Quit lying and address the controversies: there are no dogmata, laws, rules or standards in the science of economics.
Becker, William E.
I. Introduction
The "No Child Left Behind" K-12 education initiative is
associated with The National Assessment of Educational Progress (NAEP).
The NAEP Economics Framework project website http://www.
naepecon2006.org/projoverview.asp states that its advisory panel
"assures that the assessment specifications meet recognized
technical standards." This pre-college thinking has permeated
advice on the teaching of economics at the post-secondary levels:
Here we offer a strategy for refocusing the Principles course on
economic literacy ... The Voluntary National Content Standards in
Economics are the building blocks of our Principles course. The 20
Standards provide an operational definition of economic literacy
... the core of economic knowledge and descriptions explaining what
students should be able to do with that knowledge. (Hansen, Salemi
and Siegfried, 2002, 464.)
But there are no standards in the science of economics. I will
argue here, as I have elsewhere, that other than a need for honesty
there are no rules, laws or dogmata in economics and attempts to impose
K-12 thinking in higher education will, to paraphrase Veblen, render
university faculties to be nothing more than high school teachers
masquerading as something much greater. (1) Doing in universities what
is arguably legitimate for high schools is remedial education (or
training) and not higher education.
II. Controversies in Science
One might assert that if economics is truly a science then like
other sciences it must have a core of non-controversial principles that
stand the test of time. Even without knowing much if anything about
other sciences, however, academic economists should be aware of heated
debates in the natural sciences from reading the Wall Street Journal and
like media sources readily available to them. For instance, WSJ articles
by Begley (2005a; 2005b) detail such controversy. MIT's Frank
Wilczek (who shared the 2004 Nobel Prize in physics) is quoted by Begley
saying that some alleged laws of physics are rightfully disputed, giving
as an example the concept that mass is conserved, a staple from
introductory courses. Wilczek is quoted saying "But that
couldn't be more wrong. Massive particles such as protons are built
of quarks and gluons, which have zero mass (unless they are moving).
Mass is far from conserved." From high school physics we learn that
for every action there is an equal and opposite reaction; yet, Wilczek
is quoted by Begley saying that is not universally true: "It fails
for magnetic forces between charged particles."
Begley tells of high school biology teachers presenting without
question that auxin promotes plant growth, when the reality is far more
complex as seen in the raging controversy over how, if at all, it does
so. She reports that only recently did Indiana University's Mark
Estelle and colleagues find that auxin attracts and binds plant proteins
that silence growth-promoting genes. It is the enzymes that then devour
the silencers that allow growth genes to turn on. Astronomers argue over
the dark matter that pervades the universe. Thus, an up-to-date textbook
should state that dark matter exists but its composition remains an
enigma. Begley's examples of controversy in the natural sciences
that are not being taught in introductory science classes go on and on
but can be summarized with the quote from physicist Lawrence Kraus of
Case Western Reserve: "Every scientific theory is constantly under
scrutiny and has unknowns at the edges." (2)
III. Looking Back
The idea that students need a sense of the historic development and
mastery of basic concepts in a science to be literate in the science was
dismissed by Richard Feynman (co-recipient of the Nobel Prize in Physics
in 1965, and at the time a faculty member at the California Institute of
Technology) when he was asked to teach Caltech's undergraduate
2-year introductory course in physics (Gleick, 1992). Before Feynman,
the normal introductory university physics courses went through the
historic basic concepts reaching atoms and molecules in the final weeks.
Feynman, however, gave short shrift to physics before the 1920s going
right to quantum physics in his second lecture, which at the time was
the sexy stuff that students could get excited about.
Over 40 years ago economists, such as the late G. L. Bach, who was
then Chair of the American Economic Association's Committee on
Economic Education, championed the idea of emphasizing a few basic
economic concepts in the hopes that students would at least retain
something (although his principles textbook was encyclopedic). The late
Ben Lewis, also a chair of the AEA Committee on Economic Education,
bemoaned the fact that his beloved short list of economics laws was
being eschewed by mathematical innovations in the rapidly advancing
science of economics. He lamented:
Ours was an economy of principles, law and order. The Law of
Self-Interest and the Law of Supply and Demand governed our
microconcerns, and our macroconcerns were few and slight. Say's Law
insured us against anything more troublesome than exceptional ...
money was kept in order by Gresham's Law. No one dreamed of
questioning the constitutionality of our laws ... The Depression
opened the door ... through the open portal came a couple of
mathematicians. They stayed to dinner. They, too, were movers--they
moved in ... my old world was gone; economics began its frantic
scramble for recognition as an exact science." (1970, 6-7)
To heed the advice of those who continue to advance the doctrinaire teaching of concepts such as opportunity cost and comparative advantage,
self-interest and incentives, supply and demand, marginal costs and
benefits and the like, with little or no discussion and questioning of
the conditions required for their use in analysis and ignoring
innovations in economics are giant steps backward in the teaching of
economics.
