The economic impact of migration: a survey.
Drinkwater, Stephen ; Levine, Paul ; Lotti, Emanuela 等
Abstract
This survey reviews both theoretical and empirical papers that
examine the economic effects of labour mobility. We address three broad
sets of issues: firstly, the effect that immigration has on the host
country's labour market. Although the possible adverse effects that
immigration can have on the wage and employment levels of natives are
typically examined, immigration may also have a role to play in raising
skill levels. This leads to the second broad issue: the effect of
migration of a particular skill composition on the long-term
(endogenous) growth of the host country. Finally, immigration can have a
major economic impact on the source country. These effects can either be
positive or negative depending on the interplay between the effects of
growth, remittances and the brain drain.
INTRODUCTION
Immigration is one of the most important issues in the contemporary
global economy. (1) It is estimated by the United Nations that over 175
million people now reside outside the country of their birth. This
clearly has major economic and political implications for both the
sending and receiving countries. Coppel et al. (2001) identify four
major of international population movements. Firstly, there is the
effect that immigration has on the host country's labour market.
Although the possible adverse effects that immigration can have on the
wage and employment levels of natives are typically examined,
immigration may also have a role to play in reducing skill shortages in
certain key sectors of the economy. Secondly, immigration is likely to
influence the budgetary position of the receiving country because the
amount recent arrivals receive through health, education and welfare
systems is unlikely to exactly balance the increased tax revenues from
new workers. Thirdly, it is argued that immigration may be a solution to
the ageing population problem that faces many OECD countries. Finally,
immigration can have a major economic impact on the source country.
These effects can either be negative, in terms of a brain drain (though
a brain drain can be beneficial if it creates incentives for human
capital investment in the source country), or positive since
migrants' remittances are thought to be an important economic
development tool for many labour exporting countries. The overall
balance of these effects is therefore likely to have a major influence
on the immigration policies that are implemented, both in the source and
host countries.
In this survey we review the theoretical and empirical literature
on the economic effects of international migration, focusing in
particular on the influence that immigration can have on growth rates in
the host and source countries. Without some restriction, this is a vast
literature so some constraints must be placed on the scope of our
survey. First, we exclude any consideration of papers that study the
determinants of migration in an attempt to understand the pressures for
migration or migration equilibria. (2) The level of migration
(controlled or otherwise) is a given throughout this survey. Second,
where possible our empirical evidence relates to the European migration
experience. (3)
We structure the rest of the survey around four sections. Section 2
examines level effects based on the strictly static framework adopted by
Borjas (1995) and reviews papers where migration affects transitional
but not long-term growth. Section 3 then looks at a much smaller
literature on the effects of migration on long-term growth. The section
concludes with results from a current project involving the authors.
Section 4 discusses the policy implications that emerge from the papers
that have been surveyed and Section 5 concludes.
The Immigration Surplus
The immigration surplus is the term coined by Borjas (1995) to
refer to the increase in income of the indigenous population of the host
country following immigration. The simplest model to assess the
magnitude of the immigration surplus is as follows. Consider two blocs,
East and West, and assume that wages are perfectly flexible and labour
markets clear in both blocs. Further assume that the regions produce the
same composite output and the labour force is equal. Capital of both the
physical and human variety are given and higher in the West. Both
average and marginal output per worker are therefore higher in the West.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 1 shows what happens when migration from East to West
occurs. The Eastern workforce (fully employed by assumption) falls from
OA by an amount HA, increasing the Western workforce by the same amount
AB(=HA). The area under the marginal product of labour (MPL) curves give
total output and the MPL(West) is higher than its Eastern
counterpart--MPL(East)--because physical and human capital are higher in
the West. Ignoring human capital differences for the moment, then 1 unit
of Eastern labour is equivalent to 1 unit of Western labour. Output then
rises by an amount KDBA in the West and falls by an amount FJAH(=ECBA)
in the East. The increase in output is therefore given by the area KDCE.
The real wage falls in the West and rises in the East. If there are
costs associated with migration and migrants maximize income net of
costs, migration will cease before wages are equalized. Figure 1 shows
the case of factor price equalization, where migration costs are zero
and migration leads to equal wage rates. Migrants gain by an amount
EDCJ; non-migrants in the East see total output fall by an amount FJG.
The original Western population gains by an amount KDE--the immigration
surplus. This constitutes a total gain of [w.sub.W] KDw for Western
capitalists and a loss of [w.sub.W] KEw for Western workers. Similarly
the non-migrants in the East lose by an amount FGJ(=EJC); [wFGw.sub.E]
is a gain for Eastern workers and [wFJw.sub.E] is a loss for Eastern
capitalists. Thus the losers are the original Western workers and
Eastern capitalists; the winners are the migrants and Western
capitalists.
Borjas (1995) provides rough estimates of the immigration surplus
for the US, but in fact it could be any OECD country. Assume first that
all workers, East and West, are perfect substitutes. Suppose a host
workforce N expands to L = N + M, where M is the number of immigrants.
Then the immigration surplus is given by
S = [DELTA]w.M/2Y = (L[DELTA]w/w[DELTA]L) x (w/L) x ([DELTA]L.M/2Y)
= - 1/2 e [(wL/Y)(M/L).sup.2] = - 1/2 [esm.sup.2]
where we have put [DELTA]L = M (since all migrants find
employment), s is labour's share of national income, e is the
elasticity of the wage rate with respect to the labour force and m = M/L
is the proportion of migrants in the workforce (AB/0B in Figure 1).
Given that labour income accounts for around 70% of GDP for most
OECD countries, and just under 10% of the US (or German) workforce are
immigrants and the elasticity of the factor price of labour (capital
fixed) is thought to be around 0.3 (Hamermesh, 1993), Borjas puts s=0.7
and e=-0.3 to arrive at the pessimistic conclusion that a 10% increase
in the workforce through immigration increases US (or German) GDP by
only 0.105%. This net gain is accompanied by a 3% fall in the wage rate
and hence a not-insignificant redistribution from labour to capital.
Now consider immigration with wage rigidity. The general case of
some wage flexibility, which encompasses the case of full flexibility
above, is illustrated in Figure 2--taken from Levine (1999). The labour
supply curves (which, following Layard et al. (1992), we refer to as the
'bargained real wage' or BRW curves) and the labour demand
(MPL) curves are shown for the two blocs. Upward-sloping BRW curves are
consistent with a number of theories of wage determination including the
monopoly union model, bargaining and efficiency wage theories. As a
result of migration from East to West, with some real wage flexibility,
the BRW (W) shifts to the right and employment rises by WW'.
Similarly the BRW (E) shifts to the left and employment falls by
EE'.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The welfare implications of East-West migration--which we analyse
in more detail in the next section--can be assessed by comparing the
increase in Western output (HJWW') with the decrease in the East
(FGEE'). We have illustrated the case where WW', EE' and
the real wage flexibility in the two regions are about equal. Then the
net output gains are positive; in general, however, the output effects
are crucially dependent on the degree of real wage flexibility in the
two labour markets. To work out the immigration surplus, we put [DELTA]L
= [eta]M where [[eta].sub.i] [member of][0,1]--encompassing the cases of
complete wage flexibility [eta] = 1 and complete inflexibility [eta] = 0
. The immigration surplus now becomes
S = - 1/2 [esm.sup.2][[eta].sup.2] (1)
which provides an even more pessimistic outlook for the economic
benefits of migration for host residents.
