Heterodox Analysis of Financial Crisis and Reform: History, Politics and Economics.
Bracker, Kevin S.
Heterodox Analysis of Financial Crisis and Reform: History,
Politics and Economics, edited by Joelle J. Leclaire, Tae-Hee Jo and
Jane E. Knodell, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc., 2011.
The 2008-09 financial crisis is a topic rich in potential for
research, analysis and potential lessons. While there are already many
books and articles, within both academics and the popular press,
addressing the financial crisis, this book takes an alternative
perspective. Heterodox economics refers to economic ideas that are
outside the mainstream that includes such ideas as post-Keynesian,
Marxism, institutionalism, etc. By looking at the financial crisis
through this lens, the editors and authors strive to seek new insights
and challenge some mainstream views. Robert Pollin states in his
foreword: "There is certainly a wide range of thinking incorporated
within heterodoxy itself, as the chapters in this book attest. But as
regards the financial system, the heterodox tradition is unified in the
conclusion developed through generations of research, debate and
rethinking--that capitalist economies operating without significant
regulations will inevitably produce instability and crisis." The
book's genesis can be traced back to the 4th bi-annual Cross-Border
Post Keynesian Conference at Buffalo State College, NY where over 50
scholars presented their work on the theme of Financial Crisis and
Reform. From these presentations, twelve essays covering various aspects
of the Financial Crisis were selected for inclusion in the book. The
essays are grouped into three themes: (1) Financial Crisis and Reform
(chapters 1-2), (2) History and Political Economy of Financial Crisis
(chapters 3-6), and (3) Theoretical Analyses of Financial Crisis
(chapters 7-12).
"Difficulties in reregulation of the financial system after
the crisis" by Jan Kregel focuses on the regulatory environment
that was in place leading to the financial crisis. Kregel argues that it
was not the lack of regulation, but the failure of regulations to be
applied and poorly designed regulations, that were responsible for much
of the behavior that led to the crisis. This is an informative article
that illustrates the difficulty of creating and applying effective
regulations in a complex environment where the parties being regulated
have the ability (and financial incentive) to work around the
regulation. The one drawback of this article was that, while it
identified the problems of the regulatory environment, it would have
been nice to see more along the lines of recommendations or solutions
for going forward.
"Public policy to support retirement: an alternative to
financialization" by Yeva Nersisyan and L. Randall Wray examines
the role pension funds in public policy. They note that from 1947 to the
present, private pension funds have gone from being predominately
invested in bonds to being predominately invested in equities. Public
pension funds have followed a similar pattern. In addition, they
highlight the fact that pension funds have increased in size relative to
the economy, peaking at about 75 percent of GDP in the
early-2000's. Judging by the provided graph, they fell to a little
under 50 percent of GDP in 2008. Nersisyan and Wray argue that this
increased financialization of pension assets leads to financial bubbles
and that "managed money, taken as a whole, is too large to be
supported by the nation's ability to produce output and income
..." Next they argue that investors, on average, will not be able
to earn higher than risk-free returns and therefore all pension fund
assets should go into Treasury debt. However, this is still not
sufficient. They suggest that employer-based pension plans are not
well-suited to "current and future realities" and that private
savings plans are also problematic--"And even if individuals tried
to do so, there is no reason to believe that they would not be duped out
of their savings by unscrupulous financial institutions selling risky
investments. There is also the aggregate paradox of thrift: trying to
save more for retirement leads to lower income and employment and thus
no increase of saving." Therefore, "the best solution would be
to eliminate government support for pension plans and private savings
and instead boost Social Security to ensure that anyone who works long
enough to qualify will receive a comfortable retirement."
Apparently funding for Social Security is not a problem as "Social
Security is a federal government program, and as such it cannot become
insolvent. All payments can be made as they come due, even if benefits
become more generous." How private savings will lower income and
employment, but funding for Social Security benefits escape this
drawback is beyond this reviewer. The argument for pension plans
investing solely in Treasury debt also seems inconsistent with my
understanding of risk premiums and long-run returns of equities vs.
Treasuries.