If for no reason other than the time constraint, to say nothing of
learning theory, classes in any subject cannot be encyclopedic. The
number of concepts to be taught must be limited by the amount of time
available for learning. This observation, however, does not imply that a
short list of outdated concepts be emphasized to the exclusion of more
appropriate alternatives. For example Victor Fuchs (2004) tells of his
use of the case method in the 1950s and how he came to believe that in
teaching his philosophy is captured by the aphorisms of "less is
more" and "there is no teaching, only learning," which 50
years later are two views that are still being advanced by many in the
economic education movement as novel. But unlike many of the current
advocates of the "less is more" philosophy, Fuchs calls
attention to the limitations of economics and the need for honesty in
spelling out the shortcomings of economic analysis. Similarly, eminent
economist and textbook author Edmond Malinvaud (2004) warns teachers of
economics to avoid a set of dogmatic and typically invalid methods of
old and the misuse of so-called stylized facts as if they were
empirically valid. There must be real empirical support for the analysis
we advance in the classroom or students will rightfully dismiss us as
dreamers or, worse yet, frauds.
IV. Outdated and Misused Ideas
During an office interview of a newly minted Ph.D. candidate for an
entry-level professorship, I asked her to relate the ideas of equilibria
in economics science to what students see in the popular press. She
paused and said, "Well, supply and demand ..." I asked how she
would respond to satirist P. J. O'Rourke's assertion (in Eat
the Rich: A Treatise on Economics, 1999) that textbook supply and demand
graphs do not help much in analyzing situations that are found in
newspaper headlines? I did not get much of an answer.
I was equally bemused by a viewer chiding provocative TV Talk show
host Bill O'Reilly (October 10, 2005) for going after the energy
companies for "gouging," saying he should understand
competitive free markets because he surely used supply and demand to
negotiate his compensation package on the FOX network. (3) He responded
that Enron demonstrates how markets can be manipulated and that he
actually took a lower salary to be with FOX.
A recent house guest who teaches masses of introductory students
berated me for maintaining a lawnmower and cutting my own grass because
my comparative advantage lay elsewhere. He called my attention to an
example in Gregory Mankiw's (1998) textbook in which a hypothetical
question is raised as to whether highly paid basketball star Michael
Jordan should cut his own grass, at an alleged opportunity cost of
$10,000, given that a neighbor girl can be hired at $20. My house guest
did not appreciate my calling his attention to the enjoyment I and
possibly Jordan get from cutting grass, not being dependent on others,
and multitasking (joint production of physical conditioning and grass
cutting--one minute walking behind the lawnmower is one less minute on a
treadmill). (4) Curiously, Gary Becker's 1992 Nobel Prize winning
work on productive consumption (activities that enhance both utility and
wealth) was ignored by Mankiw and my academic economist house guest.
Is it really true that many of the things of interest to students
and things that they see and hear in the popular media lend themselves
to supply and demand analysis, comparative advantage assessment, and
like ideas that are advanced as the bedrock of introductory classes? Is
one really economically literate if he or she has mastered the rhetoric
of outdated textbook economics? Given modern advances in the science of
economics, literacy today implies that a student confronted with an
application of a supposedly immutable principle can articulate why the
underpinning key assumptions are likely not met in the real world.
Students who are literate in economics should be able to recognize that
there are no "principles of economics" in the sense of basic
truths in economics. The principles that economists think they are
teaching are in fact theories underpinned far too often with assumptions
that are unlikely to be met in actual circumstances and which when
blindly applied give erroneous results.
For example, when imperfect information leads to the use of price
as a measure of quality--as in used-car markets, insurance, and labor
markets--then an equilibrium may be characterized by inequality between
quantities demanded and supplied, and a neat separation of demand and
supply curves may not be appropriate. Scarcity of concert tickets may
actually increase their attractiveness making static demand curve
analysis meaningless. Similarly, supply and demand curves are arguably
unidentifiable in the case of medical and legal services.
The traditional competitive model of the Arrow and Debreu variety
is based on a collection of identical items. If one tries to define a
market for an individual, such as that for Bill O'Reilly, then it
is not a competitive market. Saying that the relevant object is not the
individual TV personality Bill O'Reilly but all such talk show
hosts implies competition but all talk show hosts cannot be treated as
homogeneous as in a competitive market. As Joseph Stiglitz (1987) wrote
some 20 years ago, we need to articulate the
... difference between economies in which the law of supply and
demand is repealed and those where it still holds ... markets in
which commodities are completely homogenous-with respect to
location and the date as well as other characteristics--are almost
inherently sufficiently thin so that the postulate of perfect
competition is inapplicable. Markets that are sufficiently 'thick'
to be competitive are almost always nonhomogeneous.(25)
Using the textbook supply and demand graphs, an instructor will
have problems correctly guiding a student who comes in with a quote such
as this from Michael Collins, a retail partner at Bain & Co. in
Chicago:
Making the 1,000th DVD player is a lot more efficient and less
expensive than making the first, and that's reflected in the lower
price. The difference between the manufacturing cost of the 1
millionth and the 2 millionth is miniscule. (El Boghdady and
Musgrove, 2003, E2)
Traditional discussions of supply curves are problematic when
marginal costs are approximately zero, as is the case for many
information-based goods with which students are familiar. The
identification of supply and demand shifts are further complicated when
demand for a product depends in part on its widespread usage. The idea
that a fall in the price of capital relative to the price of labor
necessitates a shift out of labor and into capital was refuted by the
Cambridge controversy when the entire notion that capital (or labor)
could be treated as homogenous was contested.
