East-Central Europe: transition to market economy and democracy.
Nikolic, Milos
During the night of november 9, 1989, the gates of the berlin wall
were opened and several hundred thousand people crossed from East to
West. Days later, they pulled the wall down. Many analysts consider this
historical event symbolic of the implosion of "real socialism"
and the beginning of a transition to a new society in East-Central
Europe, to democracy and a market economy, as it is usually expressed.
What are the results of these five years of transition for the nations
of East-Central Europe?
I
I shall first address the relation between theoretical thinking and
the events in East-Central Europe during those five years. The events in
1989 and 1990 were a kind of a political revolution, but a revolution
without a previous historical model and without a revolutionary theory
or a theory of any other kind. According to Claus Offe (1985):
Its most conspicuous distinguishing characteristic is indeed the lack
of any elaborated theoretical assumptions and normative arguments
addressing such questions as: Who is to carry out what actions, under
which circumstances, and with what aims, what dilemmas are to be
expected along the road, and how is the new synthesis of a
postrevolutionary order to be constituted, and what meaning should be
assigned to the notion of "progress"?
The political revolutions of 1989 to 1990 did without theory and
succeeded in their main aim of overthrowing the existing "real
socialist" political regimes. The social developments following
those political revolutions, usually called the "transition to
democracy and the market economy," but which might be considered a
kind of a social revolution, differ in relation to theory, in at least
two important respects.
First, they have so far, for better or worse, been oriented and
guided by some of the concepts of mainstream political and economic
theory, let us say, by bourgeois thinking. Second, in my opinion, the
last five years have shown and confirmed that the success of the
"transition" cannot be realized without a proper theoretical
base, without proper theoretical analyses and orientations.
In my firm conviction, this must be new theoretical thinking based on
all relevant historical experience. It must start from all that is best
in left and radical thinking, including Marx and his true followers, and
from all that is best in the mainstream social sciences. As new
theoretical thinking, it must create a new emancipatory normative
foundation and legitimation, an emancipatory theory that cannot be
formulated in advance and then be realized in practice as a kind of
blueprint. New theoretical thinking may appear and be developed merely
in practice, as a result of new kinds of emancipatory struggle; this
practice would necessarily be characterized as "trial and
error," to use Karl Popper's paradigm. At the same time, this
nascent emancipatory theory would provide a general orientation for
social development, a theoretical basis for empirical analyses and
normative legitimation for emancipatory struggle.
II
I will set forth hypothetical judgments concerning the entire
transitional process in East-Central Europe. The 1989 to 1990 revolution
in East-Central Europe was a kind of political revolution that solved
the question of political power. It opened the gates to a great social
reconstruction implying not only the development of democracy, but also
simultaneously the establishment of modern market economies both in
East-Central Europe and in the West.
This fact reveals a very important difference between the current
social process in East-Central Europe and the transition to democracy
realized in Germany and Italy after World War II and subsequently in
eight Latin American countries and four European countries in the 1970s.
In those countries, it was a matter of changing political regimes since
the pre- and post-transition social system remained essentially the
same. The simultaneous transition to democracy and a market economy
signals a change in political regime and a change in the social system
as a whole, because the establishment of the market economy,
theoretically and practically, means the development of new relations of
production in Marxian terms. Therefore, in East-Central Europe this
transition must be conceived as a kind of social revolution. The first
five years of transition in East-Central Europe, despite lacking a
sufficiently developed and deep social reconstruction, nevertheless
confirmed, at least negatively, that the social revolution is in
question and is needed.
My second hypothetical judgment concerning the process in
East-Central Europe is, in the words of Clause Offe, a Pandora's
box full of paradoxes. By this I mean that this development differs from
and in many important respects is the opposite of the historical
development of Western countries. In addition, this development must
solve and has begun to solve some basic problems in the way in which it
is, in fact, opposite to the corresponding theoretical standpoints;
furthermore, it must carry out some basic tasks that presuppose contradictory factors, principles, and actions. I shall emphasize the
following paradoxes:
1. The paradox of the transition to democracy and its corresponding
politics;
2. The paradox of simultaneous transition to democracy and the market
economy;
3. The paradox of the formation of the relations of capital;
4. The paradox of the social agencies of social forces that could and
should lead and legitimate the whole process; and
5. The paradox of the final goal of the entire process.
My third hypothetical judgment is that the great social process
underway in East-Central Europe has been fueled and developed mainly by
political and even administrative means and acts of state authority,
having been conceived and forged by a new political elite born in 1990
to 1991. The societies in transition have not yet created the objective
factors enabling them to function spontaneously in support of the
transition. This is particularly obvious with respect to economic
transformation. Similarly, no social classes lead the transition process
and it is even difficult to say that any social class or quasi-class,
apart from the political elite, is acting consciously or spontaneously
as an articulated social group in favor of the transition. Thus, we have
the beginning of the social revolution without a leading social class.
As a result of the foregoing, the process of transition has not yet
taken hold of the inherent social structure in order to change it.
Neither has it overcome some of the principal legacies of the former
system and has no clear concerns or generally accepted goals. With
respect to this defect, the normal political life of a modern society
cannot be established in East-Central Europe because in socially and
politically plural societies, it is necessary for a kind of volonte
generale, a kind of generally accepted social agreement or general will,
to exist with respect to the general orientation of social development,
with its corresponding "rules of the game."
This relates to my fourth hypothetical judgment, that the first five
years have confirmed the principal meaning of the expression
post-"real socialist" countries. They have confirmed that this
transitional development is characterized by many legacies of the
previous system and that the transition, for better or worse, has had to
and must in the future rely on elements of those legacies. Here I have
in mind the inherited industrial structure, the paternalistic welfare
system and, above all, the social psychology and mentality of the
majority of the population.