"Those who forget the past are condemned to repeat it: lessons
learned from past financial crisis that were ignored by the deregulators
of the past 15 years" by Robert W. Dimand and Robert H. Koehn
examines the works of Veblin, Keynes and Fisher to provide historical
context from past financial crisis to the recent financial crisis. By
looking at past speculative bubbles and lessons learned by scholars who
were active at those times, they argue that the 2008-09 crisis could
have been averted. Deregulation, lack of transparency, and too much
leverage led, predictably, down the path to speculative excess and the
inevitable bust that followed. Whether you agree or disagree with the
conclusion, the paper does a good job of providing historical context to
the recent problems and makes a compelling argument.
"Panics and depressions: a historical analysis of 1907, 1929,
and 2008" by William T. Ganley, like the previous chapter, explores
the recent financial crisis in a historical context. While the
presentation of each crisis is necessarily brief, they are done well and
provide the reader with a chance to see the similarities and
differences. One conclusion, that echoes an idea raised in the first
chapter of the book, is that government responses (regulation) tend to
be more responsive to what has happened and less effective for dealing
with what will happen in the future. Another conclusion, which we are
seeing play out, is that recovery from severe financial panics is a
long-term process.
"The instability of financial markets: a critique of efficient
markets theory" by Robert A. Prasch takes aim at one of the
hallmarks of financial theory. The initial attack is based on a logical
contradiction. Specifically, if markets are efficient, why do so many
smart people spend so much time and effort trying to find opportunities?
I would counter this by arguing that market efficiency need not be a
binary variable where prices are 100 percent efficient or meaningless.
While there can be some debate on the degree of market efficiency, the
argument that "smart money" may not always lead to efficient
and self-stabilizing prices is worth raising. The author also argues
that it is not just uncertainty that may lead to inefficient pricing and
thus market instability, but also systematic institutional pressures
that lead to speculative excesses and instability.
"Sismondi, Marx and Veblen: precursors of Keynes" by John
F. Henry examines the similarities of the works of Sismondi, Marx and
Veblen to Keynes and argues that these authors may provide more insights
in addressing potential problems of capitalism than Keynes. While this
may be an informative article comparing the works of economists, it
seems out of place in this text. While there is a connection in that the
economists in question are known for their critiques of certain aspects
of capitalism, I would like to see more discussion of the 2008-09
financial crisis in particular rather than capitalism in general.
"Money manager capitalism, financialization and structural
forces" by Yan Liang covers similar territory to Nersisyan and
Wray's article that comprised chapter two. The emphasis here is on
the idea that intermediation from pension funds and mutual funds leads
to increased complexity and financial power in the hands of these
institutions. This in turn leads to economic instability. Liang notes
that private pension fund assets have increased from $11 billion in 1952
to over $6 trillion in 2007. As in the Nersisyan and Wray paper, Liang
notes the significantly lower emphasis on bonds and greater emphasis on
equities and alternative investments over time. Liang also notes that
the top 10 percent of families by income level have seen significant
growth in both the mean and median levels of financial assets while the
bottom 20 percent of families have seen no growth in median levels and
much lower growth (relative to the top 10 percent) in mean levels of
financial assets from 1989 to 2007. In addition, mutual funds have
increased significantly as a share of household financial assets (from
less than 1 percent in the 1980's to nearly 10 percent in 2008)
while deposits have declined (from over 25 percent to around 16 percent)
during the same time period. Further discussion is focused on the
increased complexity of financial instruments and the lack of sufficient
regulation. Liang states "The birth and growth of 'financial
weapons of mass destruction' is a joint product of the
'innovative' financial engineers and the lenient financial
regulators." This chapter provides an interesting critique on the
role of finance, and particularly financial innovation, in an economy.