Students do need to learn about supply and demand, but they also
need confirmation that textbook-style competitive markets with demand
and supply curves that might work for agricultural commodities, at least
in an idealized world, do not work for all items of interest to them.
Students need to see situations in which increasing or decreasing a
price does not automatically imply higher or lower profits, but they
don't need to spend hours calculating meaningless elasticities.
They need to know about the principle of comparative advantage, but they
also need to learn the difference between static and dynamic analyses
(5) and learn how risk is defined and reduced through diversification,
not specialization. (6) Students recognize that there is satisfaction in
doing things oneself and that behavior toward risk must enter
decisions--we are not all nor are we always risk neutral, risk adverse
or risk loving. Thus, how can instructors expect students to ignore
these things when they are given rigid multiple-choice tests on overly
simplistic and outdated economic concepts? (7)
V. Standards
Any professor of economics can identify the field's
traditional basic concepts. The trick is to recognize and articulate the
shortcomings of simplistic analysis before students rightly dismiss it
as irrelevant and then wrongly dismiss all of economics with it.
Bright and motivated students will view standards that are based on
out-dated ideas and inappropriate methods of analysis, no matter how
hard and complex, as dismal. For instance, the driver's test
administered by Britain's Driving Standards Agency is regarded as
one of the hardest in the world. Only 44 percent of takers pass,
compared with 79 percent in Germany and 61 percent in New York State;
yet, 20 percent of those passing the British test have accidents within
a year of passing (Calian and Stecklow, 2002). This test is mocked as
outdated, remaining relatively unchanged since the 1920s--correct
actions include: using the hand break to bring the car to a stop; being
able to back around a corner and up one block next to a curb without
touching the curb; never crossing hands when turning the steering wheel;
looking in the review mirror before activating the turn signals; etc.
Within the United States, the claim is made that state law and medical
exams have become dated as seen in the California exam where more than
50 percent of the state law exam takers fail, including Stanford Law
School Dean Kathleen Sullivan, (Bandler and Koppel 2005).
As stated in Becker, Greene and Rosen (1990), some basic skills may
have a high value at one point in time and little value at another; for
example, the Polish cavalry was revered as highly skilled and unmatched
in discipline and high standards, however, that tradition of excellence
came to a tragic end when confronted with the German tank. As with
cavalry skills, paper and pencil long division was trumped by an ability
to manipulate a slide rule, which fell in value with the availability of
the inexpensive hand calculator; the ability to work the hand-held
calculator fell in value with the advancement of computer spreadsheets
and statistical packages. Since writing with Greene and Rosen, the
development of online search engines has made library card catalog
skills obsolete.
So, too, in economics: skills, ideas and information become dated.
The advent of the modern-day computer, for instance, has turned
economics into a more empirical subject, as seen in the work of recent
recipients of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Science. Yet, the
typical undergraduate curriculum gives little attention to the
importance of empirical research and empirical findings. For instance,
standard textbook demand and supply analysis is presented as religious
dogma to show that minimum wages destroy jobs; yet, empirical evidence
by Card and Krueger (1997) has stirred debate about the accuracy of this
widely accepted theoretical assertion. Even Levitt and Dubner's
(2005) research behind the pop-culture book Freakonomics is data driven
with ideas that are at the frontier of economics and not at all in
keeping with standard textbook presentations.
Innovations in the science of economics are not making their way
into the teaching of economics at the undergraduate level. For example,
although Nobel prizes are typically awarded for work completed years
earlier, and Zahka (1999) described how the Nobel Laureates'
acceptance speeches can be used in teaching the principles of economics,
as I report in Becker and Greene (2004) the work of Nobel Laureates is
rarely presented regularly in principles textbooks prior to announcement
of the award and even seldom afterward.
Although major empirical findings and related debates are regularly
reported in the popular press they are not featured in introductory
textbooks. Instead what we are beginning to see is a trend toward the
presentation of stylized facts, employed to give the appearance of
empiricism. True academic debate, such as that between Harvard's
Caroline Hoxby and Princeton's Jesse Rothstein over Hoxby's
empirical assessment of the importance of school competition, was
sufficiently important to make it onto the front page of the Wall Street
Journal (October 24, 2005) but somehow is not appropriate to be
mentioned in textbooks.
A learned professor with refined (or yellowed) classroom notes
might argue that current theoretical works and empirical methods of
investigation are beyond the grasp of the typical 18- to 22-year old.
However, students are aware of the idea of the complex dynamics of chaos
theory from movies such as the schizophrenic thriller "[pi],"
where Max says, "If you graph the numbers of any system, patterns
emerge; therefore, there are patterns everywhere in nature ... So what
about the stock market? A universe of numbers that represents the global
economy ... " A similar theme appears in Tom Stoppard's play,
Arcadia. An anthology by Watts (2003) provides nearly a hundred passages
from both classic and contemporary literature and drama dealing with a
wide range of economic concepts and issues. Contemporary movies like
"[pi]" and plays like Arcadia can engage the general movie and
theater-going population with current economic ideas.
