Original sin and the exchange rate regime debate: lessons from Latin American and transition countries.
Jonas, Jiri
INTRODUCTION
The financial crises of the 1990s have ignited an intense debate
about the international financial architecture. The question of what
exchange rate regime is optimal for emerging market countries (EMCs)
becoming integrated with the international capital market has attracted
special attention. The fact that all of the EMCs suffering a financial
crisis in the 1990s had some kind of fixed exchange rate arrangement has
discredited the so-called soft peg as a preferable or even a viable
exchange rate arrangement. Even though views continued to differ about
what exchange rate arrangements are appropriate for EMCs, (2) a
consensus seemed to be emerging favouring the so-called corner
solutions, either a flexible regime or a hard peg such as a currency
board arrangement (CBA), dollarisation, or creation of a monetary union.
The collapse of Argentina's CBA, accompanied by a serious
currency, banking, and debt crisis, will probably have important effects
on the debate about what exchange rate regimes are appropriate for EMCs.
For most of the 1990s, Argentina was considered a successful economy.
The view seemed widely be held that the CBA had contributed much to
Argentina's successful stabilisation and resumption of growth.
However, after its collapse in late 2001, history will probably judge
its CBA less kindly.
In this paper, I will highlight the link between the inherent
vulnerability of the EMCs (the so-called original sin hypothesis) and
the operation of different exchange rate regimes. I will begin with a
brief review of the latest discussion about exchange rate arrangements
for EMCs following the recent financial crises. Then I will discuss the
structural weaknesses that typically make EMCs vulnerable to negative
external shocks. I will illustrate how these weaknesses affect different
currency regimes, using examples such as Argentina with its CBA, Brazil
with its floating currency, and Panama with dollarisation.
In the last part, I will discuss why the accession countries in
Central and Eastern Europe are much less sensitive to external shocks no
matter what their exchange rate regime. I will argue that the main
reasons for this difference are smaller role of debt-creating flows in
the financing of current account deficits, higher domestic savings,
and--most important of all--the prospect of accession to the European
Union (EU) and Economic and Monetary Union (EMU), which provides an
important anchor for market expectations and sends a credible signal of
countries' commitment to disciplined economic policies.
ETERNAL CURRENCY REGIME DEBATE
The debate of optimal currency arrangements has a long history (eg,
see Cooper, 1999). The frequent recurrence of this reflects the apparent
fact that no currency arrangement operates satisfactorily at all times
and in all places.
The spectacular collapse of fixed exchange rates in the 1990s, in
connection with financial crises in several EMCs, has illuminated in a
very destructive way the risks of maintaining fixed exchange rate
regimes in EMCs that are becoming integrated into the world capital
market and are therefore exposed to large swings in capital flows. The
conclusions drawn from the experience of the 1990s is that it is
significantly more difficult to maintain a successful fixed exchange
rate regime in a world of relatively free capital movements. The
prerequisites for maintaining a successful fixed exchange rate regime
have increased so much that a soft peg is no longer a viable option for
most, if not all, emerging market countries.
After the collapse of the fixed currency regimes in Asia and
elsewhere, a consensus began to emerge in favour of the so-called
'corner solutions.' This view holds that EMCs open to capital
flows should choose either a freely floating exchange rate or a hard
currency peg, that is, either dollarisation or a CBA. Some economists
expressed no preference; others supported either one or the other. (3)
It appears that most EMCs are moving toward more flexible currency
regimes (see Fischer, 2001), but some authors have documented that the
movement toward more flexibility is not so clear when one examines the
actual practices of exchange rate management as opposed to the declared
currency regimes. (4)
What is noteworthy in this debate is that all corner solutions,
that is, the currency board, dollarisation, and the float appear to have
serious problems that can complicate exchange rate management and
economic policy in EMCs. It is possible to raise serious objections
against any of these currency regimes, and to find evidence of problems
in practice.