My fifth hypothetical judgment concerning the transition refers to
the change in the everyday life of the majority of the population,
caused by the first five years of transition. The people in East-Central
Europe unquestionably achieved political freedom, which is important
from the historical point of view and from the standpoint of everyday
life. What is not so certain is whether the mass of the population is
able to use this political freedom to decisively influence the course of
further development. These five years have undeniably brought about a
great impoverishment of the majority of the population, which has
strongly influenced all essential aspects of their individual and social
lives, including some very negative and even dramatic demographic
changes in the rate of births and deaths.
My sixth hypothetical judgment concerning the transition is that
although all East-Central European countries share more or less
identical structural dimensions of the transition, so far and for many
reasons, the concrete process of transition has differed from country to
country and will continue to do so in the future. We may distinguish
those countries in which the transition proceeds in a
"normal," i.e., peaceful way, from those that face the
transition in such "abnormal" ways as conditions of war. Three
groups of countries are undergoing a "normal" transition. The
first, consisting of those showing the best results, includes the Czech
Republic, Hungary, and Slovenia. The third group consists of countries
with the worst results: Russia, the Ukraine, Bulgaria, Rumania, and
Albania. The second group falls somewhere between the first and third
groups: Poland, perhaps Slovakia, and the Baltic Republics. A group of
countries in which the transition occurs in "abnormal"
circumstances, involving them in war caused by aggressive nationalism
and war politics includes: Serbia, Croatia, and Bosnia-Herzegovina. The
main results of the past five years in these countries are unfortunately
expressed in the number of dead, wounded, and refugees, and in the
immense destruction of material and cultural wealth and civilized
values.
My seventh and final hypothetical judgment concerns the international
aspect. The Western capitalist countries directly organized, guided, and
paid the principal financial costs of transition to democracy in Germany
and Italy after World War II. They gave great, though sometimes
ambiguous, support to the transition to democracy in certain Latin
American countries and four European countries in the 1970s. In both
cases, these engagements were determined above all by Cold War politics,
namely, by confrontation with the Second World bloc led by the Soviet
Union. After the collapse of the "real socialist" system and
the destruction of the Soviet bloc, Western capitalist policies have
generally changed with respect to their concrete engagement in the form
of assistance. Most of them, starting from their own narrowly conceived
national interests, are concerned only with making good political and
economic use of the newly created situation and putting some
East-Central European countries under their protection without giving
them concrete economic assistance. Strong tendencies exist to organize
the new world order as a system of concentric circles, with one leading
center surrounded by a number of great power and hierarchically ordered
peripheral countries playing only those roles in the world
political-economy permitted by the center.
III
I will now make four hypothetical judgments concerning the transition
to democracy in East-Central Europe. The first concerns realization of
the principal tasks of modern politics and the functioning of the
political system as a whole. Claus Offe's three-stage process seems
to adequately explain all the complexity and challenges of transition in
post-Communist societies. According to Offe, each political life or
"operative political system" is the cumulative outcome of
decision-making at three hierarchically distinct levels. At the first
and fundamental level, such identity decisions are made as who
"we" are, and where our social, cultural, and territorial
borders lie with respect to others. In the tradition of early modern
European political philosophers, this level is related to passions,
courage, and patriotism and is probably best expressed synthetically in
the category of nationhood.
At the second level, key constitutional decisions, or decisions on
common rights, procedures, and rules are made, as well as decisions on
the main institutional structure of political life. Following early
political philosophers, this level is associated with reason and
rationality. Only at the third and highest level does what is usually
called normal political decision-making take place. It is viewed as the
result of transforming particular interests into political decisions.
This level corresponds to the categories of interests and power.
In the history of capitalism, the principal goals of these levels
were generally realized at different times and over many centuries. The
principal goals of the first level, which concerns identity decisions -
formations of social, national, cultural, and territorial borders and
units - were realized by strong authoritarian rulers and there was no
place for democracy. It was a time of nation-state formation, from the
16th to the 18th century. The goals of the second level of today's
political life were realized in the 18th and 19th centuries as a result
of the realization of the goals of the first level. That was the time of
the Enlightenment and of the birth of liberalism and socialism, the time
of social revolutions. This period saw the first steps toward democracy,
the greater role of parliaments, the formation of political parties, and
the first institutions of public opinion. The goals of the third level,
normal political decision-making to solve current problems of
people's everyday lives, based on interests and relations of power,
began only in the 19th century.
Constant realization of these goals alone has opened the way for the
real people's struggle for democracy, as the democratic structure
and practice of society. This struggle has lasted more than 130 years,
from the Chartist movement until 1971, when women finally won the right
to vote in Switzerland. The struggle for universal suffrage itself had
two main dimensions: to abolish the property requirement - the
limitation of the right to vote to the ownership of property - so that
all the people, regardless of property, could have active and passive
voting rights, and to abolish the gender barrier so that women could
vote.
As Claus Offe correctly stresses, the East-Central European countries
must realize the goals of all three levels simultaneously and more or
less quickly. That is the main paradox and the main difficulty of the
political dimension of the transition, but it strongly influences the
whole transitional process. A theoretical and practical question is how
it is possible to simultaneously realize the tasks and goals of all
three levels, when modern history has shown that to do so demands
different, even contradictory factors, principles, and actions. For
instance, realization of the first-level goals grouped around identity
is connected with passions and courage and demands a strong hand, not
democracy; realization of the second-level goals must be based not on
passions, but on reason, whereas the goals of the third level demand
tolerance and democracy. In many East-Central European countries,
particularly in former Yugoslavia, political regimes are still so deeply
engaged with the idealized goals that the goals of the second and
particularly third levels are repressed.