The analysis up to now has assumed only one type of labour. Suppose
now the workforce in both blocs consists of skilled and unskilled labour
and output Y=f(K, L, H) in the host country, where L and H denote
skilled and unskilled labour respectively. Let elasticities of factor
prices [w.sub.L] and [w.sub.H] be denoted by [e.sub.LL] = [partial
derivative]log[w.sub.L]/[partial derivative]logL, [e.sub.HH] = [partial
derivative]log[w.sub.H] /[partial derivative]logH and [e.sub.LH] =
[partial derivative]log[w.sub.L]/[partial derivative]logH. Let the
migration rate be m = M/(L + H) and the post-migration proportion of
skilled labour be h = H/(L + H). Let [beta] denote the fraction of
skilled workers among immigrants and the changes in the skilled and
unskilled workforces following migration be [DELTA]L = [[eta].sub.L](1 -
[beta])M and ?H = [?.sub.H][beta]M where [[eta].sub.i] [member of][0,1]
are measures of labour market flexibility for the two types of labour.
Finally let [s.sub.L] = [w.sub.L]L/Y and [s.sub.H] = [w.sub.H]H/Y be
factor shares. Then following Borjas (1995), the immigration surplus
generalizes to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII (2)
From the assumed concavity of the production function the
immigration surplus can be shown to be positive. Equation (2) can be
used to assess immigration policy that favours immigrants with or
without skill. Borjas (1995) quotes Hamermesh (1993) whose survey
suggests that the factor elasticity is greater for skilled than
unskilled workers. Then as this elasticity rises if immigration consists
solely of skilled workers, the immigration surplus can rise
substantially depending on original mix of skilled and unskilled workers
in the population. Thus Borjas' analysis provides a foundation for
a positive theory of immigration policy and points to a strong economic
case for an immigration policy that favours skilled immigrants.
Borjas (2001) analyses the immigration surplus in an economy with
regional differences in marginal product. Compared to the situation with
a 1-region aggregate labour market, where the gains arise because
immigrants and natives complement each other, Borjas (2001) argues that
immigration improves economic efficiency by speeding up the process of
wage convergence. The idea underlying the paper is simple--immigration
injects into the economy a group of highly mobile self-selected
individuals who are ready to move to exploit economic opportunities in
different areas. The underlying assumption is that native workers
respond slowly to wage differentials and their marginal product is not
maximized. By moving to the high wage region, immigrants generate two
kinds of benefits for natives. First, they increase national GDP through
the standard immigration surplus and second, they maximize the income
that accrues to natives net of migration costs. The author presents both
descriptive statistics and econometric evidence in support of these
hypotheses. Data refer to the US economy, where new immigrants show a
high propensity to cluster in high wage areas. In the European context,
there is clear evidence that the costs of internal migration play an
important role in slowing down the convergence process and therefore new
immigrants may improve labour market efficiency.
Bauer and Zimmermann (1999) use the Borjas (1995) framework to
provide simulations for immigration's effect on the EU economy (as
well as separately for the German and UK economies). They also extend
Borjas' analysis by introducing the possibility of unemployment for
unskilled labour. They estimate that if there is an immigration inflow
equal to 1% of EU employment and this consists solely of manual
(unskilled) workers then natives gain by only 0.01% of EU GDP in the
full employment scenario. If non-manual (skilled) workers migrate then
the gain to natives increases to 0.03% of EU GDP. They also estimate the
distributional effects of immigration, finding that largest gains accrue
to capital, with a 1% immigration of skilled workers producing gains of
0.22% of EU GDP. Non-manual natives will gain if less than 40% of
immigrants are manual and manual natives will gain if less than 70% of
immigrants are non-manual. In the unemployment scenario, natives can
lose as a result of the immigration of manual workers, because their
jobs may be displaced. However, potential gains from the immigration of
non-manual workers in this scenario may be much larger; they estimate
that native workers may gain by up to 6.9% of EU GDP if there is zero
native unemployment. Calculated gains are likely to be under-estimates
because they ignore the tax and social security contributions of
immigrants as well as the increase in labour demand that could result
from higher consumption levels.
Brain Drain or Gain?
The question of how migration of the highly skilled affects human
capital formation and the average level of human capital in the source
and destination countries is of major importance. Miyagiwa (1991)
analyzes the brain drain phenomenon, introducing increasing returns to
scale in the education sector in a model with heterogeneous workers. The
key elements of the model are that information is not a public good and
that geographical distances matter. This implies that the greater the
number of educated workers in the economy, the greater the income of
each educated worker. To illustrate this, suppose there are two
countries of different size--in particular, country A (e.g. the US) is
bigger than country B (e.g. Taiwan). The author shows that in the bigger
country not only is there a larger number of workers, but also a higher
percentage of the population acquire education. The increasing returns
effect results in higher wages for skilled workers in country A and
therefore skilled workers from country B have an incentive to migrate to
country A. The author considers two cases. In case 1, all skilled
workers migrate with direct and indirect positive effects for the host
country. In case 2, only a proportion of the skilled migrate and the
effects of the brain drain for the source country are ambiguous. There
is the possibility of a positive brain drain (i.e. the income of the
migrants increases, while the income of the low skilled non-migrants is
kept constant), but it is also possible that only the most gifted gain
from opening up the economy. In fact, given externalities in education,
migration of the most gifted negatively depresses incomes of the
'intermediate' individuals forcing them to migrate.
Mountford (1997) suggests an alternative scenario. The amount of
human capital in any period depends on the decision of households to
acquire education. The prospect of higher wages through emigration stimulates acquisition of human capital and therefore enhances growth.
This effect can be stronger than the direct effect of emigration. A
brain drain may therefore actually enhance growth in the source economy.
Stark et al. (1997, 1998) reach similar conclusions, as do Beine et al.
(2001) in an overlapping generations framework.
Becker et al. (1990) take a different perspective on human capital
formation and the brain drain phenomenon. They model economic growth
assuming endogenous fertility, but depart from both the Malthusian and
neoclassical approaches by placing investments in human capital at the
centre of the analysis. We assume that rate of return to human capital
is higher in economies with a higher stock of knowledge. As a result,
economies with a low initial stock of human capital choose large
families and invest a small amount in each child, while countries with a
high stock of human capital do the opposite. This paper contributes to
the brain drain literature because it gives an explanation for why the
brain drain occurs from poor to rich countries. Moreover, if returns to
education are increasing in the stock of knowledge, this advantage will
not disappear.
MIGRANTS' SAVING, REMITTANCES AND DURATION OF MIGRATION
In exogenous growth models with exogenous savings the effect of an
increase in the savings rate is to increase the level of the per capita capital stock and therefore per capita output. (4) Therefore, in order
to analyse the effect of immigration on transitional growth, it is
necessary to examine whether immigrants, particularly those who only
stay for short periods, have positive saving rates and if so, how these
savings rates compare with those of natives.