* CBA: Even before the collapse of Argentina's CBA, there were
serious reservations about whether this currency regime could be applied
to more than a handful of EMCs. Roubini (2001) argues that the reason
for the success of countries with CBAs was not the currency regime but
the fact that they were pursuing correct policies otherwise. Countries
pursuing correct policies do not need to adopt a CBA. Goldstein (2002)
lists the potential drawbacks of a CBA, and concludes that this regime
is appropriate only for countries with poor policy track records but
solid fiscal and financial sector fundamentals. The collapse of
Argentina's CBA gives the views of these skeptics a further boost.
* Dollarisation: Dollarisation was sometimes seen as a solution in
cases where neither a CBA nor a floating currency was an attractive
alternative. However, as Edwards (2001) argues, there is little
empirical evidence to justify the view of dollarisation's
proponents that it is a workable and attractive currency arrangement for
more than a small number of countries.
* Floating currencies: Calvo and Reinhart (2000) have argued that
floating is less advantageous for EMCs than its proponents suggest. They
note that EMCs that float their currencies nominally exhibit relatively
more variable interest rates and relatively less exchange rate
variability than developed countries, and that they pursue procyclical
interest rate policies. In their words, EMCs exhibit a 'fear of
floating'--they are unable or unwilling to enjoy the most important
benefit of a floating currency, which is the ability to implement their
own monetary policy. Policymakers in EMCs are concerned about the
effects on their economies of large exchange rate fluctuations, and try
to limit these fluctuations through more aggressive interest rate
policies and interventions in the foreign exchange market. Under such
conditions, the exchange rate does not serve as an absorber of external
shocks, but is rather seen as a potential channel of instability.
Furthermore, for EMCs depreciations can be contractionary, because the
adverse balance sheet effect of a weaker currency outweighs its positive
effect on net exports. Calvo and Reinhart argue that the middle ground
is not actually disappearing, and that in practice, 'corner'
solutions are still rare.
The debate about the optimal currency arrangement for EMCs suggests
one conclusion: the inherent vulnerabilities of these countries makes
the choice of the currency regime especially difficult, and increases
the probability that whatever regime is chosen will not operate
smoothly.
EMERGING MARKET COUNTRIES ARE VULNERABLE BY DEFINITION
By definition, EMCs are very vulnerable. 'Emerging' means
that these economies are abandoning the protective shield of
administrative controls by liberalising economic activity and opening
themselves to trade and financial flows. In the process they become more
dependent on external economic and financial conditions. They become
more exposed to external competition, more sensitive to capital flows,
and more dependent on economic activity in the rest of the world. While
this integration should ultimately bring many benefits, these economies
must travel a long road before they can reach the degree of stability
and resistance to external shocks which the developed economies enjoy.
This road is full of danger. (5)
There are several reasons for EMCs' financial fragility (see
Eichengreen and Hausmann, 1999). Their inherent vulnerability has even
given rise to an 'original sin' hypothesis. For various
reasons, including their histories of price and financial instabilities
and a large degree of currency and interest rate volatility, the
financial markets of EMCs are insufficiently developed. They do not
provide their borrowers with many opportunities to borrow long-term in
the domestic currency, particularly from nonresidents. The borrowers
must therefore borrow either short-term, or in foreign currency. Such a
composition of borrowing makes debtors sensitive and vulnerable to
external shocks, complicates the conduct of monetary policy, and makes
any currency regime potentially problematic. If exchange rate fluctuates
a lot in a floating regime, the domestic currency value of external debt
in foreign currency will also fluctuate, threatening financial distress and even bankruptcy to borrowers with external debt. At the same time,
efforts to limit exchange rate fluctuations with a more active use of
interest rate policy would affect the costs of borrowing in domestic
currency. It would immediately increase the borrowing costs for floating
rate debt, or increase the costs of the new debt that has to replace the
maturing debt. All this can cause financial problems for borrowers whose
debt is denominated in domestic currency. (6)
In principle, there are two solutions to the "original
sin' problem. (7) An immediate and apparently simple solution would
be to get rid of the domestic currency and dollarise. As argued by
Eichengreen and Hausmann (1999), this would do away with currency
mismatches and reduce maturity mismatches, because of the possibility to
borrow more long-term in dollars. However, as we have noted,
dollarisation is not a free lunch: it can have its own problems, and may
be appropriate for only a small number of countries.
