Monetary misjudgments and malfeasance.
Hanke, Steve H.
The Federal Reserve has a long history of creating aggregate demand
bubbles in the United States (Niskanen 2003, 2006). In the ramp up to
the Lehman Brothers" bankruptcy in September 2008, the Fed not only
created a classic aggregate demand bubble, but also facilitated the
spawning of many market-specific bubbles. The bubbles in the housing,
equity, and commodity markets could have been easily detected by
observing the price behavior in those markets, relative to changes in
the more broadly based consumer price index. True to form, the Fed
officials have steadfastly denied any culpability for creating the
bubbles that so spectacularly burst during the Panic of 2008-09.
If all that is not enough, Fed officials, as well as other members
of the money and banking establishments in the United States and
elsewhere, have embraced the idea that stronger, more heavily
capitalized banks are necessary to protect taxpayers from future
financial storms. This embrace, which is reflected in the Bank for
International Settlements' most recent capital requirement regime
(Basel III) and related country-specific capital requirement mandates,
represents yet another great monetary misjudgment (error). Indeed, in
its stampede to make banks "safer," the establishment has
paradoxically rendered the economies of the Eurozone, the United
Kingdom, and the United States--among others--weaker and, therefore,
less "safe" (Hanke 2011).
Aggregate Demand Bubbles
Just what is an aggregate demand bubble? This type of bubble is
created when the Fed's laxity allows aggregate demand to grow too
rapidly, Specifically, an aggregate demand bubble occurs when nominal
final sales to U.S. purchasers (GDP - exports + imports change in
inventories) exceed a trend rate of nominal growth consistent with
"moderate" inflation by a significant amount.
During the 24 years of the Greenspan-Bernanke reign at the Fed,
nominal final sales grew at a 5.2 percent annual trend rate. This
reflects a combination of real sales growth of 3 percent and inflation
of 2.2 percent (Figure 1). But, there were deviations from the trend.
The first deviation began shortly after Man Greenspan became
chairman of the Fed. In response to the October 1987 stock market crash,
the Fed turned on its money pump and created an aggregate demand bubble:
over the next year, final sales shot up at a 7.5 percent rate, well
above the trend line. Having gone too far, the Fed then lurched back in
the other direction. The ensuing Fed tightening produced a mild
recession in 1991.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
During the 1992-97 period, growth in the nominal value of final
sales was quite stable. But, successive collapses of certain Asian
currencies, the Russian ruble, the Long-Term Capital Management hedge
fund, and the Brazilian real triggered another excessive Fed liquidity
injection. This monetary misjudgment resulted in a boom in nominal final
sales and an aggregate demand bubble in 1999-2000. That bubble was
followed by another round of Fed tightening, which coincided with the
bursting of the equity bubble in 9.000 and a slump in 2001.
The last big jump in nominal final sales was set off by the
Fed's liquidity injection to fend off the false deflation scare in
2002 (Beckworth 2008). Fed Governor Ben S. Bernanke (now chairman) set
off a warning siren that deflation was threatening the U.S. economy when
he delivered a dense and noteworthy speech before the National
Economists Club on November 21, 2002 (Bernanke 2002). Bernanke convinced
his Fed colleagues that the deflation danger was lurking. As Greenspan
put it, "We face new challenges in maintaining price stability,
specifically to prevent inflation from falling too low" (Greenspan
2003). To fight the alleged deflation threat, the Fed pushed interest
rates down sharply. By July 2003, the Fed funds rate was at a
then-record low of 1 percent, where it stayed for a year. This easing
produced the mother of all liquidity cycles and yet another massive
demand bubble.
During the Greenspan-Beruanke years, and contrary to their claims,
the Fed overreacted to real or perceived crises and created three demand
bubbles. The last represents one bubble too many-and one that is
impacting us today.
Market-Specific Bubbles
The most recent aggregate demand bubble was not the only bubble
that the Fed was facilitating. As Figure 2 shows, the Fed's
favorite inflation target the consumer price index, absent food and
energy prices--was increasing at a regular, modest rate. Over the
2003-08 (Q3) period, this metric increased by 12.5 percent.
The Fed's inflation metric signaled "no problems."
But, abrupt shifts in major relative prices were underfoot. Housing
prices, measured by the Case-Shiller home price index, were surging,
increasing by 45 percent from the first quarter in 2003 until their peak
in the first quarter of 2006. Share prices were also on a tear,
increasing by 66 percent from the first quarter of 2003 until they
peaked in the first quarter of 2008.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The most dramatic price increases were in the commodities, however.
Measured by the Commodity Research Bureau's spot index, commodity
prices increased by 92 percent from the first quarter of 2003 to their
pre-Lehman Brothers peak in the second quarter of 2008.