Galor and Stark (1990) use an overlapping generations framework to
show that migrants have a higher savings ratio than natives if they face
a positive probability of return migration. This is consistent with the
life-cycle theory of consumption since migrants may expect their future
income to fall, if they have a positive probability of returning to
their home country and will save more to smooth their lifetime levels of
consumption. Similarly, Djajic (1989) proposes that temporary migrants
have a higher savings ratio because of their expectations of future
price levels in the host and home countries. Studies also assume that
immigrants have a higher marginal utility of consumption in the home
country.
Karayalcin (1994) argues that temporary migrants save more than
natives because they face a higher rate of interest if there is
imperfect capital mobility. A 2-country overlapping generations model is
developed to examine the impacts of both temporary and permanent
migration. Temporary migration is equivalent to international capital
mobility because they produce the same interest rates, output levels and
wage (at every point in time). Both temporary and permanent migration
cause world income and output levels to rise. This is explained by the
Borjas-type argument of labour migrating from the labour abundant low
wage country to the host country which has a higher marginal
productivity. Dustmann (1997) extends previous studies to incorporate
the effects of uncertainty, finding that if the migrants' variance
of income is higher than that of natives then they will save more.
However, this result depends on whether any of the potential random
shocks in different time periods are correlated.
Rather than holding their savings in the receiving country,
migrants may opt to transfer money back to friends and family in the
source country in the form of international remittances. (5) The amounts
sent abroad are substantial, with World Bank estimates of officially
recorded remittances amounting to around $75bn in 2000, although this is
thought to be a significant underestimate of the true figure. Therefore
remittances are a vital development tool and source of foreign exchange
for many countries. For example, Coppel et al. (2001) report that
remittances were 1.5 times the level of exports of goods and services in
Albania in 1998 and were equivalent to more than 20% of exports in six
other countries. Furthermore, the total amount sent in remittances is
thought to far outweigh net level of foreign aid received from OECD
countries (Coppel et al., 2001).
However, there is a debate over the extent to which remittances
boost the economy of the source country since income is used for
consumption and not investment (Glytsos, 1993). Macmillen (1982)
outlines some of the negative consequences if remittances are used in
this way: an increase in price level and imports, an overvalued exchange
rate and a dependence on remittances which may delay long term economic
policies, especially if the level of remittances cannot be guaranteed
due to economic fluctuations. Policies to divert remittances to more
productive sources may be neccesary. However, Adams (1998) finds that
external remittances do have an important statistical effect on the
accumulation of rural assets in Pakistan.
Empirical evidence on the savings of migrants is provided by Merkle
and Zimmermann (1992), who investigate savings behaviour of guestworkers
living in Germany. Nearly all guestworkers had positive savings, either
a savings account in the host country or through remittances (which they
argue are a special form of savings if the migrant intends to return to
their home country). They find a negative relationship between planned
duration of residence in Germany and remittances, but this was not
statistically significant. However, guest-workers who return home early
may well hold savings in their home country. Unfortunately, they do not
compare migrants' savings rates directly with those of natives.
Evidence suggests that local savings rates (earnings invested into
savings in the host country) are higher for immigrants in Britain and
France. Immigrants living in Birmingham and Manchester had a savings
rate around 2% above the British average in 1965 (Jones and Smith, 1970)
and Granier and Marciano (1975) report that French immigrants had a
saving rate that was 50% higher than a native with a similar income
level. Paine (1974) reports that Turkish migrants had a local savings
rate of 36%, which was well above the national rate for developed
economies. It is also worth reporting the effect that these savings have
on the probability of entrepreneurship. McCormick and Wahba (2001),
analyse use of savings by return migrants to Egypt, find that 29% of
their sample were entrepreneurs after returning, compared to 18% before
migrating. Savings accrued by the migrant while overseas, they argue,
account for much of this increase because potential entrepreneurs are
often liquidity constrained and savings can provide capital to start a
business (Evans and Jovanovic, 1989). The acquisition of overseas work
experience increases the probability that literate migrants become
entrepreneurs, which may reflect skill acquisition while abroad.
Mankiw et al. (1992) provide supporting evidence to the Solow
(1956) view that richer countries have higher savings rates, whereas
poorer countries tend to be those with high rates of population growth.
This suggests that those countries that experience large immigration
flows have lower growth rates. However, these variables are not
significant in the regression for a sample of OECD countries. Mankiw et
al. (1992) also emphasise that account be taken of human capital
differences in the empirical specification. The results of their
augmented Solow model indicate that human capital is important in
explaining wealth differences, even within OECD countries. There may be
a link between savings and human capital in that a higher saving rate
produces higher income in the steady state, which causes human capital
levels to increase even if the rate of human capital accumulation remains the same. Higher savings are associa ted with higher levels of
total factor productivity.
THE WELFARE STATE AND DEMOGRAPHIC CONSIDERATIONS
It is important to determine whether immigrants are more or less
likely to be recipients of welfare payments than natives, particularly
if low skilled immigrants are attracted by the relatively generous
social welfare payments that are offered in some countries. Immigrants
are less likely to be social welfare recipients, and when they do
receive assistance, these are typically lower than those received by
natives with similar characteristics (OECD, 1997). However, Gustman and
Steinmeier (2000) find that the probability that an immigrant to the US
receives state benefits has risen since the 1970s. This can be explained
by the lower levels of human capital and poorer English language skills
of more recent immigrant cohorts. Borjas and Hilton (1996) also report
that immigrant households are more likely to be benefit recipients than
native households, but find that immigrants' welfare recipient
rates fall the longer they stay in the host country.
However, in order to examine the fiscal impact of immigration more
fully, the amount received in immigrant tax receipts should be compared
with social welfare payments to immigrants. Lalonde and Topel (1997)
survey US evidence and report that immigrants are net contributors,
although most of this evidence relates to the 1970s, since when average
immigrant skills have decreased and hence a larger proportion are below
the poverty line. Net benefits associated with recent immigration may be
smaller than for previous cohorts. Gott and Johnston (2002) suggest that
immigrants make a positive net contribution to the UK economy. They
estimate that in 1999/2000, immigrants to the UK contributed 31.2bn
[pounds sterling] in taxes and received 28.8bn [pounds sterling] in
benefits and services. Furthermore, intergenerational considerations
should be taken into account, and if this is done immigrant
contributions may be an underestimate since second generation immigrants
are also likely to be net tax payers.
Canova and Ravn (2000) examine macroeconomic consequences for West
Germany of German unification using a dynamic general equilibrium model.
They argue that this event is similar to a mass migration of low-skilled
workers holding no capital into a foreign country. In the absence of a
welfare state, West to East transfers raise distortionary tax rates and
result in an investment boom and depressed output. Winners are Western
owners of capital, highly skilled workers and migrants. With the welfare
state, the investment boom disappears and recession is prolonged.
Winners are now confined to migrants and unskilled workers in the former
East Germany.
Sinn (2002) focuses on the potential adverse fiscal consequences of
migration that may result from EU enlargement. He expects there to be
significant East-West migration, induced by large wage differentials
that exist and this could produce some of the positive aspects of
migration that we have discussed previously. However, if migration
occurs as a result of the welfare programmes offered by Western
countries, then this could create competition between these countries to
deter Eastern migrants from entering. The overall outcome of this
process could therefore be the erosion of the welfare state. To prevent
this, Sinn (2002) recommends the harmonisation of welfare systems (which
may be too expensive), selective migration policies or limiting, the
access of migrants to the welfare system.