For example, following the showing of Max's clip from
"[pi]," macroeconomics students who have had some exposure to
probability theory can be challenged by Mathews' (2000, pp.
242-246) "urn activities" to show the "Polyaprocess"
in which multiple equilibria result from a stochastic time process
involving the sequential drawing and replacing of balls based on a
stochastic decision rule. Mathews (2001) places the importance of this
classroom experiment in an economic context through examples drawn from
history.
Learned professors accustomed to only chalk and talk teaching
methods might also ague that the idea of a Pareto equilibrium is a
theoretical concept not to be observed in the real world. But, again,
turning to the movies, consider the blonde-in-the-bar clip from "A
Beautiful Mind." I have used this clip as a motivational tool to
establish the connection between Adam Smith's invisible hand and
John Nash's recognition of the role of cooperation with
heterogeneous student bodies consisting of both entry-level university
students and advanced graduate students. (8) I sandwich this clip
between Charles Holt's (1996) trading-pit simulation (in which a
Smithian equilibrium results from students pursuing their individual
self-interest as demanders and suppliers) and Pickhardt's (2005)
extension of Holt and Laury's (1997) classroom simulation in which
a less than optimum non-cooperative equilibrium tends to dominate a Nash
cooperative equilibrium, which is the Pareto optimum.
VI. Textbooks
Colander (2004) tells how he entered into textbook writing with an
ambition to change the way economics is taught, with among other things
an emphasis on complexity and dynamic processes. To market books he
describes how he was led by reviewers and editors to follow the standard
static framework of market clearing prices and AS/AD. He stated that
instructors must recognize that textbooks do not represent what the
author knows or believes:
a text(book) is not a direct expression of what the author
believes, but instead a combination of a much more complicated set
of considerations in which inertia and processes, not intellectual
or even pedagogical validity, play the central roles ... users of
the books should be aware that that's what principles of economics
textbooks are, and structure their teaching accordingly, adding
context to the discussion whenever possible. (39)
Although some textbook authors and their publishers may be
pandering to the remedial approach of many college introductory courses
that are taught as secondary-school courses masquerading as much more,
it is refreshing to read how Carolyn Shaw Bell (2004) responded in her
early days of teaching at Wellesley College when she was assigned to a
consumer economics course for which she found the requisite content
dreadful. Instead of taking the easy road and going along with material
in the textbooks of the day, she "refused to admit this body of
prejudice, misinformation and ninth-grade arithmetic into my field of
economics," and began an inquiry into the subject that has lasted
over 20 years. This defiance is yet another illustration of how students
in institutions of higher education benefit from having a
research-oriented economist teach an introductory class versus a docent
who can only parrot what is in the textbook or on some standardized
multiple-choice test. It is the instructor's job to bring his or
her students current thinking and up-to-date debate going on in the
science of economics.
Many intermediate and advanced economics textbook authors present
without question the tenets of expected utility theory, even though the
work of Nobel Laureate Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky demonstrates
that decision-makers have trouble with the concept of probability and
the valuation of expected gains and losses. (9) The Allais paradox
(which is named after Maurice Allais, the 1988 Nobel Prize in economics recipient) can be used to demonstrate the trouble people have ordering
uncertain prospects in a way that is independent of irrelevant
alternatives--a critical postulate for von Neumann and
Morgenstern's expected utility theory. (10)
One of the insights that Kahneman and Tversky had was that choice
problems are usually described in terms of gains and losses, but the
utility functions that were supposed to explain the choices were defined
in terms of absolute levels. Similar to Harry Markowitz, who won the
Nobel Prize in economics in 1990, they decided to adopt changes and/or
differences as the sources of utility, which provided the foundation for
their "prospect theory," as used in "behavioral
economics" today. Prospect theory replaces the notion of
"utility" with "value," which is defined in terms of
gains and losses as deviations from a reference point. The value
function for losses is convex and relatively steep, but for gains, it is
concave and not quite so steep. In addition, Kahneman and Tversky
replaced the probability factor for each preference with a subjective
"decision weight" that tends to overweight small probabilities
and underweight moderate and high probabilities."
I hear instructors employing traditional textbook economics saying:
"students will not understand these calculations !" To those
instructors, I ask: what do you think they are teaching in psychology?
VIII. Enough Is Enough!
Becker and Greene (2004) give numerous other ways in which the
contributions of the Nobel Laureates in economics can be used to bring
more current thinking into the classroom so I will stop with those
examples here. An instructor does not have to endorse dynamic analysis,
complexity, prospect theory, the more general theories of bounded
rationality, or delve into the intricacies of probability theory in
decision-making, but those teaching economics today can no longer ignore
this work even if the textbooks do. Students are no longer confined to
what is in textbooks. The Internet provides them with up-to-date data,
headlines, commentary and academics' views on the economy and
current events. (12)
I am not calling for anything like Nobel Laureate Richard
Feynman's dismissal of pre-1920 ideas in his teaching introductory
physics. Students need to know the historic rhetoric of economics to
communicate in economics, but that level of understanding does not
require an unquestioning belief that those concepts can be widely
applied in situations where research suggests that they come up short.