A second solution would be to seek redemption from the original sin
by correcting the financial market deficiencies that produced the
vulnerable structure of borrowing. It is not clear how easily this can
be accomplished. All depends on the cause of the original sin.
Eichengreen and Hausmann argue that foreign creditors are unlikely to
lend to a sovereign in its own currency, if the sovereign is capable of
manipulating the exchange rate and thus the real value of its external
debt. The authors speculate that until there is a strong political
constituency that would provide a sufficient guarantee that the
sovereign will not pursue such a strategy, external borrowing in
domestic currency will not develop. Cooper (1999) provides some
additional reasons for scepticism about the possibility that local
markets will develop. He argues that a broad and well-functioning
financial market is unlikely to develop under a floating exchange rate
regime. He postulates the existence of a vicious circle, in which
imperfectly developed financial markets contribute to large exchange
rate fluctuations, and in their turn these large exchange rate
fluctuations prevent the development of deeper and broader domestic
currency markets. The reason is that large exchange rate fluctuations
cause equally large fluctuations in real value of assets denominated in
domestic currency, thus giving residents an incentive to invest in a
more stable foreign currency. (8) In contrast, Goldstein (2002) argues
that the original sin could be cured, which in turn should permit the
successful operation of a currency regime called 'managed float
plus.' Goldstein's 'plus' includes inflation
targeting to provide a credible nominal anchor for the economy, and
measures to reduce currency mismatches in the economy.
The problems that EMCs are facing in connection with external
borrowing are not limited to the terms of external borrowing arising
from the original sin problem. There is a related problem involving the
quantity of external borrowing. External borrowing can become a problem
when domestic savings are already very high, in which case it could
finance excessive investment and ultimately inefficient projects. It can
also be a problem when domestic savings are too low, in which case the
country would become too dependent on external borrowing, and its
investment activity could fluctuate excessively in response to
fluctuations in the availability of external savings.
The first problem was typical for some Southeast Asian countries
that had high domestic savings before the crisis, while the second
problem is typical of many Latin American countries with low domestic
savings.
In the EMCs of Southeast Asia, domestic savings were traditionally
high, well over 30 percent of GDP, so that the inflows of foreign
savings augmented the already abundant savings available to finance
domestic investments. The result was very large investment-to-output
ratios in these economies, sometimes approaching 40 percent. This
eventually led to overinvestment, excess capacity, and even to bubbles.
The subsequent correction of these excessive investments caused enormous
swings in current account balances, which moved from deficits of 6-8
percent of GDP to like-sized surpluses 1 or 2 years later as these
countries stopped using external savings and began to export some of
their domestic savings and to accumulate foreign reserves.
For most EMCs in Latin America the situation was different. Large
inflows of external savings were a welcome supplement to very low
domestic savings. Here, the problem was that a relatively large share of
domestic investment was dependent on the availability of external
savings.9 This made domestic investment and economic activity much more
sensitive to the availability of external savings. At the same time,
large fluctuations in economic activity could reduce the availability of
external savings, further worsening the external vulnerability resulting
from low savings. Over time, heavy reliance on external savings results
in high external debt and external vulnerability. As concern grows about
the debtor country's ability to continue servicing its external
debt, the rise in external debt will gradually begin to inhibit access
to external savings.
There is good reason why some of the savings should flow from the
highly developed industrial economies to the less developed EMCs. EMCs
are correctly seen as a having potential for higher-return investment
opportunities. The stock of capital and the capital-labour ratio are
typically lower in EMCs than in developed economies, and the marginal
productivity of capital is higher. (10) The differences between the
capital-labour ratios and the marginal products of capital in developing
countries and developed countries are so large that in a world
conforming to the neoclassical growth model, we should see much higher
capital flows to developing countries (see Lucas, 1990; Lipschitz et
al., 2002). However the original sin-related weaknesses in the structure
of EMCs' external borrowing, and the problems of excessive
investment and low domestic savings, are among the market imperfections
that cause the reality to differ from the predictions of the
neoclassical growth model. The EMCs face a dilemma. Given their
relatively low level of economic development, they would normally be
recipients of foreign savings coming from the more developed countries,
but the structural vulnerability (see the original sin) of EMCs implies
that foreign savings often come in forms that make the borrower country
more sensitive to exchange rate movements and other shocks, thus
increasing their external vulnerability.