Many OECD countries face the problem of an ageing population. In
the 2001 UK Census, it was reported that for the first time, the
population aged over 60 was greater than the population aged under 16.
In addition to lower fertility and mortality rates, there has been a
trend towards early retirement, especially among skilled workers,
leading to a pensions crisis. Immigration could help to alleviate this
'demographic time-bomb' since immigrants are typically younger
and have higher fertility rates. Furthermore, Zimmermann (1995) reports
that there is strong migration potential from developing and Eastern
European countries because many of these countries have growing
populations. However, the current level of immigration will be unable to
sustain the level of the working age population because has been
estimated that a net migration of around 1.5 million individuals per
annum is required to keep the EU's working population constant
until 2050 (United Nations, 2000).
MIGRATION AND ENDOGENOUS GROWTH
A vast theoretical and empirical literature pioneered by Romer (1986, 1990),has emerged since the 1980s which has transformed the way
economists think about growth. New growth theory contrasts with the
earlier neoclassical or old growth theory of Solow (1956), which invoked
exogenous technical change to explain sustained long-term growth. By
contrast, focus of the new endogenous growth (EG) theory is on how the
consumption and savings decisions of households, investment decisions of
firms, and public policy in various forms, determine long-term growth.
Whilst the neoclassical model could be described as a model with
long-run growth, new literature offers a number of possible models of
long-run growth.
The EG literature can be divided into three broad strands: the
first builds on Romer (1986), is closest to the classical tradition and
emphasises capital accumulation as the engine of growth, with capital
broadly defined to include human and physical components. The second
sees EG driven by the accumulation of human capital (Lucas, 1988). In
the third broad strand of the literature, following Romer (1990) and
Grossman and Helpman (1991), the discovery of new goods and of new
processes provides the engine of growth. Research and Development
(R&D) activity provides blueprints for these innovations and a
feature of this literature is the attempt to understand the economic
forces that drive R&D. This section first reviews papers that draw
upon this literature to assess migration impacts on long-run EG.
Growth Driven by Capital Stock
Reichlin and Rustichini (1993) study the impact of migration in a
2-period overlapping generations model of consumers with free trade and
perfect capital mobility. Following Romer (1986), the authors assume
that level of technology is an increasing function of the aggregate
stock of capital (i.e. knowledge is a public good) through a
learning-by-doing mechanism. Due to externalities, equilibrium is
characterized by a continuous flow of migration from low wage to high
wage countries. Flow of migrants from the poor to the rich country does
not stop since the assumption of perfect capital mobility implies the
high wage country has a higher capital-labour ratio and this advantage
increases over time in the presence of positive externalities. The
existence of a scale effect of the labour force is the key, even if
controversial, element of the model. The two countries are assumed
identical in terms of technology, but they differ in terms of initial
stocks of factors of production.
In the first part of the paper, they show configurations of the
migration patterns in a homogeneous labour framework. They then discuss
the case of heterogeneous labour where the scale effect (the crucial one
in the homogenous labour case) may be partially or totally offset by a
'composition effect'--a change in the ratio of skilled to
unskilled in the two countries. In the latter case, a flow reversal in
migration patterns takes place. The size effect is captured by a
technology which is positively affected by the aggregate stock of
capital, as in Romer (1986). Young individuals are endowed with
different predispositions towards emigration so that a given proportion
of workers will move. In the model with unskilled and skilled workers,
this proportion is assumed equal to the fraction of agents who are
willing to qualify as skilled workers. The composition effect influences
the relative position of a country and gives a possible explanation of
why a country which, at some point in time, is a sending country, may
become a receiving country in the future, even if there are large
positive externalities. The main condition of the reversal, which is
also a condition for convergence in the growth rates, is a balanced
composition of skilled and unskilled workers.
To sum up, the authors show that the positive effects of migration
are determined by pure size effects. On the other hand, with high and
low skill workers, the continuous flow of migrants affects the ratio of
skilled and unskilled and if the flow is proportionately larger in the
unskilled labour sector then migration, through the composition effect,
may penalize the receiving country.
Growth Driven by Human Capital
Walz (1995) uses a 2-bloc EG model to address the effects of
migration on both host and source countries. He provides conditions
under which a brain drain is beneficial for the source economy, avoiding
the use of pure size effects. He offers an explanation of skill
formation and migration decision in an EG model with individuals living
a finite period of time. In particular, individuals choose whether they
will invest in education or work in the unskilled sector. A key
assumption of the model is given by the presence of two types of agents
with different advantages in the education process. Clearly, agents with
an advantage in the human capital formation process have a higher
incentive to invest in education and migration acts as a screening
device. Since the costs of migration are the same for both categories,
the expected benefits to migration are higher for workers with a greater
ability in the education process. Two cases may arise. In case 1, the
expected zero benefit condition is satisfied before all individuals with
an advantage in the education process (i.e. a type 1 agent) have chosen
to become skilled. In case 2, all type 1 and some type 2 individuals
invest in education. In contrast with Beine et al. (2001), the author
explicitly considers two countries, developing the analysis of the
dynamic effects of migration in the source (low wage) as well as in the
host (high wage) economy.
The central idea is that migration affects the growth rate of the
economies by altering the composition of the labour force in each
country. Each country specializes in the production of a consumption
good. In each country, besides the consumption sectors, an education
sector exists. The evolution of knowledge depends positively on the
average human capital, the result of migration decisions. The author
highlights the positive effects of opening up the economies for
individuals in both countries via a decreasing price level and a rising
real income. If the growth in the source country does not decrease,
migration can make everybody better off. Moreover, if migration
increases the overall growth rate, the positive dynamic effects offset
any negative static effects.
The role of history and initial conditions is highlighted in Premer
and Walz (1994). The authors explain divergence between regions or
countries through an EG model in which regional growth occurs due to
learning by doing and where the allocation of skilled workers is
endogenously determined.
Haque and Kim (1994) concentrate on the effects of migration of the
highly skilled on the source economy. In a 2-country EG model with
heterogeneous agents, the authors show that the migration of skilled
labour may have negative effects on income and growth in the sending
economy. (6) The heterogeneous individuals live two periods. In the
first period they may decide to invest in education while in period 2
they can choose their location. The two countries differ in terms of
government policies and possibly technology. These differences explain
migration flows, which will result in a truncation of the distribution
of ability in the source country. As in Walz (1995), there is a tendency
for individuals with higher ability to migrate. This generates a
permanent decrease of the growth rate in the home country, which is
proportional to the fraction of the population that has migrated.
Whereas the effects on the host country depend on the evolution of the
ratio of the average human capital of the two countries. Given this
theoretical framework, the authors derive implications for policies to
affect the level of human capital, distinguishing the case of a closed
economy from one which is open.