As reflected in the work of the Nobel Laureates in economics and other
well recognized modern day economists, much has been learned to amend,
clarify and in some cases replace ideas of old. The process of modifying
and replacing the old with the new involves argument and debate. It is
contentious.
An economist might rightfully ask why academic economists are not
already bringing controversy into their classrooms, if it is desired? In
the case of probability and decision-making, Christopher Sims (2001, p.
53) states that few economists have been taught--and thus they have not
given thought to--the differences and similarities among different
definitions of probability, chance and risk and how people behave when
confronted with ambiguity and uncertainty. In the case of teaching
techniques appropriate for showing controversy, it may be that academic
economists do not know what activities are available to teach these new
ideas, since they have never seen them in practice in the teaching of
economics. As Gail Hoyt (2003) states, possibly academic economists have
not embraced these new ideas and teaching methods because they are
experience goods: anticipated high start-up costs keep risk-averse
economists from trying them. Finally, it might be that less-than-secure
instructors are fearful of end-of-term student evaluations. (13)
Regardless of the reason for lack of innovation in teaching, ideas
in the science of economics, no matter how entrenched, must be
questioned in a classroom devoted to higher learning. As with other
sciences, there are no divinely sanctioned laws that are beyond
question. Students need to learn that the very nature of a science is to
have unresolved topics and an on-going scrutiny of theories no matter
how steeped they are in tradition. The dumbing down of economics to the
dogmatic preaching of a few simple concepts, principles, and axioms of
old misses the excitement of modern day economics and is a deceitful
representation of the science of economics and a disservice to students
seeking a higher education.
References
Allais, Maurice. 1953. Fondements d'une Theorie Positive des
Choix Comportant un Risque et Critique des Postulats et Axioms de
L'Ecole Americane. Dordrecht: Reidel.
Anderson, Simon and Maxim Engers. 2002. "A Beautiful Blonde: A
Nash Coordination Game." Working Paper, University of Virginia
(July).
Bandler, James and Nathan Koppel. 2005. "Raising the Bar: Even
Top Lawyers Fail California Exam." Wall Street Journal, December 5.
Becker, Gary. 1965. "A Theory of the Allocation of Time."
Economic Journal, (September): 493-517. Reprinted in Gary S. Becker.
1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Becker, William E. 1979. "Professorial Behavior Given a
Stochastic Reward Structure" American Economic Review, 69
(December): 1010-1017.
Becker, William E. 2003. "Undergraduate Choice: Sexy or
Non-Sexy." Southern Economic Journal, 70 (1): 219-223.
Becker, William E. 2004a. "Economics for a Higher
Education." International Review of Economics Education, 3 (1):
52-62.
Becker, William E. 2004b. "Good-Bye Old, Hello New in Teaching
Economics." Australasian Journal of Economics Education, 1 (1):
5-17.
Becker, William E. and Moya Andrews. 2004. The Scholarship of
Teaching and Learning in Higher Education: Contributions of Research
Universities. Bloomington: Indiana University Press. Becker, William E.
and William Greene. 2004. "Bringing Advanced Quantitative Methods
into the Undergraduate Computer Classroom." in The Scholarship of
Teaching and Learning in Higher Education: Contributions of Research
Universities, W. Becker and M. Andrews, eds. Bloomington: Indiana
University Press, 2004: 99-129; with an abridged version appearing as
"Using the Nobel Laureates in Economics to Teach Quantitative
Methods." Journal of Economic Education, 36 (3), 2005: 261-277.
Becker, William E., William Greene and Sherwin Rosen. 1990.
"Research on High School Economic Education." American
Economic Review P&P, 80(2): 14-23, and an expanded version in
Journal of Economic Education, 21(3): 231-253.
Begley, Sharon. 2005a. "Yes, Evolution Still Has Unanswered
Questions; That's How Science Is" Wall Street Journal June 3:
B1.
Begley, Sharon. 2005b. "Physicists Are Asking: Are
Universe's Traits Random or Inevitable?" Wall Street Journal
September 16: B1.
Bell, Carolyn Shaw. 2004. "Thinking about Economics." in
Michael Szenberg and Lall Ramrattan, eds. Reflections of Eminent
Economists. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar: 38-62.
Calian, Sara and Steve Stecklow. 2002. "In Britain, Getting a
Driver's License Can Be a Royal Pain--The Exam Is So Harrowing That
Many Give Up?' Wall Street Journal, October 30: A1+.
Card, David and Alan B. Krueger. 1997. Myth and Measurement: The
New Economics of the Minimum Wage. Princeton NJ: Princeton University.
Colander, David. 2004. "Caveat Lector: Living with the 15%
Rule." Australasian Journal of Economics Education, 1 (1): 30-40.