This has brought about an ethnification of politics, which is
strongly antidemocratic, as well as ethnic-civil wars. So much for my
second hypothetical judgment on practical restructuring. In many
East-Central European countries, political restructuring, but primarily
the national question and the politics of national identity, brought
about the ethnification of politics. Such practices easily became war
politics and have brought about the kind of war of which Yugoslavia is
the worst example. There are several reasons for this. One has to do
with the need of East-Central European countries in transition to find a
form for their new identity. Ethnic characteristics have provided the
easy way to that end. Elsewhere, I have explained other reasons for the
national politics and practice of "real socialism" and the
ethnification of politics as means of getting power or retaining it.
My third hypothetical judgment may be phrased as follows: in the past
five years of post-"real socialist" history, formal elements
of democratic social order (democratic institutions and principles) have
been established constitutionally and more or less practically
installed. However, a fuller democratization of political and
sociocultural life, which might be comparable to some countries enjoying
developed democracy, has not been achieved. There are weak points in the
functioning of democratic institutions and in the efficacy of democratic
principles. The main reason for this is that the East-Central European
countries have not yet developed all three segments of the democratic
order of society. To understand this hypothesis, it is necessary to
explain the phrase, "the structure of the democratic order of
society." Three main factors (re)produce the democratic order of
society:
(1) Constitutionally established and guaranteed democratic
institutions and principles, as formal constitutive elements of the
democratic order (i.e., there is no democratic order without these
formal elements). By democratic institutions, we understand the
following: the citizen as the basic instance; free exercise of universal
suffrage; parties, or a multiparty system; a state strongly based on law
and the separation of powers (executive, legislative, judicial);
institutions of citizen and employee participation in relevant
decision-making; institutions that guarantee the rights of all
minorities; free press and mass media; legally guaranteed independent
civil associations, etc. By democratic principles we understand the
principle of the sovereignty of the people, the principle of legality,
the principle of legitimacy, principles of representation and
delegation, the principle of the majority in decision-making, and the
principle of consensus in particular cases, etc.
(2) The presence of the great new age's idea-values of democracy
as the substantive element of democratic order, which has mainly a
regulatory role (in the Kantian sense). These ideas are: the role,
dignity, and (self-)respect of the individual and the protection of his
or her privacy, freedom, quality, justice, solidarity, tolerance,
safety, and welfare. Without a partly constitutive, but mainly
regulatory role played by these idea-values, democracy could not
function to the benefit of all citizens. These idea-values form the
corpus of individual and collective human rights and the democratic
political culture that are a prerequisite to the functioning of
democracy.
(3) A true democratic order of society comprises a democratic praxis (as a synthesis of the formal and substantial elements of democracy
indicated above), a praxis of people as citizens and as a working
population in decision-making on all societal levels and in all spheres
of society, directly or indirectly. Participation of employees in the
economy is a constitutive part of a modern democratic social order.
Structural Reasons for the Malfunctioning of Democratic Social
Organization
The malfunctioning of democracy in East-Central Europe results
primarily from the fact that the second and third segments of a
democratic order have not yet been developed. Democratic idea-values are
developing and taking root very slowly and with great difficulty, such
that the functioning of democratic constitutions and effective
democratic principles are losing the very important regulatory role of
their idea-values. For instance, new democratic institutions,
particularly the executive authorities, do not operate in accordance
with the great idea-values of democracy. These idea-values are likewise
not internalized or integrated into the consciousness and everyday
behavior of the majority of the population. The main expression of this
fact is the persistent lack of a feeling of self-respect for the
existence and role of the citizen, the feeling and respect for
citizenship, and the lack of a corresponding democratic political
culture and the acceptance of the idea of democracy in a very abstract
and simplified way. Ralph Dahrendorf (1990) may be exaggerating somewhat
when he stresses that the creation of the rule of law would require six
months, the introduction of the market six years, and the development of
a democratic political culture and civil society 60 years.
The experience of democratization in East-Central Europe, and perhaps
in Mexico and some other countries, supports theoreticians who, in the
long controversies over formal and substantial elements of democracy,
have argued that democracy, besides its formal elements, must have
substantive elements as well if it is to function properly, and that
democracy cannot be reduced (as Joseph Schumpeter argued, for instance)
simply to a method of solving social issues. In the third level of the
democratic order of society, excluding the praxis of voting, the
democratic praxis of citizens exists mainly in the form of
"acclamatory" or "plebiscitary" democracy.
My fourth hypothetical judgment concerning the political dimension of
the transition relates to features of the general political situation.
There are obvious signs that a degree of normalization of the structure
of political forces in some East-Central European countries has been
underway in recent years, though the process is still incomplete. By the
term "normalization" I have in mind the process of overcoming
the great fragmentation of political parties that characterized the
beginning of the transition, and the first signs of the presence and
articulation of social interests in the field of politics.
There has been a recomposition of relevant political forces. However,
it cannot be said that more or less long-lasting stability has been
achieved. Umbrella political organizations that gathered people in
during the historical moment of the collapse of "real
socialism" on the basis of anticommunism and on abstract ideas of
democracy have disappeared (Civic Forum, Czechoslav Solidarity
Citizens' Committee, Hungarian Democratic Forum, Demos in Slovenia,
and Depos in Serbia).