Growth Driven by R&D
Lundborg and Segerstrom (2000, 2002) examine a quality-ladders
model of economic growth based on a North-South model in Grossman and
Helpman (1991, chapter 12). In such a model, growth is driven by
improvements in product quality. In each period, firms engage in a
R&D race to become the quality leader by hiring R&D workers. A
firm that wins the race becomes the only producer in that period. All
firms stay in the R&D race and every leading firm will be replaced
by another. Any firm's probability of becoming the leader depends
positively on its own R&D effort and negatively on the aggregate
effort made by all firms. Since all firms are identical, they all make
the same R&D investments and face the same probability of becoming
the product leader.
The world is made up of two regions called North and South. The
high-quality products of the North are called 'high-tech',
only Northern firms can produce them. The products of the South are
called 'low-tech'. The Northern firms could produce them but
they will not do so because production of high-tech products is more
profitable. Consumers spend a fixed part of their expenditure on
commodities of each region. They benefit from the innovation in both
regions through falling commodity prices, therefore the rate of growth
of real expenditure is identical in both regions. Southern welfare
levels are a constant fraction of northern welfare levels. There is a
constant incentive to migrate.
Consider first what happens when some Southern consumers/workers
die. To start with this means a reduction of consumer expenditure in the
South. (7) Therefore, demand and production of Northern commodities
falls and the relative wage of Northern consumers falls, leading to a
fall in Northern expenditure. The fall of expenditures leads to a fall
in the growth rate because there are reduced incentives to invest in
R&D. All these circumstances reduce Northern welfare. Southern
welfare is affected negatively by the fall in growth rate, but it is
affected positively through the increase in the relative wage. As far as
workers--who receive labour income--in the South are concerned the
latter effect dominates the former in simulation evidence presented by
the authors. As far as capitalists--who own the stock value of firms--in
the South are concerned, the growth effect dominates.
Now consider the effect of migration from the South to the North.
An R&D worker is assumed to be more productive in the North than in
the South, therefore the growth potential in the world economy increases
when labour moves to the North. We also have the effect of a population
decrease in the South as discussed in the previous paragraph. In
addition we have the impact of the labour supply increase in the North,
that puts further pressure on the wages in the North. Firms in the North
and South increase R&D expenditure. But in simulations the resulting
increase in growth is not sufficient to make migration beneficial to
Northern consumers. Northern workers are affected more than Northern
capitalists. Southern workers benefit from migration; the incentives to
migrate are reduced. Thus welfare effects of migration can be divided
into static effects from changes in wages and the terms of trade, and
dynamic effects from higher growth. Static distributional effects are as
the previous section--Northern workers (excluding new immigrants) and
Southern capitalists lose and Northern capitalists, Southern workers and
migrants gain. Workers in the North and South gain from increased
growth, but Northern capitalists can lose because more R&D activity
intensifies competition and squeezes profits. Table 1 summarizes these
results on winners and losers. The net effect of migration is naturally
sensitive to parameter values and to the specification of the model.
In a 2-country, 3-sector model, Bretschger (2001) challenges a main
result of the existing literature on the impact of migration on growth,
namely the positive effects of unskilled migration given an elasticity
of substitution between skilled/unskilled greater than 1 (Grossman and
Helpman, 1991). Moreover, the author shows the role of countries'
shares in world goods markets, a role neglected by previous studies. (8)
Using an expansion in varieties framework, the author analyzes the
impact of the supply of skilled and unskilled workers on the growth rate
in open economies. In the medium term, the three sectors (traditional,
high tech and R&D sectors), are spread in the two economies, but
given increasing returns in the R&D sectors, the final outcome will
be one of full specialization.
After presenting empirical evidence supporting his model, the
author considers two versions. In a first version, he shows the effects
of migration in expanding varieties in consumption, as in Grossman and
Helpman (1991). An increase in skilled migration has unambiguously
positive effects on growth, while the effects of unskilled migration
depends on the elasticity of substitution of skilled and unskilled in
both the high tech and the traditional sector. In particular, the
smaller the country, the higher the possibility of negative effects on
growth of unskilled migration. In a second version of the model,
Bretschger (2001) considers the case of an expanding varieties in inputs
into production, highlighting the role of the reward for the inventions
of new designs (R&D sector). In this version he assumes varieties to
serve as intermediate goods for a capital input and he shows how a
migration of unskilled labour has unambiguously negative effects on the
growth rate. At the same time, the growth effects of an
equi-proportionate immigration of unskilled and skilled depends again on
the elasticity of substitution and the countries' size.
To summarise, the main findings of Bretschger (2001) are: migration
of skilled labour has a positive effect on the host country but
migration of unskilled labour has a negative impact of on growth. A
corollary of these results is that migration of the highly skilled
negatively affects growth in the source economy, which is in accordance
with the mainstream literature on the brain drain. The example of
Switzerland with its policy that discriminates foreign skilled labour is
introduced to support the author's arguments.
The importance of the skill composition of migrants is also
emphasised by Levine et al. (2002). They revisit the work of Borjas
(1995) and extend his analysis in a number of directions. First, they
study the immigration surplus in the context of a general equilibrium
model in which capital is endogenous and the welfare of the indigenous
population is set out explicitly. Second, they introduce several sectors
into the model so that changing the skill composition leads to changes
in sector shares. Third and related to the second development, they
introduce dynamics and develop a model with long-term EG driven by
R&D. The result is that growth effects on the immigration surplus
come to dominate the purely static effects in the original analysis of
Borjas, but they are not sufficient to eliminate the emergence of losers
among the section of natives competing with immigrants in the labour
market.
Migration and Growth: Empirical Evidence
Despite the positive effect that immigration can have on growth,
immigration is typically not included as an explanatory variable in the
avalanche of (cross section) growth regressions that have emerged
following Barro (1991). Even those studies that attempt to control for
virtually every conceivable covariate e.g. Levine and Renalt (1992) and
Hoover and Perez (2001) do not explicitly control for immigration.
Rather, they include the population growth rate of which net migration
is just one component, although this variable is not very significant in
their regressions. On the other hand, Sachs and Warner (1997) include
the growth of the economically active population minus the population
growth rate, which they find to be positive and almost significant at
the 5% level. Therefore we must look to other evidence to demonstrate
the importance of immigration per se on growth.
A possible reason for the relative absence of immigration as an
economic explanation for growth was suggested by Neal and Uselding
(1972) who believed that economists take the growth rate of the labour
force as a fixed parameter, even in periods when the amount of
immigration varies. However, there is considerable evidence from the
economic history literature as to the importance of immigration, and of
factor movements in general, on growth and convergence.
Kindleberger (1967) was one of the main advocates of the view that
immigration was the main factor behind the remarkable rates of economic
growth witnessed in the post-war period in Europe. Taylor (1999)
suggests that his empirical model for the period 1870-1914 "...
certainly indicates the importance of the three classical factors, and
the indisputably mobile labour and capital, as the basis of economic
growth" (p. 1642). Focusing solely on Argentina over this period,
Taylor (1997) finds that immigration drove down real wages in the
country by around 25% and caused a 19% increase in GDP. Given the huge
inflow of people over this period, Taylor (1997) describes Argentina as
an ideal test case for analysing the economic impact of immigration.
Neal and Uselding (1972) estimate that the 1912 US physical capital
stock would have been between 13% and 42% lower had it not been for
immigration into the US economy and that its proportionate effect on
human capital would have been at least as great.
