What should a central bank (not) do?
Steil, Benn
The financial crisis that began unfurling in 2008 has led to the
refashioning of the model central bank governor along the lines of
Churchillian war leader, willing to try anything with the money he
conjures to restore economic growth. This raises important questions as
to what limits, if any, elected officials should impose on such aspiring
great men, and what limits markets will ultimately impose on them if
elected officials forbear. This article focuses on the second of these
questions.
The Pitfalls of Aggregate Demand Management
It is a fundamental postulate of today's dominant paradigm of
Keynesian macroeconomics that all demand is created equal. Government
spending is interchangeable with consumer spending, which is itself
interchangeable with business investment. Paul Krugman (2001)
illustrated the paradigm impeccably.
"The driving force behind the current [2001] slowdown is a
plunge in business investment," he observed. "Over the last
few years businesses spent too much on equipment and software, and ...
they will be cautious about further spending until their excess capacity
has been worked off," he cautioned. But "to reflate the
economy," he assured us, "the Fed doesn't have to restore
business investment; any kind of increase in demand will do." For
as "Larry Summers says, you don't have to refill a flat tire
through the puncture." How would Krugman, then, have had the Fed
refill the tire punctured by plunging business investment?
"Housing," he said, "which is highly sensitive to
interest rates, could help lead a recovery."
But surely Krugman understood that we could have too much demand
for housing, even if the economy as a whole was producing less than what
he believed to be its aggregate capacity? No, he did not, so in 2002 he
urged the Fed to do more. The Fed, he wrote, "needs to create a
housing bubble to replace the Nasdaq bubble" (Krugman 2002). We
know how that turned out. Yet today he is singing from precisely the
same hymn sheet--just louder.
If Krugman and Summers could be permitted a tire analogy in support
of their paradigm, perhaps I can be allowed a shower analogy in
rebuttal. Imagine you get into the shower, turn on the water, and
nothing comes out. You call the plumber. He tells you there's a
hole in the pipes, and that it will cost you $1,000 to repair it. You
tell him just to turn up the water pressure instead.
Sound sensible? Well, this is the logic behind the Fed's
strategy of flooding the money pipes until credit starts flowing freely
again from banks to businesses. You wouldn't expect this to work in
your shower, and there's little reason to expect it to work in the
commercial lending market. The credit transmission mechanism in the
United States has been seriously damaged since 2007. There is a hole in
the pipes. Small- and medium-sized businesses in this country are
dependent on small- and medium-sized banks for access to vital credit,
yet too many of these banks remain walking dead, unable to lend because
their balance sheets are littered with bad commercial and real estate
loans made during the boom years. And so whereas the Fed has driven its
short-term lending rate down to zero, most banks will only lend on
vastly greater collateral and at much higher real interest rates than
before the bust. So the Fed plows on with the cheap and easy
macroeconomic option: flood the pipes and see what comes out.
We've already seen the liquidity intended to boost domestic
bank lending instead spill out through the cracks into markets as
diverse as agricultural commodities, metals, and poor-country debt.
Those bubbles will burst, as they always do, but more will be
doubtlessly be created through these tried and troubled methods of
modern central banking.
A Note on Liquidity Traps
When further monetary loosening flails to generate a sustainable
recovery, Krugman will tell us it's because we are in a liquidity
trap--a rare exception to the putative interchangeability of monetary
and fiscal policy in which monetary policy becomes, in effect, chicken
soup (i.e., it may not help, but it can't hurt), and only fiscal
policy (specifically, increased government spending) will do.
What, then, is a liquidity trap? "The economy is in a
liquidity trap when even a zero nominal interest rate isn't enough
to restore full employment," explains Krugman (2011).
"That's it."
This is an astonishing definition, as it implies that there is no
possible reason for less than full employment when the central
bank's policy rate is zero other than that the government is not
spending enough. If the government were to, say, triple the minimum
wage, does less than full employment at a zero policy rate still mean
we're in a liquidity trap, and that the government must therefore
increase spending?
What Krugman surely means is not that there is no possible reason
for less than full employment at a zero policy rate, but rather that
there is no permissible reason for it. I say "permissible"
because he takes it as given that government intervention to prevent
employment below wage, benefit, or job-security levels it finds
acceptable is intrinsically good: any unemployment that might result
from it can and should necessarily be offset by cheaper money and more
government spending. (He cannot argue that structural unemployment is
not an issue in the current liquidity trap, because his definition of
liquidity trap would then be circular.)
This leads to a wider point about this paradigm. Although its
exponents almost invariably want more business activities to be subject
to more restrictions, and frequently fault economic downturns on the
lack of such restrictions, the presence or absence of these
microeconomic interventions is ultimately irrelevant to growth, in their
model of the world, since growth can always be increased through
macroeconomic metals--that is, by looser monetary or fiscal policy. Over
time, this approach is a sure recipe for instability and stagflation.