El Boghdady, Dina and Mike Musgrove. 2003. "Prices Play
'How Low Can You Go?'" San Francisco Chronicle, December
29: E2.
Ferraro, Paul and Laura Taylor. 2005. "Do Economists Recognize
an Opportunity Cost When They See One? A Dismal Performance from the
Dismal Science." The B.E. Journals in Economic Analysis &
Policy, 4(1): Article 7
Field, Kelly. 2006. "American Colleges Must Change to Compete
in the Global Economy, Speakers Tell Panel on Future of Higher
Education." Chronicle of Higher Education, February 3,
http://chronicle.com/daily/2006/02/ 2006020302n.htm.
Fuchs, Victor. 2004. "Education and its Consequences: My
Philosophy of Life." in Michael Szenberg and Lall Ramrattan, eds.
Reflections of Eminent Economists. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar:
178-189.
Gleick, James 1992. Genius: The Life and Science of Richard
Feynman. New York: Vintage Books.
Hansen, W. Lee, Michael Salemi and John Siegfried. 2002.
"Promoting Economic Literacy in the Introductory Economics
Course." American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 92 (2):
463-472.
Holt, Charles. 1996. "Classroom Games: Trading in a Pit
Market?' Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10 (1): 193-204.
Holt, Charles and Susan Laury. 1997. "Classroom Games:
Voluntary Provision of a Public Good." Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 11 (4): 209-216.
Hoyt, Gail. 2003. "How to Make Economics the Fulfilling Social
Science." Southern Economic Journal 70 (1): 216-218.
Jayson, Sharon. 2005. "Charles Miller Invests Himself:
Reformer Turns Focus to Higher Education-Testing for College
Students?" USA Today, December 8:D8
Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky. 1979. "Intuitive
Prediction: Biases and Corrective Procedures." Studies in
Management Science, 12: 313-327.
Keen, Steve. 2002. Debunking Economics: The Naked Emperor of the
Social Sciences. Annandale, Australia: Pluto Press.
Levitt, Steven D. and Stephen J. Dubner. 2005. Freakonomics: A
Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything. New York, New
York: Haper Collins.
Lewis, Ben E. 1970. "A Retrospective Look at Undergraduate
Economics." Journal of Economic Education, 2 (1): 5-13.
List, John. 2003. "Does Market Experience Eliminate Market
Anomalies?" Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 (1), February:
41-71.
Malinvaud, Edmond. 2004. "Some Ethical and Mythological
Convictions." in Michael Szenberg and Lall Ramrattan, eds.
Reflections of Eminent Economists. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar:
275-297.
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 1998. Principles of Microeconomics. Fort Worth:
Harcourt.
Mathews, Peter. 2000. "Toward the Complexification of
Statistics and Econometrics Curricula," in David Colander, ed. The
Complexity Vision and the Teaching of Economics. Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar: 231-254.
Mathews, Peter. 2001. "Positive Feedback and Path Dependence
Using the Law of Large Numbers." Journal of Economic Education, 32
(2): 124-136.
McKeachie, Wilbert. 1997. "Student Ratings: The Validity of
Use." American Psychologist, 52 (11): 1218-1225.
O'Rourke, P. J. 1999. Eat the Rich: A Treatise on Economics.
New York: Atlantic Monthly Press.
Pickhardt, Michael. 2005. "On Teaching Public Goods Theory
with a Classroom Game." Journal of Economic Education, 36 (2):
145-159.
Sims, Christopher. 2001. "Pitfalls of a Minimax Approach to
Model Uncertainty." American Economic Review Papers and
Proceedings, 91 (2): 51-54.
Starmer, Chris. 2000. "Developments in Non-Expected Utility
Theory: The Hunt for a Descriptive Theory of Choice Under Risk?'
Journal of Economic Literature, 38 (2):332-382.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1987. "The Cause and Consequences of the
Dependence of Quality and Price." Journal of Economic Literacy, 25
(10): 1-48.
Watts, Michael, ed. 2003. The Literary Book of Economics.
Wilmington, Delaware: ISI Books.
Zahka, William. 1999. "Acceptance Speeches by the Nobel
Laureates in Economics." in William Becker and Michael Watts, eds.
Teaching Economics to Undergraduates: Alternatives to Chalk and Talk.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar: 209-224.
Notes
(1.) Some might think that I am making a mountain out of a molehill
in arguing that there are those in positions of authority who would like
to see higher education become more like high school education. But, as
chairman of the Board of Regents of the University of Texas System Board
of Regents, business executive Charles Miller introduced system-wide
testing of college students, similar to the high-stakes testing used in
public schools. Miller is credited with being a driving force behind the
Texas public-school accountability system that is based on standardized
tests and which became the national education model for the George Bush
administration, Jayson (2005, 8D). In 2005, Miller was selected by
Margaret Spellings, U.S. Secretary of Education, to head the newly
formed Commission on Higher Education, with the expectation that his
committee would recommend testing of college students similar to that
being implemented in the University of Texas System, Field (2006).
(2.) Becker and Andrews (2004) provide examples to show that higher
education involves much more than the teaching of traditional doctrine.