Other attempts to quantify the magnitude of the effect of
immigration have used fairly crude techniques. For example, Askari (1974) simply multiplied the annual contribution of labour to growth by
the percentage of foreign workers in the labour force. He found that the
impact of immigrants on growth rates in the EEC was fairly small. The
largest effects were found in Luxembourg, where immigrants were
estimated to have increased annual growth rates by an average of around
7% (0.2 percentage points per year) between 1960 and 1970. Impact of
immigrants on the annual growth rates of Belgium, France, Germany and
the Netherlands was much smaller since immigrants typically contributed
less than 0.05 percentage points. Other studies include that of
Gallais-Hamonno (1977) who estimated that immigrants contributed around
5% to France's GNP.
Blattner and Sheldon (1989) take a different approach in that they
specify a production function for Switzerland that distinguishes between
domestic and foreign labour. They apply a growth accounting framework to
isolate the contribution of immigrants to output growth rates,
productivity and per capita GDP. They estimate that foreign labour
accounted for around 0.3 percentage points of the 2.7% average growth
rates that Switzerland experienced between 1961 and 1982. The other
contributions to output growth were domestic employment (0.1 percentage
points), hours of work (-0.2 percentage points), capital (0.8 percentage
points) and technical change (1.7 percentage points). However, they find
that foreign employment had a negative effect on both productivity
growth and per capita growth over this period, which they explain by the
lower output elasticity of foreign workers, possibly as a result of the
jobs in which immigrants are typically found.
POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Policy debates typically focus on the role of institutions and
governments as mechanisms, which can first regulate migration flows and
their composition and second mitigate the potential negative impact of
immigration on the host country. On the one hand, studies in favour of
migration emphasize its role in partially offsetting slower growing or
declining populations as well as easing the skilled labour shortages in
specific sectors. On the other hand, opponents point to the adverse
impact on native unemployment and wages, although most empirical studies find that the effect of immigrants on the host country labour market is
small. (9) Here we attempt to synthesize the policy implications of
papers surveyed on three themes: i) What are the static and dynamic
consequences of an increase in immigration? ii) What is the relationship
between skilled/unskilled migration and economic development in the
source and host countries? (iii) What role can governments play?
Previous surveys by Borjas (1994, 1995, 1999, 2001) focus on the
static effects of migration. Borjas (1994, 1995) produces clear policy
recommendations. In a heterogeneous labour market framework, he looks at
the original mix of skilled and unskilled workers in order to measure
the immigration surplus and analyse the role of possible
complementarities between migrants and native factors. However, he
estimates that immigration has only a small impact on US GDP and causes
a not-insignificant redistribution from labour to capital. For these
reasons, Borjas' earlier work suggests a pessimistic outcome from
active recruitment policies. However, the 'greasing the
wheels' argument in Borjas (2001) is more optimistic. Whether the
resulting immigration surplus is significant or not, winners and losers
remain and this suggests that compensating redistributive policies among
immigrants, domestic workers and domestic capital owners may be
necessary. A similar policy is suggested by Steineck (1996), who
concludes in favour of potential positive effects of migration, which
are unequally distributed amongst the native population.
Turning to the dynamic aspects of immigration (growth and economic
development), the debate focuses on the skill content of migrants and
concerns of a possible brain drain from LDCs. Growth may be driven by
pure size effects, human capital and R&D and the policy
prescriptions are strongly related to the mechanism generating growth.
In a model where growth is driven by pure size effects, Reichlin and
Rustichini (1993) suggest an active migration policy, whilst in a world
with different skills they also look at the composition of migration and
recommend policies which guarantee a proportional flow of skilled and
unskilled migrants.
Lundborg and Segerstrom (2000, 2002) in a two-country EG model with
a homogeneous labour force, show that the representative agent loses
from large immigration quotas, despite a positive growth effect, whilst
the population of the sending country gains. Given this negative result
for natives in the host country, the authors consider different policy
recommendations. A migration tax lowers the incentive to migrate but
native workers would have been better off in a no migration equilibrium.
Migration incentives can be affected by other policies. In the Lundborg
and Segerstrom framework, even if a R&D subsidy in the host country
enhances growth, a R&D subsidy in the sending country has the
positive effect of reducing migration incentives by lowering the
international utility differences among workers.
Policies that favour immigration of more skilled individuals are
advocated by Bretschger (2001), since it is argued that migration of the
highly skilled raises human capital levels in the host country and
therefore has a positive effect on its growth rate. Referring to the
experience of other countries (e.g. Canada), the quality of migrants can
be influenced by adopting a points system to meet the labour market
needs of the EU. However, the quality of migrants with regards to the
transferability of their human capital depends on the type of skills
they possess and the characteristics of the host and sending countries
(e.g. language, institutions etc). This implies that selection
mechanisms based on the country of origin may also be considered by
labour importing countries.
The positive effects of skilled migration are also stressed by
Levine et al. (2002). They revisit and extend the standard Borjas
analysis (Borjas, 1995). Focusing on the dynamic aspects, the authors
show that in an EG framework, the positive effects of skilled migration
are magnified. At the same time, however, the distributional effects
still dominate.
Issues surrounding the skill composition of migrants are also
important in the context of the brain drain for LDCs. Therefore policies
designed to promote growth in these countries should take the human
capital flight into account. To the extent that human capital is an
important determinant of growth, Haque and Kim (1994) suggest that in an
open economy, subsidies to education can have a negative impact on the
growth rate of the source country. On the other hand, some of the papers
surveyed above suggest that the possibility of migration can have
positive effects for the home country by encouraging individuals to
enhance their human capital stocks. Another important benefit of
international migration LDCs are remittances, although there is some
debate over the extent to which these payments are used for productive
purposes. Therefore policies that encourage remittances to be invested
should be recommended.
CONCLUSIONS
This survey has reviewed a large number of theoretical models that
consider various aspects of the immigration process, focusing in
particular on the effect that immigration can have on growth rates. In
general, these models indicate that immigration should increase growth,
both in terms of endogenous and short-run growth. This is particularly
the case if the inflow of workers consists mainly of the highly skilled.
However, the outflow of skilled workers from sending countries might
have a detrimental effect on those countries i.e. the brain drain, but
some authors argue that the migration of the highly skilled can actually
bring about positive effects in that it is likely to encourage human
capital formation in the source country.
There are relatively few reliable econometric estimates of the
contribution that migration makes to raising growth rates, but no
shortage of empirical evidence on its importance in various time periods
for different countries. The survey also contains a discussion of the
policy options available for both sending and receiving countries, in
the light of the empirical evidence and theoretical findings. With
reference to the forthcoming enlargement of the EU, given that migration
from Eastern to Western Europe may well produce positive growth effects,
especially if migrants are highly skilled, an overly restrictive
migration policy may constrain the overall growth of the region.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
We acknowledge funding from the European Commission's
Framework 5 Programme for a project examining the impact of migration on
growth and employment EU enlargement.
REFERENCES
Adams, Richard H. 1998. "Remittances, Investment, and Rural
Asset Accumulation in Pakistan". Economic Development and Cultural
Change. 47: pp. 155-73.
