Ill-considered experiments: the Environmental Consensus and the developing world. (Perspectives).
Bell, Ruth Greenspan ; Russell, Clifford
For a brief period between the end of the Cold War and September
11, 2001, an opportunity arose to consider global concerns beyond
East-West politics and nudear threats. The connection between
states' failed environmental policies and the devastation wreaked
on the health and stability of their people suddenly became a frequently
discussed subject in foreign policy, no longer consigned to specialized
journals.
However, though the foreign policy debate has shifted, the
potentially disruptive environmental conditions still persist. One
solution to pollution and depleted biodiversity has come in the form of
development assistance. International financial institutions' (IFI)
environmental advice to the developing world and transitioning counties
sounds familiar. Its components--principally market solutions--parallel
what the institutions and their advisors (dubbed the Washington
Consensus) tell the same counties to do to reform their economies. The
environmental policies therefore suffer from the same failings as the
economic advice.
The IFIs, in a form of Environmental Consensus, preach that
counties can only clean up badly polluted environments by adopting
management systems based on economic incentives. Elements of the
institutions' mantra include tradable emissions permits and
effluent charge systems. Advice arrives in a flood of papers from the
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development and the World
Bank.
The difference between the economic and environmental programs is
that IFI environmental advice flies under the radar. The Washington
Consensus has become a brawl among economists, lawyers, sociologists,
and politicians who fight publicly over what went wrong in Russia and
how best to manage Argentina's meltdown. In contrast, the
Environmental Consensus has received little public attention.
As a result, the countries most in trouble are not hearing the
whole truth. What the Consensus does not say is that the institutions,
infrastructure, and human capital needed to support the sophisticated
environmental instruments the West promotes are not present in much of
the developing world. Although the advice sounds appealing, it will not
lead to clean air or drinkable water where it is badly needed. For the
most part, the IFI investments have not improved environmental quality
in any significant manner. It is time to end the silence and initiate a
public discussion. The stakes are too great to cede the conversation to
economists.
Western Origins
The story starts with the use of market-based instruments in the
United States, the model for dissemination elsewhere. Economists were
developing incentive-based approaches to environmental control at the
same time that many of the basic environmental laws were being written
in the United States, but none of those early laws used economic tools.
Economists' suggestions began to make inroads when US Environmental
Protection Agency (EPA) regulators realized that they could help resolve
difficult Clean Air Act implementation problems using incentives.
Accordingly, the EPA set up a system that gave industry the opportunity
to bank or sell emission reduction credits.
This policy worked well enough that credit trading was written into
a 1990 law to control acid rain. Firms that can control their pollution
more cheaply may accumulate credits and can then sell the credits to
others, who must otherwise spend more to reduce pollution. Trading has
clearly accelerated the goal of reducing sulfur dioxide discharges in
the United States and has saved money. Business, not government, decides
the most cost-effective way to comply.
The entire system, however, rests on the rule of law. The
government firmly manages system integrity, expensive monitoring
equipment assures that genuine reductions are being sold, and every
credit (called an "allowance") is assigned a serial number,
which allows the EPA to record transfers and ensure that a units
emissions do not exceed the number of allowances it holds. All
transactions are online and completely transparent, and non-compliance
is vigilantly prosecuted.
Despite its success, trading is not the dominant approach to
environmental protection in the United States. Most regulatory programs
use traditional methods, such as statutory prohibitions, because doing
otherwise poses technical challenges and generates political fights.
Some public advocates oppose economic instruments because they fear that
emissions trading cannot be adequately enforced; others mistakenly think
these programs sanction pollution.
Many European states benefit from environment-protecting economic
instruments, such as deposit-refund systems, which pay people for
dropping recyclable material at a center. Taxes on fertilizer, gasoline,
and other polluting agents are also widely used. Germany, France, and
the Netherlands charge industry for certain kinds of emissions, but the
charges are designed to raise revenue for infrastructure investment
rather than to discourage pollution. Surprisingly, many communist bloc
countries used market instruments, such as imposing fines on emissions
of certain compounds. But pollution charges were not an incentive to
reduce pollution because they were paid out of the soft budgets of state
enterprises.
Banking on Markets
Domestic environmental policy-making in the developing world is
dominated by a unique and unlikely 800-pound gorilla: the development
banks. It is almost unthinkable that these institutions could have any
role, much less a significant one, in shaping domestic US environmental
policy. The introduction of market-based instruments in the United
States, like other contentious issues of domestic policy, took place
after messy battles in and between Congress, the EPA, the media, and
various interest groups.
Yet in the developing world, financial donors wield
disproportionate power on matters of environmental policy. Bank
environmental departments, staffed by Western analysts trained in
efficient markets, use grant-funded studies and reports to communicate
their views. Money and prestige make them the ally of marginalized
environment ministries, but their understanding of institutional issues
is less complete. Although IFIs today have departments that interact
with nongovernmental organizations (NGOs), these serve as facilitators,
not policy advisors.
The 1992 World Development Report marked the opening salvo of the
World Bank's endorsement of economic instruments as a means to
resolve the tension between growth and its environmental consequences.