A general survey of the majority of the population is today primarily
characterized by disappointment due to unrealized expectations,
discontent with the new regime, and frustration with the difficult
conditions of the transition. Such a view has brought about declining
interest in engagement in political life. These facts have also brought
important benefits to left-oriented parties, which is evident in the
results of the last elections in Poland, Hungary, and Bulgaria.
IV
I will briefly enumerate seven hypothetical estimates of the economic
dimensions of the transition in East-Central Europe, the transition to a
market economy.
(1) The process of transition in East-Central Europe has already
confirmed the opinion of many scientists (Jon Elster, Clause Offe, and
others) who argued that the transition to democracy and its
consolidation along with radical economic reforms (i.e., the transition
to a market economy) cannot be successfully realized simultaneously
because these two transitions make contradictory demands and encourage
different expectations. I have in mind the satisfactory functioning of
established democratic institutions and the slow process of economic
restructuring.
(2) In the first five years of transition, the people have been
obliged to pay a high price for their standard of living and everyday
life in general; the economic transition has given them nothing in
return.
(3) Despite the many practical state strategies adopted for economic
transition and measures taken to implement them, they have not realized
most of their main goals.
(4) The entire program for economic transition, liberalization,
marketization, and particularly privatization, conceived and realized as
organized state activities, has not yet brought about a real opening for
the formation of new relations of production within the logic of
capital-labor relations. This leaves the whole economic transition in an
artificial light, transforming it into a more or less administrative,
technical construct.
(5) The program for economic transition has been conceived and
realized with only the "exchange value" and not "use
value" in mind; that is, the program and its realization have taken
insufficient (or no) account of the only existing real economic factors:
human agency and material productive forces and their
"character."
(6) In most East-Central European countries, privatization of state
property is considered by leading politicians and most scientists as the
first and main task of the transition to a market economy. A prevailing
view is that there can be no be market economy without radical and more
or less complete privatization. This position reflects the real
unprofitability of most state enterprises under "real
socialism" and is widely spread by the influence of Western
advisors and their ideology. Privatization is one of the most important
tasks of the economic transition. However, the thesis that a modern
market economy demands complete privatization is not valid; it is a
product of ideology.
(7) The realization of economic transition has not yet found a proper
balance between state organized and directed activities and spontaneous
economic processes. There is a tendency to treat programs for economic
transition as a blueprint that must be simply and completely followed;
practice does not validate such a tendency and it is characterized by
confusion and even anarchical features.
The majority of the population has paid a great price for economic
transition in the form of great impoverishment, a massive reduction in
welfare systems, increased unemployment, and increased crime rates, to
the extent that it threatens the very life of the citizenry in some
countries. Some East-Central European countries now even fit into the
group of the world's poorest countries. Eastern Europe could become
a Third World in Europe.
V
Civil society in East-Central Europe is one of the most important
prerequisites for building a democratic order and developing a market
economy. Associations within civil society in almost all East-Central
European countries played a very important role in the struggle against
the political regimes of "real socialism" and in their final
collapse.
At the outset of the process of transition, as new political regimes
were established, these associations and the existing, weak structure of
civil society with its principles lost influence throughout society.
Thus, although the number of associations in civil society is now a
hundred times greater than before, their social influence is not at all
commensurate with their number. Many reasons account for this. First,
the onset and development of new political regimes have understandably
shifted the focus of social interest and decision-making in the nascent
political sphere. However, real political life, which has for better or
worse been determining the development of their societies, has been
enclosed in new emerging political circles, without proper social
foundations.
Second, civil society, as a structural sphere of society situated
between the political and economic systems, did not exist under
"real socialism." Conversely, associations in civil society
formed in the last decade of real socialism have been too weak to shape
civil society as a structural sphere of society, and the new political
regimes in most of these countries have not felt the urgent need for a
developed civil society. Further, the emergence of a new economic
structure has not required a civil society either, because new economic
structures in East-Central Europe are emerging from state political and
administrative decisions and measures.
Third, civil society is based on a life world, a structural element
of society, and its development is determined by features of the
existing life world. This notion I took from Habermas (1989), but as
reconstructed by Cohen and Arato. For this reconstruction, two moments
are particularly important. Instead of a two-part, state vis-a-vis civil
society model as a framework for understanding civil society (found in
almost all writings on civil society in the 1980s), Cohen and Arato
introduce a three-part model: politics, economy, and civil society
(which implies that economy is outside civil society). Instead of
Habermas' three structural components of the life world (culture,
society, personality), they introduce two main components: the life worm
as "the reservoir of implicitly known traditions, the background
assumptions that are embedded in language and culture and drawn upon by
individuals in everyday life" and the life world as a sum "of
institutions specialized in the reproduction of traditions,
solidarities, and identities" (Cohen and Arato, 1992: 427-428,
429).
After the collapse of "new socialism" in almost all
East-Central European countries, the pre-"real socialist"
traditions that formed the pre-real-socialist "life world"
have been awakened and reaffirmed. Those pre-"real socialist"
legacies exist in many East-Central European countries due to the late,
specific, and unfinished modernization, characterized by traditional,
conservative, and prepolitical consciousness and behavior, and all that
is usual in the sociocultural and political scene.
The quest for a new identity, which also has its origins in the
"life world," has brought the ethnification of politics and a
kind of nationalism that accords with the basic elements of socialist
legacies. Those characteristics of the old pre-"real
socialist" life world are contrary to the establishment of a modern
society. For instance, Serbia has many more or less influential
associations in civil society if viewed only structurally, but many of
them are conservative and nationalistic.