It is the academic inquiry that elevates higher education above mere
training. They argue that at a research university instruction has the
potential to be enhanced because it can be made a part of an integrated
and aggressive campaign of inquiry. Active researchers can engage
students in the challenging ideas, questions and methods of inquiry at
the forefront of their disciplines, whereas docents can be expected only
to teach that which they have been taught or learned from textbooks.
They call attention to the fact that research is expensive and that
public community colleges with no research mission have thrived under
the belief that a faculty devoted to research is not essential to
performing the less-expensive teaching function. A contextual updating
of Gresham's law (inferior currency drives out superior currency)
might suggest that the less expensive educational practices of community
colleges will force out the more expensive fulltime, tenured faculty
members teaching at the research universities. As Becker and Andrews
demonstrate, there is evidence of this happening with both public
research and doctoral institutions increasing the proportions of both
part-time and full-time faculty members with non-tenure track
appointments. Following the community college model, universities are
increasingly looking to part-time and non-tenure track docent-type
appointments to teach in undergraduate baccalaureate programs.
Unfortunately, Gresham's law in this context is just as deficient
in assessing effects as it is for monetary policy.
(3.) The idea (or law) that the demand and supply functions can be
isolated to show how changes lead to a competitive equilibria (in which
the quantities demanded and supplied are necessarily equated in textbook
fashion) is so simplistic that there is an old joke about training (not
educating) a parrot to be an economist by teaching it to repeat two
words "demand" and "supply."
(4.) A few of years ago I presented a version of Becker (1979) in
which the shadow prices of teaching, research and leisure were derived
to be a function of several parameters in joint production processes
with no simple tradeoff between teaching and research. After the
presentation someone who taught introductory and intermediate economics
asked, "why didn't you consider the opportunity costs of
teaching and research?" Ferraro and Taylor (2005) report on
economists attending the Allied Social Science Association meetings not
being able to correctly identify the opportunity cost in the following
hypothetical situation:
You won a free ticket to see an Eric Clapton concert (which has no
resale value). Bob Dylan is performing on the same night and is your
next-best alternative activity. Tickets to see Dylan cost $40. On any
given day, you would be willing to pay up to $50 to see Dylan. Assume
there are no other costs of seeing either performer. Based on this
information, what is the opportunity cost of seeing Eric Clapton?
They conclude that although the concept of opportunity cost is
covered in the first week of an introductory undergraduate course,
it is incorrectly deemed to be so straightforward as to not require
further teaching time. They also observe that it is not contained
in graduate textbooks and clearly should be. They quote a survey
responder from a top-20 Ph.D. economics program saying: "When would
I have learned the concept of opportunity cost? I don't remember
hearing that word used in graduate school."
Could it be that the old idea of opportunity cost is too simplistic
to have any true meaning in real decision making? Could it be that the
science of economics has moved beyond this simplistic bivariate relative
pricing idea? Could it be that graduate textbooks, as in my presentation
on the shadow prices of teaching and research, have correctly given up
on the introductory economics course idea of an opportunity cost in
favor of more useful measures of price? Alternatively, why is there such
a divide between undergraduate and graduate education in economics?
Could it be that those at the forefront of research in economics and
teaching in prestigious graduate programs are misleading their students?
These are not rhetorical questions--I seriously do not have the answers.
(5.) David Ricardo advanced the idea of comparative advantage some
200 years ago. It requires that the production technologies and
resources of the trading partners remain in place--for example, one
parcel of land is fixed and owned by one country and another piece of
land is fixed and owned by another country. Unlike climate and
geography, in today's world both capital and technology are not
fixed; they quickly can be moved from one country to another. As a
result, even if the U.S. has an advantage in the electronic processing
of insurance forms today, that technology (as well as related
technologies as we have seen) can quickly be moved to India for even
greater cost savings. To say that the U.S. has a comparative advantage
in processing forms requires the assumption that this technology is
fixed to the U.S., which students know from TV viewing and Web surfing
to be nonsense. The assumed static world of Ricardo versus the dynamics
of technological change cannot be ignored.
(6.) Students see articles such as that in Business Week "The
Nitty-Gritty: How to Do the Math" (January 17, 2000, p. 110), which
stated "Happily, about 96% of any one company's risk can be
eliminated simply by owning a diversified portfolio ..." Such
headlines can be used to ask students why employees of a company would
be wise not to own stock in that company, or why career specialization
is risky?
(7.) In reviewing a draft of this paper, Bill Goggin observed that
a standardized test, if it is not designed to reinforce the incorrect
notion that there are immutable principles in economics, would have to
explore a student's understanding of the underlying assumptions and
what happens to the so-called unassailable prediction when those
assumptions are not met. But since that is not the way economics is
often taught, many students would likely fail such a test--Catch-22!!!
(8.) Anderson and Engers (2002) correctly point out that the Nash
equilibrium portrayed in the movie (all the men including Nash ignore
the blonde) is not a sustainable equilibrium because given the
strategies of the others Nash himself could score by going for the
blonde--as pointed out by one of his male friends in the bar. Given
sufficient desirability of the blond, no heterosexual male will be
willing to let her walk, unescorted, so any one of them could expect to
score given the strategy of the other males.