"Engineering pyramid Ponzi finance: the evolution of private
finance from 1970 to 2008 and implications for regulation" by Eric
Tymoigne furthers the discussion on the role of finance in the household
and, in turn, the economy. Here, the purpose is to discuss the emergence
of Ponzi finance and regulatory changes that would help reduce the
inherent instability while encouraging economic growth. As with previous
chapters, the role of growth in both size and complexity of financial
institutions and instruments plays an important role in the thesis. The
Ponzi finance system is defined as one where cash flows from operations
are insufficient to cover expected debt services and instead rely on
refinancing or increased asset prices. This was the nature of many real
estate loans made leading up to the financial crisis. To reduce this
problem, two regulatory changes are proposed. First, focus loans on the
ability to repay from cash flows and relegate collateral to a secondary
role. Second, have a government agency that must approve financial
innovations and periodically check that it does not fall into Ponzi
practices. The problem with both of these proposals is enforcement. They
require regulatory bodies with enough information, foresight, technical
expertise, political power, and resources to effectively regulate the
institutions under their supervision. They also must not be too
restrictive to prevent valid innovation, which can be a fine line to
walk. As was suggested in chapters one and four of this text, having
regulations is not sufficient. Being able to enforce the regulations and
having the right regulations is easier said than done. Having said that,
the issues raised in this article make a positive contribution to the
discussion on the role of regulation of the financial system.
"A heterodox microfoundation of business cycles' by
Tae-Hee Jo seeks to introduce more of a role for social relations into
understanding of business cycles. Specifically, the author compares
Schumpeter's Instability Thesis with Minsky's Financial
Instability Hypothesis and then moves to a micro view of business
cycles. While it may be due to my background being more in finance
rather than economics, this chapter did little to enhance my
understanding of the financial crisis.
"Business competition and the 2007-08 financial crisis: a Post
Keynesian approach" by Tuna Baskoy examines the role of competition
on the financial crisis. Baskoy sees a cycle in which firms try to
maintain profit margins. However, as conditions change to reduce
margins, competition increases which leads to higher risk and ultimately
bankruptcy, withdrawals from the market and rising unemployment. The
chapter does an excellent job of using news reports, banking industry
data, and quotes from executives to illustrate how the banking
environment at the time fit the model of competition that is introduced
at the start. The author introduces a model, illustrates the model with
a real world example that was one of the prime components of the
financial crisis, and a well-written conclusion.
"The global crisis and the future of the dollar: toward
Bretton Woods 3?" by Jorg Bibow discusses global currency markets
in a framework of repeated Bretton Woods agreements. The author starts
with the "Bretton Woods 2" hypothesis that "a
quasi-permanent US current account deficit may be sustainable."
From there, "Bretton Woods 3" is introduced where "US
public debt replaces private debt" and fiscal policies of lower
taxation and higher government spending kick-start the economy and
deficit spending (although at lower rates than immediately following the
financial crisis) are financed through high demand for US Treasuries.
The discussion then moves to a potential "Bretton Woods 4."
The key takeaway is the argument that fiscal deficits may be sustainable
for the intermediate term.
The final chapter "Exchange rate regimes and the impact of the
global crisis on emerging economies" by Alfredo Castillo Polanco
and Ted P. Schmidt examines what types of exchange rate regimes (ERR)
work best for developing economies in dealing with external shocks--such
as the financial crisis originating in the US. The authors develop
"a short run Post Keynesian macro model for developing countries
with non-substitution between domestic production and imports."
Their results indicate that "the more flexible the ERR, the more
harmful the impact on the domestic economy" and that "the
central bank should intervene to reduce the depreciation of the domestic
currency."
As someone approaching this from the perspective of finance with an
interest in looking at some non-mainstream (heterodox) discussion of the
financial crisis, I found this book to be a bit hit-or-miss. Some
chapters did an excellent job of presenting information regarding
regulatory environments, history of previous financial crises, or the
role of financialization which added to my understanding of the 2008-09
financial crisis. While I may not have always agreed with the
conclusions, the authors raised valid concerns and criticisms. However,
there were other chapters which I thought were not as well developed or
did not directly address the financial crisis. There were also chapters,
and this is no fault of the editors or authors, that were outside my
area of expertise or interest as they tried to cover a wider range of
topics. For those who want to look at the financial crisis from an
alternative point of view, this book does offer some insightful
chapters. However, unless you have a significant interest in the
heterodox literature (either from a teaching or research perspective),
there are other books on the financial crisis that are both more
accessible and provide more insight into the specifics of the financial
crisis.
KEVIN S. BRACKER
Kelce College of Business
Pittsburg State University