Fourth, certain theoretical and ideological misunderstandings and
confusions affecting associations of civil society, its activities, and
the relations between these activists have contributed to the social
marginalization or disorientation of some activists in the new
situation. The concept and practice of civil society in the 1980s
(accepted in "real socialism" and in Western Europe and based
on a model of civil society vis-a-vis the state) have shown serious
analytic and strategic weaknesses in the new circumstances, after the
collapse of real socialism. The opposition between civil society and the
state has produced an "anti-politics" strategy and behavior
that after the fall of "real socialism" contributed to the
marginalization of civil society. Under new circumstances, this two-part
model has uncritically accepted even neoliberal strategies for the
economic transition. The three-part model of the political system, civil
society, and the economic system, which is developed in the writings of
Habermas, Offe, and particularly Cohen and Arato, is not yet widely
accepted in important East-Central European circles.
VI
My last group of hypothetical judgments concerns a possible prognosis
for further development of the transition in East-Central Europe. It is
explained in the form of an abstract-theoretically and
concrete-historically based hypothesis. The former relies on many
aspects of Marxist work and the scientific work of many others. The
latter refers to similar or analogous historical experiences and to the
experience of the history of "real socialism" and the five
years of transition in East-Central Europe.
Hypotheses Concerning Possible, Desirable, or Non-Desirable
Transitions
Almost all social and political forces accept the imperative to
realize the transition to a society characterized by a democratic
political order, a strong civil society, and a developed modern market
economy. However, the influence of various internal and international
social and political forces and circumstances can bring about very
different societies, primarily in terms of the everyday lives of the
people. The past five years of transition in East-Central Europe do not
make it possible for me to definitively answer the question of where the
countries of this region are going. However, the direction depends not
only on the new "political class" and international factors,
but also on the mood of the populations themselves.
Hypotheses Concerning the Direction of the Transition
Desirable transitional development in East-Central Europe would be
one in which under certain favorable circumstances following radically
directed and spontaneous structural changes in the former "real
socialist" countries, they could bring about a "mixed
society" as a more lasting historical form of the global
organization of society. By "mixed society" we understand a
society characterized by adherents to institutional (structural and
dynamic) factors: plurality of property ownership, classical private
property, and various forms of public, collective ownership, legal
recognition of the rights of labor and capital, a modern market economy
with developed commodity, labor, and capital markets, the accumulation
of capital subordinate to social (national and international) goals and
principles and to environmental imperatives; it is a state based
strictly on law, Rechtsstaat, and guarantees of all human (individual
and collective) rights and a "social or welfare state" with
important tasks in economic life; the political system is a
parliamentary, multiparty democracy on the model of a consensus
democracy, including forms of participative democracy (in politics and
economics); it has developed and efficient institutions, principles, and
conventions of civil society, and a system of neocorporatist dynamic
balance and conflictive cooperation between the main social classes or
semi-classes, strata, which presuppose among other things strong trade
unions; finally, there is the international opening of society and its
economic, technological, political, and cultural integration into
European and world space and order, but not in a "semi" or
"quasi" colonial status.
Such a mixed society, as a more lasting historical form for the
global organization of society, would have some basic characteristics of
capitalism and some important features of the socialist project. Capital
as a social relation (between capital and wage labor) will remain the
"organizational principle" of this society. Following
Habermas, this principle is a "very abstract rule," which is
dependent on the development of productive forces, defines the main goal
of the reproduction of society, and determines the space inside which
the evolution and changes of a social system could occur without loss of
the system's identity. At the end of the third volume of Capital,
Marx stresses that there are two distinctive characteristics of the
capitalist mode of production: first, the "commodity is the
dominant and determinant character of its products," which means
that labor power is a commodity; second, "the production of surplus
value is a direct purpose and the determining impulse of
production" (Marx Engels Werke, Vol. 23: 731). That is precisely an
organizational principle of the capitalist mode of production.
Hypotheses of Undesirable Results
Radically directed and spontaneous structural changes could bring
about a society characterized by privately owned national,
international, or other enterprises and financial institutions that make
use of diverse legal and illegal privileges to hire cheap labor without
a developed system of labor protection and developed workers'
practice, such as trade union rights. Conversely, authoritarian
governments can use state ownership mainly for political purposes; this
results in an authoritarian or semi-authoritarian paternalistic,
populist regime without a developed Rechtsstaat (legal system), regular
violations of human rights, a kind of "acclamatory democracy,"
accumulation of capital and economic development subordinated mainly to
egotistic and particular interests of individual capitalists or groups
of domestic and international capitalists, and a
"semi-colonial" political and economic status for the country.
This scenario assumes that at least some East-Central European countries
would become a kind of periphery in Europe, a Third World on the
European continent.
A "mixed-society" presupposes the realization of capital in
its double form, as a social relation of production and as a form of
productive force as the main organizational principle of the "mixed
society." However, such realization of capital must not create a
capitalist society, that is, a capitalist social formation. With the
corresponding action of relevant social forces, it could bring about a
"mixed society" as a new transitional historic social
formation that incorporates some structural and dynamic elements of
capitalism into the socialist project. The development of a "mixed
economy" would create new possibilities, new objective factors and
subjective forces of, and new ideas about, class and human emancipation,
which we have called socialism. Below I will elucidate only the main
abstract-theoretical arguments in favor of a "mixed society."