Askari, Hossein. 1974. "The Contribution of Migration to
Economic Growth in the EEC". Economia Internazionale. 27: pp.
341-5.
Barro, Robert J. 1991. "Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of
Countries". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 106(2): pp. 407-33.
Barro, Robert J. and Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 1995. Economic Growth.
New York: McGraw-Hill.
Bauer, Thomas and Zimmermann. Klaus, F. 1999. Assessment of
Possible Migration Pressure and its Labor Market Impact Following EU
Enlargement to Central and Eastern Europe. IZA Research Report No. 3.
Becker, Gary, S., Murphy Kevin, M. and Tamura, Robert. 1990.
"Human Capital, Fertility, and Economic Growth". Journal of
Political Economy. 98(2): S12-S37.
Beine, Michel, Docquier, Frederic and Rapoport, Hillel. 2001.
"Brain Drain and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence".
Journal of Development Economics. 64: pp. 275-289.
Blattner, Niklaus. and Sheldon, George. 1989. "Foreign Labour,
Growth and Productivity: The Case of Switzerland". In European
Factor Mobility: Trends and Consequences. Eds. Ian Gordon and Anthony P.
Thirlwall. London: Macmillan.
Borjas, George, J. 1994. "The Economics of Immigration".
Journal of Economic Literature. 32(4): pp. 1667-1717.
Borjas, George J. 1995. "The Economic Benefits from
Immigration". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9(2): pp. 3-22.
Borjas, George J. 1999. "The Economic Analysis of
Immigration". In Handbook of Labor Economics, Volume 3A. Eds. Orley
Ashenfelter and David Card. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Borjas, George, J. 2001. "Does Immigration Grease the Wheels
of the Labor Market?". Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1:
pp. 69-133.
Borjas, George J. and Hilton, Lynette. (1996). "Immigration
and the Welfare State: Immigrant Participation in Means Tested
Entitlement Programmes". Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(2):
pp. 575-604.
Bretschger, Lucas. 1993. "Labor Migration and Long-Term
Growth". University of Zurich, Institut fur Empirische
Wirtschaftsforschung Working Paper No. 9302.
Bretschger, Lucas. 2001. "Labor Supply, Migration, and Long
Term Development", Open Economies Review. 12(1): pp. 5-27.
Canova, Fabio and Ravn, Morten O. 2000. "The Macroeconomic
Effects of German Unification: Real Adjustments and the Welfare
State". Review of Economic Dynamics. 3(3): pp. 423-460.
Card, David. 1990. "The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift on the
Miami Labor Market". Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 40: pp.
195-211.
Commander, Simon, Kangasniem, Mari and Winters, L. Alan. 2002.
"The Brain Drain: Curse or Boon? A Survey of the Literature".
Paper presented at the CEPR/NBER/SNS Seminar on International Trade.
Stockholm, May 24-25.
Coppel, Jonathan, Dumont, Jean-Christophe and Visco, Ignazio. 2001.
"Trends in Immigration and Economic Consequences". OECD
Economics Department Working Paper No. 284.
Djajic, Slobodan. 1989. "Migrants in a Guest Worker
System". Journal of Development Economics. 31: pp. 327-339.
Dustmann, Christian. 1997. "Return Migration, Uncertainty and
Precautionary Savings". Journal of Development Economics. 52: pp.
293-316.
Evans, David and Jovanovic, Boyan. 1989. "An Estimated Model
of Entrepreneurial Choice under Liquidity Constraints", Journal of
Political Economy. 97(4): pp. 808-827.
Friedberg, Rachel M. and Hunt, Jennifer. 1995. "The Impact of
Immigrants on Host Country Wages, Employment and Growth". Journal
of Economic Perspectives. 9(2): pp. 23-44.
Gallais-Hamonno, Georges. 1977. "The Direct Short-Term Effects
and Advantages of Migration of Manpower or Capital". In
International Labour Migrations and Economic Choices: The European Case.
Eds. Francois Bourguignon and George Gallais-Hamonno with Bernard
Fernet. Paris: OECD.
Galor, Oded and Stark, Oded. 1990. "Migrants' Savings,
the Probability of Return Migration and Migrants'
Performance". International Economic Review. 31(2): pp. 463-467.
Ghatak, Subrata, Levine, Paul and Wheatley-Price, Stephen. 1996.
"Migration Theory and Evidence: An Assessment". Journal of
Economic Surveys. 10(2): pp. 159-198.
Glytsos, Nicholas P. 1993. "Measuring the Income Effects of
Migrant Remittances: A Methodological Approach Applied to Greece".
Economic Development and Cultural Change. 42: pp. 131-68.
Gott, Ceri and Johnston, Karl. 2002. "The Migrant Population
in the UK: Fiscal Effects". Home Office Research, Development and
Statistics Occasional Paper No. 77.
Granier, R. and Marciano, G. 1975. "The Earnings of Immigrant
Workers in France". International Migration Review. 111: pp.
143-65.
Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanan. 1991. Innovation and Growth
in the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Gustman, Alan L. and Steinmeier, Thomas L. 2000. "Social
Security Benefits of Immigrants and the US Born". In Issues in the
Economics of Immigration. Ed. George J. Borjas. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Hamermesh, Daniel S. 1993. Labor Demand. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Haque, Nadeem Ul and Kim, Se-jik. 1994. "Human Capital Flight:
Impact of Migration on Income and Growth". IMF Research Department
Working Paper No. 94/155.
Hoover, Kevin D. and Perez, Stephen J. 2001. "Truth and
Robustness in Cross-Country Growth Regressions", University of
California Davis Discussion Paper in Economics, No. 01-01.
Hunt, Jennifer. 1992. "The Impact of the 1962 Repatriates from
Algeria on the French Labor Market". Industrial and Labor Relations
Review. 45: pp. 556-572.
Jones, Kathleen and Smith, Anthony D. 1970. The Economic Impact of
Commonwealth Immigration. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Karayalcin, Cem. 1994. "Temporary and Permanent
Migration". Journal of Development Economics. 43: pp. 197-215.
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1967. Europe's Postwar Growth: The
Role of Labor Supply. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Lalonde, Robert J. and Topel, Robert H. 1997. "Economic Impact
of International Migration and the Economic Performance of
Migrants". In Handbook of Population and Family Economics, Volume
1B. Eds. Mark R. Rosenzweig and Oded Stark. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Layard, Richard, Blanchard Olivier, Dornbusch, Rudiger and Krugman,
Paul. 1992. East-West Migration: The Alternatives. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
Levine, Paul. 1999. "The Welfare Economics of Immigration
Control", Journal of Population Economics. 12: pp. 23-43.
Levine, Paul, Lotti, Emanuela and Pearlman, Joseph. 2002. "The
Immigration Surplus Revisited in a Model with Endogenous Growth".
Mimeo, Department of Economics, University of Surrey.
Levine, Ross and Renalt, David. 1992. "A Sensitivity Analysis
of Cross-Country Growth Regressions", American Economic Review.
82(4): pp. 942-963.
Lucas, Robert E. 1988. "On the Mechanics of Economic
Development". Journal of Monetary Economics. 22(1): pp. 3-42.