Additionally, the breakdown of the Soviet Union intensified interest in
harnessing markets. The former Soviet bloc countries, with their
impressive histories of environmental activism, seemed like the most
receptive audience for this message. They were more like industrialized economies than developing countries. They had technically trained civil
services, high rates of literacy, excellent universities, and existing,
frequently forward-looking, environmental laws. Central Europeans in
particular reacted strongly against anything that smacked of central
planning. The phrase "command and control," typically used to
describe traditional forms of environmental regulation, hit an emotional
chord, especially when contrasted with the glittering "free
markets."
Advisors and audiences eager to be seduced by markets joined to
take up the tantalizing idea that the mistakes made in the name of
environmental protection in the West were easily avoidable. The pitch
rarely mentioned the considerable history and experience that allow
markets to work in the Western democracies.
Transition Road Bloc
Economic instruments have not taken hold in Kazakhstan, Poland, the
Czech Republic, and other transitional countries because the
prescriptions simply did not fit the conditions for which they were
suggested. The intuition that these countries were stronger candidates
than developing countries was wrong for two major reasons. First, they
lacked the institutions that serve as the cornerstone of sophisticated
market-based instruments. Second, actors in complex market transactions
need considerable skills that did not exist in the countries of the
former Soviet bloc.
Before 1989, Soviet economists and planners studied non-Marxist
systems, but the people who ran state enterprises operated in an economy
structured under the rules of state socialism. They knew nothing about
Western accounting principles and stock markets; profit and loss were
unimportant.
Former communist countries lacked four main ingredients that would
have facilitated the success of economic solutions to pollution
concerns. First, they did not have institutions to deal with failure.
People who trade emissions represent a right to pollute in the future;
it is difficult to imagine a more complex and intangible property right.
Donor advice on emissions trading rarely mentions the possibility that
transactions might fail. In such an event, some authority,
administrative body, or court must police trades and ensure their
integrity. Yet the same advice was peddled in countries with working
legal systems and those without similar institutions. Some of these
transitional countries recently have begun to restore an European legal
system, free of political and economic safety valves, but in parts of
the former Soviet Union, there was no rule-of-law tradition to revive.
Citizens of Central Europe have experienced many years of
corruption and under-the-table differential treatment. Today, they need
to know that grants of discretion will not be hijacked to serve the
purposes of people in power. Confidence in emissions-trading
transactions has developed in the United States through a high level of
transparency. Competitors, NGOs, and public interest groups can monitor
and know relatively quickly whether or not industry is meeting its
commitments. The "trust but verify" approach has helped build
an enthusiastic constituency in the United States.
In Western Europe, the public is more tolerant when industry and
government sit down to negotiate, so Central European trading programs
may work without as much transparency as the United States demands. On
the other hand, architects of any trading program cannot ignore the
legacy of the Soviet period, especially in countries struggling with
endemic corruption.
The third problem facing former Soviet countries is a lack of
experience with the real costs of compliance. When firms grapple with
actual, rather than theoretical, environmental regulations and genuine
enforcement, they develop an awareness of the real costs of compliance.
Economic pain is a great motivator. Western firms know that emissions
trading is a cheaper way to comply because they have had a century of
experience with cost accounting.
Industry in the Soviet bloc countries had never confronted the hard
realities of environmental compliance. When production goals conflicted
with environmental requirements, it was clear which would win. Even
today, regulatory bodies are still weak in many of the successor
countries. Now the challenge is to make laws work.
States in the former Soviet bloc also faced an absence of a
tradition of monitoring--knowing what amounts of what pollutants are
released into the environment by particular plants--which is an
essential part of any regulatory program. It is especially important for
market-based instruments, since trading sanctions vary in the amount of
permitted discharge from each source.
Monitoring is not reliable in the former Soviet bloc, but there are
alternative ways to prevent cheating. One is to make estimates of
emissions amounts by using the sulfur content of coal. But the accuracy
of the estimates depends on the dubious assumption that the plants have
maintained and used their pollution control equipment. Firms in
countries with rampant corruption and many incentives not to comply with
the rules often save money by turning off their control equipment unless
they know the inspector is coming.
The Environmental Consensus has never admitted the importance of
these issues. The experts vaguely caution that market-based instruments
are effective only if implemented properly and under the. right
conditions. They are reluctant to acknowledge that there is little
experience with market instruments outside the Western democracies.
Developing Advice
If transparency, accurate monitoring, a working legal system, and
realistic incentives to trade are scarce in transitioning economies, the
problems run much deeper in the developing world. There are fewer people
to design and implement these sophisticated programs, the available
talent is generally concentrated in capitals rather than field posts,
monitoring equipment is in short supply, basic data are unreliable, and
informal and even institutionalized corruption is rampant.
In spite of these unfavorable conditions, the most vocal proponents
of the Environmental Consensus say that if the countries of the
developed world were to adopt economic instruments, they would eliminate
the need for regulatory bodies and enforcement programs. In a paper
financed by the United Nations Environment Programme, Theodore Panayotou
of Harvard University argues that economic instruments take full
advantage of the self-interest and superior information of producers and
consumers "without requiring the disclosure of such information or
creating large and costly bureaucracies."