(1) The principal, starting (hypo)thesis of the first argument is as
follows: capital (as a social relation, a relation of production with
its logic) is not identical with the capitalist social system, i.e.,
with capitalist society. This (hypo)thesis proceeds from certain of
Marx' theoretical-methodological stands. Marx bases the existence
and the role of theory on the difference between essence and appearance
(Marx Engels Werke, Vol. 23: 261-680). In Grundrisse and Capital, there
are two conceptions of this difference, although they are not clearly
articulated. In most places, Marx describes appearance as illusion,
apparition (der Schein) in opposition to essence as true reality,
"the peaceful kingdom of laws" (Hegel). In this respect Marx
writes in Grundrisse about "the apparent equality and freedom"
in capitalist society (Marx Engels Werke, Vol. 19: 133, 134). We do not
follow this.
The second conception of this difference is a developmental one,
which "genetically develops the various forms" of the
metamorphoses of capital (Marx Engels Werke, Vol. 26: 384). This
conception appears implicitly in the expositions in the three volumes of
Capital (and in the criterion of the division of the whole subject of
capital into three volumes) and is explained by Marx in the first
sentences of the third volume. By describing the content of the first
and second volumes, Marx stresses that in the third volume, "the
forms of capital...coming nearer, step by step, to this form in which
they are stepping, on the surface of society, in the interaction of
various capitals, in competition..." (Marx Engels Werke, Vol. 23:
27). Important here is Marx' emphasis that all this is "a real
development of capital." In our argument, we shall follow this
"understanding" of Marx.
In this and the next hypotheses, we rely upon another of Marx'
insights in Capital. According to Marx, "it is necessary to
differentiate between the general and necessary tendencies of capital
and the forms in which they are expressed" (Marx Engels Werke, Vol.
21: 284). Marx often stresses this idea elsewhere in Capital, making
clear that there are differences between the laws and the logic of
capital, as they are explained in Capital, and their real functioning in
capitalist society. These differences, as will be shown, are the result
of the influence of the mediators in the process of transformation of
capital into capitalist society.
(2) The second (hypo)thesis is as follows: Capital, as a relation of
production, produces and reproduces mediations. Mediations are very
important for at least four reasons. First, they are an active factor in
(re)producing capitalist society; second, some of them more or less
contradict the very logic of capital (and that constitutes the inner
contradiction of capital, its "inner limit"); third,
contradictions between the logic of capital and these mediations lead to
various types of capitalist society and therefore make a "mixed
society" possible. Fourth, these mediations are structural from the
point of view of the realization and functioning of capital and from the
standpoint of capitalist society. However, at the same time, they are
circumstantial, that is, they are historically determined. Thus, they
are at the same time a constant and a variable.
To explain the possibility of a "mixed society" at the
abstract-theoretical level, it is useful to describe these mediations.
The first metamorphosis of capital and its mediations takes place in the
sphere of economy. The first step in the realization of capital, in its
process of reproduction, is a "circular course" that subsumes
the unity of the process of producing capital (Capital, Volume II) and
the process of exchange (Marx Engels Werke, Vol. 22: 291). The process
of exchange is at the same time a product and prerequisite to the
production of capital ("circular course"). This unity brings
into the process of (re)production of capital two very important
elements: the competition of individual capital (which means individual
capitalists) in capital's commodity and labor markets and the
relationship between capitalists and workers, because "the very
introductory act which is an act of exchange is a buying and a selling
of labor power" (Marx Engels Werke, Vol. 22: 320). This
relationship between capital and labor is realized in the society as a
class struggle between capitalists and workers, that is, the capitalist
and working classes.
Capitalism can realize itself as a social factor only through
competition between individual capitalists and through class struggle.
In this respect, these two phenomena are structural elements of the
reproduction of capitalist society. At the same time, they are also
circumstantial, i.e., historical elements that can be and really are
different in their intensity and, particularly, in their influence upon
the whole of society. This structural historical fact also speaks in
favor of the possibility of a "mixed society," showing that
workers' struggles can direct development toward such a society.
The second step appears in capital as a relation of production and
combines with the productive forces that assume the function of capital
as well. This unity forms the capitalist mode of production. Capital as
a social factor can function in its full capacity (when a "formal
subsumption of labor under capital" is replaced by a "real
subsumption") only if it is realized as a capitalist mode of
production. Moreover, capital begins to function in its full capacity,
having formed the capitalist mode of production, when (thanks to the
first Industrial Revolution) it has taken the form of the "system
of great machinery" (Marx), as productive forces adequate to
themselves (Marx Engels Werke, Vol. 20: 66). In this respect, adequate
productive forces are also a constitutive structural element of
capitalist society. At the same time, however, productive forces like
the industrial system are circumstantial elements, i.e., concrete
historical variables. Indeed, the entire capitalist mode of production
has such a historically variable dimension because "class struggle
is not a simple consequence of the mode of production," but is
always inside it, a part of "the very definition" of the mode
of production, as E. Balibar said. The third step in the economic
metamorphosis of capital, a step that departs from the sphere of economy
and enters the sphere of social (i.e., sociological) relations is the
transformation of capital and wage labor into their
"personifications" (Marx), the capitalist and the laborer, and
their class struggle, which (re)produces the capitalist and working
classes.
The second group of mediations concerns civil society and is based in
the life world. The entire history of capital has shown the very
important role civil society, i.e., the "life world," has
played in the formation of capitalist society. This structural element
and concrete historical variable has brought about very different types
of capitalist systems. One of the newest arguments in favor of this
thesis is the Japanese economic "miracle" of the 1970s and
1980s and the economic development of the "four tigers" in
Southeast Asia in the 1990s.