Lucas, Robert E. B. and Stark, Oded. 1985. "Motivations to
Remit: Evidence from Botswana". Journal of Political Economy.
93(5): pp. 901-918.
Lundborg, Per and Segerstrom, Paul S. 2000. "International
Migration and Growth in Developed Countries: A Theoretical
Analysis". Economica. 67: pp. 579-604.
Lundborg, Per and Segerstrom, Paul S. 2002. "The Growth and
Welfare Effects of International Mass Migration". Journal of
International Economics. 56: pp. 177-204.
Macmillen, Malcolm J. 1982. "The Economic Effects of
International Migration: A Survey". Journal of Common Market
Studies. 20: pp. 245-267.
Mankiw, N. Greogory, Romer, David and Weil, David N. 1992. "A
Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth", Quarterly Journal
of Economics. 107(2): pp. 407-437.
McCormick, Barry and Wahba, Jackline. 2001. "Overseas Work
Experience, Savings and Entrepreneurship Amongst Return Migrants to
LDCs". Scottish Journal of Political Economy. 48: pp. 164-178.
Merkle, Lucie and Zimmermann, Klaus F. 1992. "Savings,
Remittances, and Return Migration". Economics Letters. 38: pp.
77-81.
Miyagiwa, Kaz. 1991. "Scale Economies in Education and the
Brain Drain Problem". International Economic Review. 32(3): pp.
743- 759.
Mountford, Andrew. 1997. "Can a Brain Drain be Good for Growth
in the Source Economy?". Journal of Development Economics. 53: pp.
287-303.
Neal, Larry and Uselding, Paul. 1972. "Immigration a Neglected
Source of American Economic Growth: 1790 to 1912", Oxford Economic
Papers. 24: pp. 66-88.
OECD. 1997. Trends in International Migration. Paris: Organisation
for Economic Development.
Paine, Suzanne. 1974. Exporting Workers: The Turkish Case.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Premer, Matthias and Walz, Uwe. 1994. "Divergent Regional
Development, Factor Mobility, and Nontraded Goods". Regional
Science and Urban Economics. 24(6): 707-722.
Reichlin, Pietro and Rustichini, Aldo. 1993. "Diverging Patterns in a Two Country Model with Endogenous Labor Migration".
Universite Catholique de Louvain CORE Discussion Paper No. 9332.
Romer, Paul M. 1986. "Increasing Returns and Long-Run
Growth". Journal of Political Economy. 94(5): pp. 1002-1037.
Romer, Paul M. 1990. "Endogenous Technical Change".
Journal of Political Economy. 98(5): S71-S102.
Sachs, Jeffrey D. and Warner, Andrew M. 1997. "Fundamental
Sources of LongRun Growth". American Economic Review. 87(2): pp.
184-188.
Schiff, Maurice. 1996. "South-North Migration and Trade: A
Survey". World Bank Working Paper No. 1696.
Segerstrom, Paul S. 1998. "Endogenous Growth without Scale
Effects". American Economic Review. 88(5): pp. 1290-1310.
Sinn, Hans-Werner. 2002. "EU Enlargement and the Future of the
Welfare State". Scottish Journal of Political Economy. 49: pp.
104-115.
Solow, Robert M. 1956. "A Contribution to the Theory of
Economic Growth". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 70(1): pp. 65-94.
Stark, Oded, Helmenstein, Christian and Prskawetz, Alexia. 1997.
"A Brain Gain with a Brain Drain". Economic s Letters. 55: pp.
227-234.
Stark, Oded, Helmenstein, Christian and Prskawetz, Alexia. 1998.
"Human Capital Depletion, Human Capital Formation and Migration, a
Blessing or a 'Curse'?". Economics Letters. 60: pp.
363-367.
Steineck, A. 1996. "The Factor Market Effects of
Immigration". In Migrants in the European Labour Market. Ed. Saziye
Gazioglu. Aberdeen: J-Net. pp. 1-30.
Taylor, Alan M. 1997. "Peopling the Pampa: On the Impact of
Mass Migration to the River Plate, 1870-1914" Explorations in
Economic History. 34: 100-132.
Taylor, Alan M. 1999. "Sources of Convergence in the Late
Nineteenth Century". European Economic Review. 43: pp. 1621-45.
United Nations. 2000. Replacement Migration: Is it a Solution to
Declining and Ageing Populations? New York: Population Division,
Department of Economics and Social Affairs.
Walz, Uwe. 1995. "Growth (Rate) Effects of Migration".
Zeitschrift fur Wirtschrift-u.Sozialwissenschaften. 115: pp. 199-221.
Zimmermann, Klaus F. 1995. "The European Migration
Problem". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9(2): pp. 45-62.
Stephen Drinkwater
Department of Economics
University of Surrey, UK
Paul Levine
Department of Economics
University of Surrey, UK
Emanuela Lotti
Department of Economics
University of Surrey, UK
Joseph Pearlman
Department of Economics
London Metropolitan University, UK
NOTES
(1.) See Zimmermann (1995) for a summary of the migration
experiences of European countries in the post-war period.
(2.) Bauer and Zimmermann (1999) provide a recent review of the
determinants of international migration and the characteristics of
immigrants.
(3.) There have been a number of recent surveys of the migration
literature. Friedberg and Hunt (1995) mainly review empirical studies of
the impact of migration, Ghatak, Levine and Wheatley-Price (1996) focus
mainly on the migration decision, and Schiff (1996) explores whether
trade liberalization and free migration policies are substitutes. Borjas
(1999)--building on Borjas (1994, 1995)--focuses on two main aspects of
the economic analysis of immigration, namely the determinants of the
immigration decision and the impact of immigrants on the host country.
Commander et al. (2002) set out a number of ways in which models address
the brain drain phenomena. The closest to our survey in terms of scope
is provided by Steineck (1996). Our survey builds on this paper, drawing
on the substantial literature in more recent years, particularly
regarding endogenous growth.
(4.) The effect on per capita consumption is more subtle depending
on whether the savings rate is above or below the 'golden
rule' that maximizes per capita steady-state consumption. For
further details, see Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995).
(5.) Lucas and Stark (1985) discuss the motives for sending such
payments.
(6.) The positive growth in this model is achieved through a
positive intergenerational externality.
(7.) It is not clear what happens to the wealth of the dead
consumers.
(8.) The interdependence between immigration and country size works
in the following way: small economies can sell additional goods without
affecting world prices very much. In particular, if we assume an
increase in the supply of unskilled workers, this will determine an
expansion in the unskilled sector first, which is usually grows more
slowly. In this case, the negative effects of growth determined by low
skilled migration is stronger for small economies.
(9.) Even those studies which make use of quasi-experimental
evidence, such as Card (1990) for the Mariel boatlift of Cubans to Miami
and Hunt (1992) for the repatriation of Algerians to France, find that
the inflow of immigrants had only a minimal effect on the wage and
employment levels of native workers.
Table 1.
Winners and Losers under skilled Migration: Static and
Dynamic Aspects
Groups Static Analysis Dynamic Analysis
Northern Capitalists Winners Winners or Losers
Northern Workers Losers Winners
Southern Capitalists Losers Winners
Southern Workers Winners Winners
Migrants Winners Winners