The dramatic jump in commodity prices was due, in large part, to
the fact that a weak dollar accompanied the mother of all liquidity
cycles. Measured by the Federal Reserve's Trade Weighted Exchange
Index for major currencies, the greenback fell in value by 30.5 percent
from 2003 to mid-July 2008, As every commodity trader knows, all
commodities, to varying degrees, trade off changes in the value of the
dollar. When the value of the dollar falls, the nominal dollar prices of
internationally traded commodities--like gold, rice, corn, and oil must
increase because more dollars are required to purchase the same quantity
of any commodity.
Indeed, in my July 2008 testimony before the House Budget Committee
on "Rising Food Prices: Budget Challenges," I estimated that
the weak dollar was the major contributor to what then, only a few
months before the collapse of Lehman Brothers, was viewed as the
world's most urgent economic problem: world-record commodity
prices. My estimates of the depreciating dollar's contribution to
surging commodity prices over the 2002-July 2008 period was 51 percent
for etude oil and 55.5 percent for rough flee, two commodities that set
record-high prices (nominal) in July 2008 (Hanke 2008).
Before leaving the market-specific bubbles, two points merit
mention. First, the relative increase in housing prices was clearly
signaling a bubble in which prices were diverging from housing's
fundamentals, A simple "back-of-the-envelope" calculation
confirms a bubble. The so-called demographic "demand" for
housing in the U.S. during the first decade of the 21st century was
about 1.5 million units per year. This includes purchases of first homes
by newly formed families, purchases of second homes, and the replacement
of about 300,000 units per year that have been lost to fire, floods,
widening of highways, and so forth (Aliber 2010). During the bubble
years 2002-06, housing starts were two million per year. In consequence,
an "excess supply" of about 500,000 units, or 25 percent of
the annual new starts, was being created each year. These data suggest
that housing prices in the 2002-06 period should have been very weak, or
declining. Instead, they increased by 45 percent. The Fed, even
according to the minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee of June
2005, failed to spot what was an all-too obvious housing bubble (Harding
2011).
A second point worth mentioning is that, while operating under a
regime of inflation targeting and a floating U.S. dollar exchange rate,
Chairman Bernanke has seen fit to ignore fluctuations in the value of
the dollar. Indeed, changes in the dollar's exchange value do not
appear as one of the six metrics on "Bernanke's
Dashboard" the one the chairman uses to gauge the appropriateness
of monetary policy (Wessel 2009: 271). Perhaps this explains why
Bernanke has been dismissive of questions suggesting that changes in the
dollar's exchange value influence either commodity prices or more
broad gauges of inflation (MeKinnon 2010, Reddy and Blackstone 2011).
It is remarkable that the steep decline in the dollar during the
2002-July 2008 period and associated surge in commodity prices, the
subsequent surge in the dollar's value after Lehman Brothers
collapsed and associated plunge in commodity prices, and the renewed
decline in the dollar's exchange rate after the first quarter of
2009 and associated new surge in the CRB spot index (Figure 2) has left
Fed officials in denial. Indeed, they continue to be stubbornly blind to
the fact that there is a link between the dollar's exchange value
and commodity prices (Reddy and Blackstone 2011).
Malfeasance
For most masters of money, it is all about an inflation target. As
long as they hit a target, or come close to it, they are defended from
all sides by members of the establishment (Blinder 2010, Mankiw 2011).
It is as if nothing else matters. The deputy governor of the
world's first central bank (Sweden's Riksbank) and a
well-known pioneer of inflation targeting made clear what all the
inflation-targeting central bankers have in mind:
My view is that the crisis was largely caused by factors that had
very little to do with monetary policy. And my main conclusion for money
policy is that flexible inflation targeting--applied in the right way
and in particular using all the information about financial conditions
that is relevant for the forecast of inflation and resource utilization
at any horizon--remains the best-practice monetary policy before,
during, and after the financial crisis [Svensson 2010: 1].
For central bankers, the "name of the game" is to blame
someone else for the world's economic and financial troubles
(Bernanke 2010, Greenspan 2010). How can this be, particularly when
money is at the center?
To understand why the Fed's fantastic claims and denials are
rarely subjected to the indignity of empirical verification, we have to
look no further than the late Nobelist Milton Friedman. In a 1975 book
of essays in honor of Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom: Problems and
Prospects, Gordon Tullock (1975: 39-40) wrote:
It should be pointed out that a very large part of the information
available on most government issues originates within the
government. On several occasions in my hearing (I don't know
whether it is in his writing or not but I have heard him say this a
number of times) Milton Friedman has pointed out that one of the
basic reasons for the good press the Federal Reserve Board has had
for many years has been that the Federal Reserve Board is the
source of 98 percent of all writing on the Federal Reserve Board.