In the third group of mediations that participate in the formation of
the capitalist system based on the logic of capital, and which bring
about very different types of this system, are democracy and the state
as well as the whole political structure. Concerning the relation
between capitalism and democracy, capitalism as a social system in
developed Western countries was unquestionably established without
democracy and its influence. The introduction of democracy in these
countries has been primarily the result of the struggle of the labor
movement.
With respect to the contemporary functioning of the capitalist
system, many scientists on the Left reasonably argue that the
development of democracy contradicts the very logic of capital. Some
post-Marxist authors interested in the struggle against capitalism
therefore argue that the main struggle against capitalism must be
performed in the field of democracy. The (neo)Marxist discussion about
the state in the 1960s and 1970s reasonably emphasized that a capitalist
state, if it is democratic, is not a simple weapon in the hands of the
ruling class, but is also a field of constant class struggle between the
ruling class and the working class (and many factions within the ruling
class as well). Democracy and democratic states are the most important
mediations in the transformation of capital and its results, the society
emerging out of these mediations.
The fourth group of mediations is the environmental problem. The
essence of the environmental problem in our context is that nature, both
external nature and the nature of man, limits the development of capital
and its logic. Nature in both meanings contradicts the very logic of
capital. Therefore, it may also be a factor in the struggle for a
"mixed society."
The fifth group of mediations consists of the complex of
international relations. This complex has become increasingly important,
particularly due to the globalization taking place in the world today.
Consequently, the development of individual countries is more and more
dependent upon the strength of the international and national capital of
developed countries, and not directly upon capital as an economic power,
but also on capital as political power. This complex is directly linked
to the production of the world's peripheries and to the possibility
of transforming certain East-Central European countries into a new kind
of world periphery.
We began this section with the thesis that capital is not identical
with the capitalist system, i.e., with capitalist society. Capitalist
society is (re)produced through the five mediations we have described.
Due to these mediations, capital can bring about very different kinds of
capitalist society, from Nazi Germany to social democratic Sweden, from
some underdeveloped countries in Africa to fundamentalist countries like
Iran and Austria. The mediations we are considering may have still other
results because many of them are, or may be, opposed to the very logic
of capital. They may be the most important factors for overcoming the
excesses of capitalism.
After 50 years of practical and theoretical struggle against
capitalism, I believe a successful struggle against capitalism might be
accomplished not by direct attacks on capital, aimed at its destruction
at once and from outside. Rather, it will take place in the long
historical process of articulating and attacking its internal limits
through precisely the five groups of mediations outlined above. It can
only be done from within. In this respect, the former "real
socialist" countries must start at the beginning if the democratic,
socialist oriented, social and political forces are to acquire power
through democratic elections. The first goal before these forces is
neither a socialist nor a capitalist society, but a "mixed
society."
The abstract-theoretical level is the highest possible level of
generalization or abstraction one can achieve and use in the social
sciences. Setting aside philosophy, some scientists would argue that the
objective social factors concerning human agency and activity cannot be
considered in the social sciences at the same high level of abstraction and generalization as are social structures and laws. Marx'
theoretical work has confirmed this position. Nevertheless, we must also
consider human agency at the abstract-theoretical level. In that
necessary generalization, however, we shall make a compromise in terms
of the objective structural factors and implicitly of some basic
philosophical insights, as well as in terms of historical experience.
REFERENCES
Adam, Frane 1990a "Deformisana modernizacija-paradoks
socijalisticke modernizacije" ("The Deformed Modernization -
The Paradox of Socialist Modernization"). J. Teokarevic (ed.),
Modernizacija i drustveni razvoj (Modernization and Social Development).
Beograd: Strucna Knjiga.
1990b "Privredna reforma i civilno drustvo u socijalizmu"
("Economic Reform and Civil Society in Socialism"). Napustanje
socijalizma (The Abandonment of Socialism). Beograd: Strucna Knjiga.
Arato, Andrew 1987 "The Budapest School and Actually Existing
Socialism." Theory and Society 4.
1984 "Kriticka sociologija i autoritarni drzavni
socijalizma" ("Critical Sociology and Authoritarian State
Socialism"). Treci program 68 (Beograd).
Babic, Stojan 1988 "Poljska kriza i privredna reforma"
("The Crisis in Poland and Economic Reform"). Nase teme 3
(Zagreb).
Bahro, Rudolf 1978 The Alternative in Eastern Europe. London: NLB.
Bauer, Tamash 1987 "Druga privredna reforma i svojinski
odnosi" ("The Second Economic Reform and Ownership
Relations"). Medjunarodni radnicki pokret 3-4 (Beograd).
Bruszt, Laszlo 1990 "1989: The Negotiated Revolution."
Social Research 1,2 (New York, 1992).
Castoriadis, Cornelius 1982 Devant la guerre. Paris: Fayard.
Cohen, L. Jean and Andrew Arato 1992 Civil Society and Political
Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Connor, Walter 1981 "Workers and Power." Jan Triska and
Charles Gati (eds.), Blue-Collar Workers in Eastern Europe. London:
Georg Allen and Unwin.
Cox, Robert 1991 "Real Socialism in Historical
Perspective." Ralph Miliband and Leo Panitch (eds.), Socialist
Register 1991: Communist Regimes. The Aftermath. London: The Merlin
Press.
Dahrendorf, Ralf 1990 Reflections on the Revolution in Europe.
London: Chatto and Windus.
Denitch, Bogdan 1992a After the Blood. Hanover, NH: Wesleyan
University Press.
1992b The Tragic Death of Yugoslavia. When the Ethnos Becomes the
Demos. Manuscript prepared for a book.
Feher, Ferenc, Agnes Heller, and G. Marcus 1986 Diktatura nad
potrebama (Dictatorship over Needs). Beograd: Pecat.