Panayotou's extravagant claims fly in the face of empirical
evidence from the United States when he argues that economic instruments
substitute for efforts to enforce compliance and that they "tend to
have lower institutional and human resource requirements than command
and control regulations."
These claims look suspect when environmental economics is examined
in the context of the realities of the developing world. Proponents
claim that market-based instruments almost automatically bring a region
or country to a solution that optimally resolves the problem of
achieving desired levels of environmental quality. They also say this
cheap solution will be reached without the regulating agency needing to
know anything about the costs of pollution control at the sources it is
regulating.
Unfortunately, these two claims are at odds with each other. When
there are multiple sources of pollution, the regulator will need
complete knowledge of costs and a complex mathematical model to
determine the cheapest solution. If the location of sources does not
matter, as in the effect of global carbon dioxide emissions on climate,
a single charge applied to all sources, the simplest sort of tradable
permit scheme, suffices to reach the cheapest solution. Then it is
conceivable, though not realistic, that environmental ministries could
use costly, time-consuming trial and error to find the appropriate
charge or permit a total that exactly meets the desired standard.
The proponents of market-based instruments go on to argue that
these tools can also produce revenue for perennially overburdened
governments that are saddled with inefficient and distorting tax
systems. Moreover, the revenue can be obtained without distortions of
the kind caused by taxes on income or sales. While there is truth in
these claims, there are also qualifications. The first is that the
amount raised is likely to be small. The second is that it is difficult
to collect this revenue in a reliable way. In countries that have
difficulty collecting even income taxes, taxes on pollution discharges,
which must be measured by special equipment in a real-time monitoring
system, present a greater challenge.
A third caveat is that if the desire for revenue comes to dominate
the government's thinking, the charge will be chosen to maximize
revenue rather than to limit pollution, and the argument about
lowest-cost solutions no longer holds. Finally, if the charges become
too costly, the long-run result will be erosion of the tax base.
The proponents' own claims make this last point explicit.
Invoking an old argument, they say that market-based policy instruments
spur technological advance for pollution control, while traditional
regulatory choices, such as non-marketable permits, do not. Economists
have agreed for some time that there are different incentives to develop
new technologies created by different policy choices. Traditional,
non-marketable permits produce a smaller incentive than do charges on
emissions or regularly auctioned marketable permits. Yet the incentives
created by traditional approaches, if they are enforced, are not
negligible.
The more fundamental question is whether or not the governments of
the developing world have the political will to impose and actually
collect charges significant enough to force industry to seek new
technology. Specifically, doubts exist regarding government willingness
to target firms insulated from market pressures by the equivalent of
soft budget constraints or those who benefit from loans made on the
basis of connections and favoritism, rather than sound business
principles and sober assessment of credit. Using the market to spur
technological change is only plausible if there are safeguards against
the many ways that market forces can be undermined.
In the final analysis, market-based instruments do offer some
highly desirable features when appropriate conditions exist, but the
package is being oversold. Some of the features are in conflict with
each other, and achieving any subset of them demands very large
institutional commitments. The data gathering, mathematical modeling,
and monitoring or auditing of emissions required are all nearly
impossible in the small, understaffed, and under-funded environmental
ministries of the developing world. The Environmental Consensus is not
telling the entire story when it presents economic incentives as a
cure-all solution to pollution in the developing world.
Prescription for Change
What harm has the effort to promote market-based instruments done?
Most developing world governments are too distracted or uninterested to
pay any real attention to their environmental problems. The few
experiments have largely been memorialized in academic journals.
One answer is that these were not mere suggestions but rather the
considered advice of prestigious institutions. When money influences
policy, full disclosure is essential. Instead, the development banks
have treated the developing countries like environmental laboratories.
Many of the ideas they and their advisors have imposed have only been
tested in models and in the minds of the people who thought of them,
where confounding facts and poor conditions can be assumed away.
Theory has much to offer environmental protection, but in the end,
local culture, institutions, and infrastructure will determine the
success of any policy. In this complex situation, policy selection
should not be a function of fads or ideology. Like good doctors, the
Environmental Consensus should examine the patient before, not after,
prescribing the cure. It would help to acknowledge that a long learning
curve lies ahead. International donors should support rather than
disparage incremental improvements and pragmatic goals.
Since institutions are the springboard for any leap forward, donors
should support a transitional or tiered approach that will take into
account existing capabilities and institutions. Only the most developed
countries should be encouraged to attempt difficult environmental policy
instruments like emissions-trading schemes. The most important thing
donors can do is to help developing countries create behavioral rules,
mechanisms for checking and encouraging compliance, and norms that make
compliance the first, rather than the last, choice of action.
Taking more measured steps does not have the same sense of
adventure as a great environmental leap forward. But it will result in
real environmental gains and can be accomplished without losing sight of
the ultimate goal of developing the most sophisticated methods of
managing the environment.
[GRAPH OMITTED]
RUTH GREENSPAN BELL is Director of Resources for the Future's
International Institutional Development and Environmental Assistance
program, and CLIFFORD RUSSELL is Director of the Vanderbilt Institute
for Public Policy Studies.