(9.) In the 1970s, Tversky and Kahneman set out to construct a
theory to explain the Allais paradox (Allais, 1953), which involves
behavior that contradicts the independence axiom and linear probability
calculations in expected utility theory. The arithmetic can be
demonstrated in an introductory economics class by asking each student
to consider two situations (A and B), each involving a choice between
two gambles:
Situation A: Which do you choose--Gamble A1 or A2?
Gamble A1 promises a sure win of $30;
Gamble A2 is a 80% chance to win $45 and 20% chance of $0.
Situation B: Which do you choose--Gamble B 1 or B2?
Gamble B1 promises a 25% chance of winning $30,
Gamble B2 is a 20% chance to win $45.
Situation B differs from situation A only in that one-quarter of
the original probability of winning a positive amount can be realized.
Yet, the majority of students typically will prefer A1 to A2 and prefer
B2 to B 1. Thus, the paradox is demonstrated by actually engaging the
students in the choice process.
A von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function and the implied
preference reversal of the Allais paradox can be demonstrated by asking
each student who said that A1 is preferred to A2 and B2 is preferred to
B1 to assign utility values to the two basic outcomes of wining $45 or
nothing and then to state the implied utility limits for $30. For
example, a student who says u(0) = 0 and u(45) = 1.00 is implying that
u(30) = v, for 0 < v < 1. Expected utility can now be introduced
as the sum of utility outcomes weighted by their respective
probabilities:
Gamble A1 promises a sure win of $30, so EU = 1.0(v) + 0(0) = v
Gamble A2 is a 80% chance to win $45, so EU = 0.8(1) + .2(0) = 0.8
If A1 is preferred to A2, then v > 0.8
Lottery B1 promises a 25% chance of winning $30, so EU = 0.25(v)
+.75(0) = 0.25v
Lottery B2 is a 20% chance to win $45. so EU=0.2(1)+.8(0) = 0.20
If B2 is preferred to B 1, then v < 0.8
Kahneman states that the apparent contradiction in this implied
utility is not a demonstration of stupidity but a much more interesting
issue: the susceptibility to erroneous intuitions about uncertainty and
probability.
(10.) Allais's problem is a demonstration that the subjective
response to probability is not necessarily linear. The difference
between probabilities of 0.25 and 0.35 in decision-making is not as
relevant as the difference between 0 and 0.10, or between .90 and 1.00.
Furthermore, via questioning of students in the classroom, what Kahneman
and Tversky (1979) call "reflection" and "loss
aversion" can be demonstrated: changing the signs of all outcomes
in a pair of gambles almost always caused the preference to change from
risk averse to risk seeking, or vice versa. For example, the majority of
students in a class typically preferred a sure gain of $900 to a .9
probability of gaining $1,000 (or nothing), but they preferred a gamble
with a .9 probability of losing $1,000 over a sure loss of $900.
(11.) For a review of alternative decision theories see Starmer
(2000). "Can people learn to be as rational as economic theory
supposes," The Economist (Aug 30-Sept 5, 2003, p. 56.) provides an
excellent discussion of some of the research supporting
behavioralists' views versus the newer research (by John List 2003)
supporting neoclassical theory that even introductory students can
understand.
(12.) Surfing the Web, students will find less than favorable
critiques of textbook economics--for example, Yoram Bauman puts the boot
into Mankiw's 10 principles of economics at
http://www.improb.com/airchives/paperair/ volume9/v9i2/mankiw.html. They
will find entire journals devoted to showing the fragility of simplistic
economics concepts--e.g., the online Post-Autistic Economics Review
started by the French students' protest against neoclassical
economics http://www.paecon.net. A trip to the library will uncover
Steve Keen's (2002) controversial book Debunking Economics: The
Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences, which could have been more
accurately titled Debunking Textbook Economics. Keen also maintains an
extensive Website at http://www.debunking-economics.com, as do other
controversial liberal and conservative academic economists, such as Brad
DeLong, at University of California Berkeley,
http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/ movable_type/or Tyler Cowen and Alex
Taborrok, at George Mason University, http://
www.marginalrevolution.com.
(13.) Psychologist McKeachie (1997) states: "Many students
prefer teaching that enables them to listen passively--teaching that
organizes the subject matter for them and that prepares them well for
tests ... research, however, points to better retention, thinking, and
motivational effects when students are more actively involved in
talking, writing, and doing ... Thus, some teachers get high ratings for
teaching in less than ideal ways" (p. 1219)
William E. Becker is Professor of Economics, Indiana University
Bloomington, Department of Economics, 105 Wylie Hall, Indiana
University, Bloomington IN 47405, Adjunct Professor of Commerce,
University of South Australia, Editor, Journal of Economic Education and
Editor, SSRN Economic Research Network Educator. This work is an
extension of and uses material in Becker (2003, 2004a and 2004b). It was
delivered as the 2005-2006 Presidential Address, Midwest Economic
Association Annual Meeting, Chicago IL, March 25, 2006. Email:
[email protected].