Feher, Ferenc and Agnes Heller 1987 Eastern Left, Western Left.
Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Humanities Press International.
Fletcher, G. 1966 "Against the Stream." T. Aczel (ed.), Ten
Years After. London: MacGibbon and Kee.
Gantar, Pavel 1988 "Sociologija i civilno drustvo"
("Sociology and Civil Society"). Pogledi, Split 1.
Golubovic, Zagorka 1982 Staljinizam i socijalizam. Beograd.
Habermas, Jurgen 1989 The Theory of Communicative Action, Volume 2.
Cambridge: Polity Press.
1984 "Odgovor mojim kriticima" ("The Answer to My
Critics"). Treci program 62.
Halliday, Fred 1991 "The Ends of Cold War." R. Blackburn
(ed.), After the Fall. London: Verso.
1983 The Making of the Second Cold War. London: Verso.
Hankiss, Elemer 1990 East European Alternatives. Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
1988 "The 'Second Society': Is There an Alternative
Social Model Emerging in Contemporary Hungary?" Social Research
(Spring-Summer).
Heller, Agnes 1986 "Kultura." Marksizam u svetu 4-5
(Beograd).
Janos, C. Andrew 1989 "Politika zaostalosti u kontinentalnoj
Evropi 1870-1945." Casopis Nase teme 10.
Jenkins, Robert 1992 "Society and Regime Transition in
East-Central Europe." G. Szoboszlai (ed.), Flying Blind. Budapest:
Hungarian Political Science Association.
Kadar, Bela 1992 "Privredna reforma u Srednjoj i Istocnoj
Evropi: cinjenice, pravci razvoja i izgledi" ("Economic
Reforms in Central-East Europe..."). Ekonomika 5 (Beograd).
Kaldor, Mary 1991 "After the Cold War." M. Kaldor (ed.),
Europe from Below. London: Verso.
Konrad, George and Ivan Szelenyi 1979 "The Intellectuals on the
Road to Class Power." Brighton: Harvester Press.
Kos, M. 1989 "Nevarnost iluzij" ("The Danger of
Illusions"). Nasi razgledi (March 24, Ljubljana).
Krizan, Mojmir 1988 "Civilno drustvo i medernizacija drustva
sovjetskog tipa" ("Civil Society and the Modernization of
Soviet Type Societies"). Gledista 5-6 (Beograd).
Kundera, Milan 1985 "Oteti Zapad ili tragedij srednje
Europe." B. Rajcic (ed.), Cesko pitanje (Beograd, 1990).
Lefort, Claude 1990 "Renaissance of Democracy." Praxis
International 1-2.
Marx, K. 1957 Various volumes in Marx-Engels Werke (K. Marx and F.
Engels Werke). Berlin: Dietz Verlag.
Marcuse, Herbert 1958 Soviet Marxism. A Critical Analysis. London:
Routledge.
O'Donnell, Guillermo and Philipe Schmitter 1988 Transitions from
Authoritarian Rule. Tentative Conclusions About Uncertain Democracies.
Baltimore: The John Hopkins University Press.
Offe, Klaus 1985 Contradictions of the Welfare State. Cambridge,
Mass.: MIT Press.
Piccone, Paul 1990 "Paradoxes of Perestroika." Telos 84
(Summer).
Przeworsky, Adam 1991 Democracy and Market. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Puhovski, Zarko 1990 Socijalisticka konstrukcija zbilje (The
Socialist Construction of Reality). Zagreb: Pitanja.
Simic, Predrag 1990 "Changes in the Socialist Countries:
Contents and Prospects." The Journal of East and West Studies 2.
Stojanovic, Svetozar 1987 Od marksizma do etatizma sa ljudskirn licem
(From Marxism to Etatism with a Human Face). Beograd.
Szelenyi, Ivan 1986 "The Prospects and Limits of the East
European New Class Project: An Auto-Critical Reflection on The
Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power." Politics and Society
15,2.
Szelenyi, Ivan 1989 "Ideje o 'trecem putu' u
Madjarskoj." Casopis Nase teme 10.
Szentes, Tamas 1990 "Perestroika and the East: The Fading Away
of 'Real Socialism' and East-West Bipolarism." Report on
the International Seminar on "Socialism, Development, and
Democracy." Dakar (December 13-15).
Szucs, Jeno 1988 "Three Historical Regions of Europe."
Civil Society and the State. London: Verso.
Touraine, Alain 1980 L'apres-socialism. Paris: B. Grasset.
Vajda, Mihaly 1981 The State and Socialism. London: Allison and
Busby.
Walicki, Andrzej 1989 "Razvoj i modernizacija u podeljenoj
Poljskoj" ("Development and Modernization in Divided
Poland"). Nase teme 10 (Zagreb).
Weiss, Dieter 1993 "Issues of the Economic Transformation in the
Former COMECON Countries." Journal of Regional Policy 2 (Naples).
Wolter, Ulf 1981 "The Review on Bahro's Alternative."
Telos 48.
Zivkovic, Bosko 1990 "Nestabilna kombinacija plana i
trzista" ("Unstable Combination of Plan and Market").
Napustanje socijalizma (The Abandonment of Socialism). Beograd: Strucna
Knjiga.
Zupanov, Josip 1988 Marginalije o drustvenoj krizi (Marginalia on
Social Crisis). Zagreb: Globus.
DR. MILOS NIKOLIC is a Professor in the Faculty of Philosophy,
University of Novi Sadf, Kneza Milosa 17, 11000 Beograd, Yugoslavia.
Revised by John Page.