Most government agencies have this characteristic.
Friedman's assertion has subsequently been supported by
Lawrence H. White's research. In 2002, 74 percent of the articles
on monetary policy published by U.S. economists in U.S.-edited journals
appeared in Fed-sponsored publications, or were authored (or
co-authored) by Fed staff economists (White 2005, Grim 2009).
For powerful and uncompromising dissidents, the establishment can
impose what it deems to be severe penalties. For example, after the
distinguished monetarist and one of the founders of the Shadow Open
Market Committee Karl Brunner was perceived as a credible threat, he was
banned from entering the premises of the Federal Reserve headquarters in
Washington, D.C. Security guards were instructed to never allow Brunner
to enter the building. This all backfired. Indeed, the great Brunner
confided to Bill Barnett that the ban had done wonders for his career
(Barnett 2006: xiii). Alas, most money and banking professionals would,
unlike Brunner, find a Fed ban to be a burden they could not bear.
Misjudgments, Again
As part of the money and banking establishment's blame game,
the accusatory finger has been pointed at commercial bankers. The
establishment asserts that banks are too risky and dangerous because
they are "undercapitalized." It is, therefore, not surprising
that the Bank for International Settlements, located in Basel,
Switzerland, has issued new Basel III capital rules. These will bump
banks' capital requirements up from 4 percent to 7 percent of their
risk-weighted assets. And if that is not enough, the Basel Committee
agreed in late June to add a 2.5 percent surcharge on top of the 7
percent requirement for banks that are deemed too-big-to-fail. For some,
even these hurdles aren't high enough. The Swiss National Bank wants to impose an ultra-high 19 percent requirement on
Switzerland's two largest banks, UBS and Credit Suisse. In June,
the upper chamber of the Swiss Parliament approved that rate. In the
United States, officials from the Fed and the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation are also advocating capital surcharges for "big"
banks (Braithwaite and Simonian 2011).
The oracles of money and banking have demanded higher capital-asset
ratios for banks and that is exactly what they have received. Just look
at what has happened in the United States. Since the onset of the Panic
of 2008-09, U.S. banks have, under political pressure and in
anticipation of Basel III, increased their capital-asset ratios (Figure
3).
The oracles have erupted in cheers at the increased capital-asset
ratios. They assert that more capital has made the banks stronger and
safer. While at first glance that might strike one as a reasonable
conclusion, it is not (Dowd, Hutchinson, and Hinchliffe 2011).
For a bank, its assets (cash, loans, and securities) must equal its
liabilities (capital, bonds, and liabilities which the bank owes to its
shareholders and customers). In most countries, the bulk of a
bank's liabilities (roughly 90 percent) are deposits. Since
deposits can be used to make payments, they are "money."
Accordingly, most bank liabilities are money.
To increase their capital-asset ratios, banks can either boost
capital or shrink assets. If banks shrink their assets, their deposit
liabilities will decline. In consequence, money balances will be
destroyed. So, paradoxically, the drive to deleverage banks and to
shrink their balance sheets, in the name of making banks safer, destroys
money balances. This, in turn, dents company liquidity and asset prices.
It also reduces spending relative to where it would have been without
higher capital-asset ratios.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The other way to increase a bank's capital-asset ratio is by
raising new capital. This, too, destroys money. When an investor
purchases newly issued bank equity, the investor exchanges funds from a
bank deposit for new shares. This reduces deposit liabilities in the
banking system and wipes out money.
By pushing banks to increase their capital-asset ratios to
allegedly make banks stronger, the oracles have made their economies
(and perhaps their banks) weaker.
UK economist Tim Congdon convincingly demonstrates in Central
Banking in a Free Society (2009) that the ratcheting up of banks"
capital-asset ratios ratchets down the growth in broad measures of the
money supply. And, since money dominates, it follows that economic
growth will take a hit, if banks are forced to increase their
capital-asset ratios.
The capital-raising mania in the United States and its consequences
are clear. While the high-powered base money (M0) has exploded since the
Panic of 2008-09, broad money (M3) has taken a different, and worrying,
course (Figure 4).
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The oracles" embrace of higher capital-asset ratios for banks
in the middle of the most severe slump since the Great Depression has
been a great blunder. While it might have made banks temporarily
"stronger," it has contributed mightily to plunging money
supply metrics and very weak economic growth. Until the oracles come to
their senses and reverse course on their demands for ever-increasing
capital-asset ratios, we can expect continued weak (or contracting)
money growth, economic weakness, increasing debt problems, continued
market volatility, and a deteriorating state of confidence.
