute for foreign-currency borrowing (examples include
Chile, India, and Korea). In both situations, the quality of the
country's macroeconomic policies as well as the strength and
transparency of its institutional framework have been critically
important for improving the access of borrowers to capital. Redemption
from "original sin" through good works may thus be possible.
These experiences suggest that, whatever interim arrangements they adopt
regarding exchange rates and capital mobility, developing countries
would do well to shift their focus to the task of building institutions,
protecting property rights, and establishing a sound fiscal and monetary
framework, with the ultimate goal of making free capital flows and a
floating exchange rate feasible.
The Bipolar View
In the wake of the Asian crisis, the conventional wisdom asserted
that a country should eschew fixed exchange rates in favor of either of
the two extremes: a floating rate or a currency union. I agree with this
"bipolar view" insofar as I think that a garden-variety fixed
exchange rate is, in most instances, the worst of all worlds. Notably,
fixed exchange rates often result in irresistible one-way bets for
speculators, with crisis and painful economic adjustment the likely
result. Large holdings of foreign exchange reserves reduce this risk but
create other costs. Currency unions are considerably less prone to
speculative attack and may reduce uncertainty and transactions costs in
international trade and finance. But, as I have indicated, I believe
that floating exchange rates are generally to be preferred either to
fixed exchange rates or--except in those relatively rare cases in which
the criteria for an optimum currency area are met--to currency unions.
This view seems to be spreading. According to the International
Monetary Fund (2004), for example, inflation-targeting countries are
becoming more numerous as countries that fix the exchange rate become
fewer. (6) Consistent with this observation, average inflation rates in
both industrial and developing countries are near their lowest levels in
four decades, reflecting the new emphasis in policy. Politicians and
policymakers around the world are being converted to the idea that
monetary policy should focus on delivering low and stable inflation,
with the determination of exchange rates left to free markets.
Increasing Capital Freedom
The most consequential exception to the general trend toward
inflation stabilization, free capital markets, and floating exchange
rates is, of course, China. China currently has relatively strict,
though not absolutely impermeable, barriers to capital flows, as well as
an exchange rate that is effectively pegged to the U.S. dollar. The
governments of the United States and the other G-7 countries have urged
China to make the transition to a market-determined exchange rate in the
interest of promoting global macroeconomic adjustment. I will add here
only that moving toward exchange rate flexibility is in the interest of
China as well as the rest of the world. As a large, increasingly
wealthy, and increasingly market-oriented economy, China will benefit
from the shock-absorber properties of an independent monetary policy and
a floating exchange rate. Because it needs capital to fuel its rapid
growth and because its citizens would benefit greatly from the
opportunity to invest their own savings abroad, China will likewise
benefit from increased capital freedom. Finally, the institutional
developments needed to support ever more open capital markets, including
a strengthened legal and regulatory framework, an increased capacity of
its banks to allocate capital to the most productive uses, and a reduced
role of the government in investment decisions, are themselves necessary
and important steps in China's economic modernization.
The United States will also benefit as China and other East Asian
countries make the transition to floating exchange rates and freer
capital flows. More open capital accounts and market-determined exchange
rates will likely engender greater stability and improved resource
allocation in Asia, setting the stage for sustained future growth. The
development of the Asian economies will expand export markets for U.S.
producers, particularly as independent monetary policies and
institutional reform provide scope for stimulating demand by Asian
households and firms. Some observers have expressed concern about the
effects of reduced reserve accumulation by Asian central banks on U.S.
bond markets; however, the U.S. bond market is extremely deep and has
shown a remarkable capacity to handle transitions smoothly, particularly
when they occur in a gradual and predictable manner. Moreover, under a
regime of free capital mobility, private savers in China and the rest of
East Asia may well wish to diversify into U.S. assets, including U.S.
bonds.
Conclusion
I have argued for an international system based on the principles
of flexible exchange rates, free capital mobility, and independent
monetary policies, at least within the great majority of countries.
Important complementary elements include free trade and the further
development of the "soft" infrastructure--the legal,
regulatory, fiscal, and financial frameworks that characterize advanced
economies. The fundamental virtue of this system is its flexibility and
adaptability--qualities that will become increasingly essential in a
complex and interdependent world.
(1) Obstfeld, Shambaugh, and Taylor (2004) provide historical
evidence that supports the empirical relevance of the trilemma.