The Limits of Monetary Sovereignty
The current crisis has been widely invoked in support of the notion
that every nation, no matter how small (even a statelet like Iceland),
needs its own activist national central bank. Yet it is crucial to note
that no central bank outside the Federal Reserve and European Central
Bank, which mint 90 percent of the world's monetary reserves, can
even attempt the requisite sort of liquidity heroics. "Wow,"
Krugman (2011b) wrote after reading Manuel Hinds and me say as much in
the Financial Times (Steil and Hinds 2011), "Have these guys ever
talked to anyone in Sweden, which doesn't need euros to create more
kronor?"
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Well, let's look at the data--for Australia too, which Krugman
throws into the mix. As Figure 1 shows clearly, when the Swedish and
Australian central banks expanded credit dramatically during the recent
financial crisis they also liquidated foreign assets. (1) That is, both
central banks accompanied their massive easing with a scramble for
reserve currencies. They were unable merely to conjure their own
monetary resources for the task. And this is not merely an artifact of
the most recent crisis, as three full decades of Australian data show.
Any country that ploughs on creating credit without ample reserve
currencies (dollars and euros) eventually becomes a ward of the IMF.
The Perils of Delegating Fiscal Authority to Central Banks
The traditional argument for central bank independence was based on
the notion that monetary policy was a uniquely important aspect of
economic policy and that its conduct needed to be isolated from
short-term political pressures. The ECB and the Fed have, however, since
2008 arrogated powers to create and allocate credit that greatly exceed
those that legislators ever intended to grant them. This is typically
defended on the grounds that the political process is too slow and
cumbersome to deal with the scale, or potential scale, of the problems
created by a rapid and systematic withdrawal of credit to systemically
important private borrowers or to sovereigns. The logical possibility
that tills is so can hardly be denied, but neither can the democratic
reasons for having strictly limited such powers in the first place. As
compelling as such reasons are, I put them aside here, and make only the
narrow point that the ECB, in particular, still faces hard limits on its
ability to conduct monetary policy while plugging gaps for reticent
fiscal authorities.
Back in 2000, the ECB's first president, Wim Duisenberg,
explained that he knew the Bank's operational framework for
implementing monetary policy was working well because it was
successfully steering short-term market interest rates exactly where the
Bank wanted them to go. Prior to the crisis, the ECB's policy rate
was indeed tightly connected to 3-month eurozone government borrowing
rates. In a growing swath of the eurozone, however, this relationship
has collapsed, as shown in Figure 2--in the case of Spain, from nearly
100 percent to nearly 0 percent. Default risk increasingly dominates
these rates, which themselves strongly influence rates in the private
sector. By Duisenberg's criterion, monetary policy in the eurozone
is becoming less and less effective as the ECB wades deeper and deeper
into the political quicksand of fiscal policy and discretionary credit
allocation.
In continually insisting that a eurozone sovereign debt
restructuring was out of the question, the ECB was merely talking its
book; that is, trying to avoid the threat to its independence that would
follow if the Bank were itself to need a recapitalization by the member
states.
That day is coming perilously close. The ECB has bought over 200
billion [euro] in bonds of the riskiest eurozone sovereigns since May
2010, and has loaned over three times that much to eurozone banks, often
against highly dubious collateral. With only 81 billion [euro] in
capital, a mere 25 percent haircut on its direct and indirect Greek,
Irish, and Portuguese bond holdings would render it technically
insolvent. Without sufficient assets to sell, it would have no effective
means of withdrawing excess euros from circulation in the future. A
timely recapitalization, which would have to be largely undertaken by
the German taxpayer, cannot be taken as a given. The imminent prospect
of a technically insolvent ECB could therefore precipitate a major run
on the euro.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The Fed is thankfully in a much less precarious position. Though
leveraged 56:1, and post-"Operation Twist" could see its
reported capital wiped out with a roughly 33 basis point rise in
long-term yields, profits on its securities purchases have to date
provided it with ample cushion ($78 billion in 2010, vs. $58 billion in
reported capital). Its balance sheet is also credibly backstopped by its
national Treasury, in contrast to the ECB. The Fed's $1 trillion
mortgage security portfolio is, however, politically toxic, in the sense
that it cannot be readily liquidated to tighten monetary policy without
provoking a political firestorm, not to mention a possible cratering of
the government-dependent U.S. housing market. The only remedy for this
serious threat to long-term monetary stability is to hand the portfolio
over to the Treasury in exchange for Treasury securities, which would
normalize the composition (though certainly not the size) of the
Fed's balance sheet. In the end, this amounts to placing the
liability for this extraordinary housing-market intervention with the
Treasury, where it should have been along. The central bank's
balance sheet is ultimately a dangerous substitute for political will
and public accountability.
References
Krugman, P. (2001) "Reckonings; Delusions of Prosperity."
New York Times (14 August).
--(2002) "Dubya's Douple Dip?" New York Times (2
August).
--(2011a) "Liquidity Traps, Once Again." New York Times
(18 March).
--(2011b) "Reserve Currency Mysticism." New York Times
(29 May).
Steil, B., and Hinds, M. (2011) "Keynesians Are Complacent
about the Dollar." Financial Times (23 May).
(1) I am indebted to Manuel Hinds for these data.
Benn Steil is Director of International Economics and a Senior
Fellow at the Council on Foreign Relations.