Conclusion
Monetary misjudgments and malfeasance have characterized U.S.
policy, Even though there were numerous signs that the financial systems
in Europe and the United States were enduring severe stresses and
strains in 2007, the money and banking oracles failed to anticipate and
prepare for the major financial and economic turmoil that visited them
in 2008-09. Indeed, the oracles' ad hoe reactions turned the
turmoil into a panic. Since then, members of the money and banking
establishment have been busy dissembling. They have hung out "not
culpable" signs and pointed their powerful accusatory fingers at
others.
The Fed has a propensity to create aggregate demand bubbles. These
bubbles carry with them market-specific bubbles that distort relative
prices and the structure of production. Contrary to the assertions of
the stabilizers who embrace inflation targeting, these relative price
distortions are potentially dangerous and disruptive.
If that was not enough, policymakers have latched onto a new
mantra: to make banks "safe," higher capital requirements are
absolutely essential. The banks have obliged and increased their
capital-asset ratios. In consequence, the banks' loan books that
are subject to higher capital-to-asset mandates have shrunk. With that,
broad money (M3) growth rates have remained submerged and a typical
post-slump economic rebound has failed to materialize.
References
Aliber, R. Z. (2010) Private Correspondence (19 October).
Barnett, W. A. (2006) "Foreword." In A. Serletis, Money
and the Economy. Hackensack, N.J.: World Scientific Publishing.
Beckworth, D. (2008) "'Aggregate Supply-Demand Deflation
and Its Implications for Macroeconomic Stability." Cato Journal 28
(3): 363-84.
Bernanke, B. S. (2002) "Deflation: Making Sure 'It'
Doesn't Happen Here," Address at the National Economists Club,
Washington, D.C. (21 November).
--(2010) "Causes of the Recent Financial and Economic
Crisis." Testimony before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission,
Washington, D.C. (2 September).
Blinder, A. S. (2010) "In Defense of Ben Bernanke." Wall
Street Journal (15 November).
Braithwaite, T., and Simonian, H. (2011) "Banks Make Basel
Appeal to Congress." Financial Times (16 June).
Congdon, T. (2009) Central Banking in a Free Society. London:
Institute of Economic Affairs.
Dowd, K.; Hutchinson, M.; Ashby, S.; and Hinchliffe, J. M. (2011)
"Capital Inadequacies: The Dismal Failure of the Basel Regime of
Bank Capital Regulation." Cato Policy Analysis 681 (29 July).
Greenspan, A. (2003) "Federal Reserve Board's Semiannual
Monetary Policy Report to Congress." Committee on Financial
Services, U.S. House of Representatives. Washington, D.C. (15 July).
--(2010) "The Crisis." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity (Spring): 201--46.
Grim, R. (2009) "Priceless: How the Federal Reserve Bought the
Economics Profession." Huffington Post (7 September).
Hanke, S. H. (2008) "The Greenback and Commodity Prices."
Interest-Rate Outlook. Boston: H.C. Wainwright & Co. Economics, Inc.
(11 September),
--(2011) "'Stronger' Banks, Weaker Economies."
Globe Asia (August).
Harding, R. (2011) "Fed Misread Dangers of Housing Crash,
Minutes Show." Financial Times (14 January).
Mankiw, N. G. (2011) "What's with All the Bernanke
Bashing?" New fork Times (30 July).
McKinnon, R. (2010) "Rehabilitating the Unloved Dollar
Standard." Asian-Pacific Economic Literature 24 (2): 1-18 (April).
Niskanen, W,A. (2003) "On the Fed's Demand Bubble."
Cato Journal 23 (1): 135-38.
--(2006) "An Unconventional Perspective on the Greenspan
Record." Cato Journal 26 (2): 333--35.
Reddy, S., and Blackstone, B. (2011) "Bernanke Denies that Fed
Is Stoking Inflation." Wall Street Journal (4 February).
Svensson, L. (2010) "Monetary Policy after the Financial
Crisis." Address at the Second International Journal of Central
Banking Fall Conference, Tokyo (17 September).
Tullock, G. (1975)"Discussion." In R. T. Selden (ed.)
Capitalism and Freedom: Problems and Prospects; Proceedings of a
Conference in Honor of Milton Friedman. Charlottesville: University
Press of Virginia.
Wessel, D. (2009) In Fed We Trust: Ben Bernanke's War on the
Great Panic. New York: Crown Business.
White, L. H. (2005) "The Federal Reserve System's
Influence on Research in Monetary Economics." Econ Journal Watch 2
(2): 325-64.
Steve H. Hanke is Professor of Applied Economics at the Johns
Hopkins University and a Senior Fellow at the Cato Institute.