(2) When the parity is nominally fixed but can be varied, and if
capital flows are less than perfectly free, monetary policy under a
fixed exchange rate may have a degree of independence; thus, the
resolution of the trilemma may not be a stark choice of two of the three
elements but a partial adoption of each.
(3) An optimum currency area is a region in which labor and capital
are internally mobile and subregions tend to be affected by similar
shocks. As Mundell (1961) first argued, in this situation the
shock-absorbing benefits of flexible exchange rates are outweighed by
the reduction in transactions costs and in uncertainty provided by fixed
exchange rates or a common currency.
(4) See, for example, Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1993) and Ghosh and
Wolf (1994).
(5) Sargent (1982) notes the role of exchange rate stabilization in
ending the European hyperinflations of the 1920s. Analysts of more
recent stabilization programs in developing countries have observed that
even if exchange rate-based policies succeed in reducing inflation
initially, fixing the exchange rate may lead to subsequent problems
(Vegh 1992, Dornbusch and Warner 1994).
(6) Reinhart and Rogoff (2002) argue that the move away from pegs
is less pronounced in terms of actual policy behavior than in terms of
official classifications. Their point is an important one. However, they
do not dispute the direction of the change; and, as their analysis
compares 1991-2001 with earlier periods, they miss a very recent
acceleration toward floating exchange rates and inflation-focused
monetary policies.
References
Bayoumi, T, and Eichengreen, B. (1993) "Shocking Aspects of
European Monetary Integration." In G. Torres and F. Giavazzi (eds.)
Adjustment and Growth in European Monetary Union. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge University Press.
Burger, J., and Warnock, F. (2004) "Foreign Participation in
Local-Currency Bond Markets." Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Paper No. 794.
Calvo, G., and Reinhart, C. (2000) "Fear of Floating."
NBER Working Paper No. 7993.
Dornbusch, R., and Warner, A. (1994) "Mexico: Stabilization,
Reform, and No Growth." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No
1: 253-315.
Eichengreen, B., and Hausman, R. (1999) "Exchange Rates and
Financial Fragility." In Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, New
Challenges for Monetary Policy.
Eichengreen, B.; Hausman, R.; and Panizza, U. (2003) "Currency
Mismatches, Debt Intolerance, and Original Sin: Why They Are Not the
Same and Why It Matters." NBER Working Paper No. 10036.
Flood, R., and Rose, A. (1995) "Fixing Exchange Rates: A
Virtual Quest for Fundamentals." Journal of Monetary Economics 36:
3-37.
Frankel, J., and Rose, A. (2002) "An Estimate of the Effect of
Common Currencies on Trade and Growth." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 117: 437-66.
Ghosh, A., and Wolf, H. (1994) "How Many Monies? A Genetic
Approach to Finding Optimum Currency Areas." NBER Working Paper No.
4805.
International Monetary Fund (2004) World Economic Outlook, October.
Klein, M., and Shambaugh, J. (2004) "Fixed Exchange Rates and
Trade." Working Paper, Tufts University.
Mundell, R. (1961) "A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas."
American Economic Review 51: 657-65.
Obstfeld, M.; Shambaugh, J.; and Taylor, A. (2004) "The
Trilemma in History: Tradeoffs among Exchange Rates, Monetary Policies,
and Capital Mobility." NBER Working Paper No. 10396.
Reinhart, C., and Rogoff, K. (2002) "The Modern History of
Exchange Rate Arrangements: A Reinterpretation." NBER Working Paper
No. 8963.
Rose, A. (2000) "One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect
of Common Currencies on Trade." Economic Policy 30: 7-46.
Sargent, T. (1982) "The Ends of Four Big Inflations." In
R. Hall (ed.) Inflation: Causes and Effects. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Truman, E. (2003) Inflation Targeting. Washington: Institute for
International Economics.
Vegh, C. (1992) "Stopping High Inflation: An Analytical
Overview." IMF Staff Papers 39: 626-95.
Ben S. Bernanke is a member of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. This article is adapted from his keynote address at the Cato Institute's 22nd Annual Monetary Conference,
cosponsored by The Economist, Washington, D.C., October 14, 2004. The
author thanks Board staff members Joseph Gallon and Steven Kamin for
their excellent assistance in the preparation of his conference paper.
The views ex-pressed in this article are the author's and are not
necessarily shared by his colleagues at the Federal Reserve.8