THREE CURRENCY REGIMES--THREE PROBLEMS
It should be noted that the concern about the operation of
individual currency arrangements has been largely based on the
examination of countries in Latin America. This reflects probably the
fact that among EMCs, those located in Latin America are especially
vulnerable to adverse changes in the external environment, and their
vulnerability to external shocks complicates policy management under any
currency regime.
We will now look at the experience of three Latin American
countries with different currency regimes that illustrate this point. We
start with the collapse of CBA in Argentina, which we examine in more
detail.
Argentina and the CBA
Argentina has a long history of financial instability, high
inflation, and defaults on its debt. After a particularly devastating episode of hyperinflation at the end of the 1980s, Argentina introduced
the CBA. The stabilisation programme brought positive results. Between
1989 and 1990, the public budget deficit fell from 7.6 to 2.3 percent,
and inflation fell from 1344 in 1990 to 3.9 percent in 1994. Real GDP
grew rapidly and foreign capital began to flow into the country. The CBA
seem to have delivered the long-awaited stability.
The CBA was seriously tested during the Mexican crisis in
1994-1995, but it survived--arguably even strengthened. When the Asian
financial crisis broke out in 1997, Argentina was initially unaffected
and continued to enjoy good access to international capital market.
However, the Russian crisis in August 1998 and Brazil's crisis and
floating of its currency in 1999 made themselves felt in Argentina as
well. Argentina's need to borrow did not diminish, but the terms of
borrowing began to deteriorate as investors became more risk-averse and
less willing to invest in emerging markets generally. While some other
countries were able to adjust to the scarcity of external borrowing by
adjusting their exchange rates and current accounts, Argentina's
ability to adjust was limited by the policy constraints of the CBA and
the relatively closed nature of its economy. In 2001, Argentina's
situation quickly deteriorated and ended in a currency, debt, and
banking crisis.
The collapse of the CBA resulted from a vicious circle created by
the interaction of domestic vulnerabilities and a series of adverse
external shocks, combined with the economy's limited ability to
respond flexibly to these shocks.
The first and, to many analysts, the most prominent cause was the
role of fiscal policy (see Mussa, 2002). Maintaining fiscal discipline
is an important condition for the successful operation of a CBA. The
CBA-based stabilisation programme launched in March 1991 brought
reductions of public spending and the public deficit. The CBA hardened
the government budget constraint by ending the monetary financing of
government deficits, but this tightening began to leak over time. As
Argentina's macroeconomic fundamentals and credibility improved,
its access to international borrowing improved as well. Two new sources
of public deficit financing appeared: privatisation revenues and
borrowing in the international capital market. There was no dramatic
weakening of fiscal discipline during the 1990s, but budget deficits
began to creep up and public debt increased (Table 1).
Fiscal discipline at the provincial level remained weak as well. An
important source of provincial government revenues were transfers from
the federal government, maintained at a minimum level regardless of the
volume of the revenues collected by the central government. This
arrangement provided insufficient incentive for fiscal discipline on the
part of the provincial governments. Table 1 shows that the provincial
budget balance remained in deficit throughout the 1990s.
The second factor contributing to the crisis and the collapse of
the CBA was Argentina's chronic dependence on external savings.
Argentina's domestic savings was relatively low compared with other
countries at a similar stage of economic development, and declined
continuously during the 1990s, forcing the country to rely on foreign
savings (see Table 2).
Argentina's heavy dependence on external savings has had two
negative consequences. First, the availability of external savings was
an important determinant of both domestic investment and economic growth
in Argentina. When a worsening external situation made investors less
forthcoming and reduced capital inflows, Argentina's economic
activity weakened rapidly. Argentina's heavy reliance on external
savings imposed uncertainty, subjected economic growth to sudden large
swings and increased vulnerability to shifts in investor sentiment.
Second, Argentina's prolonged reliance on external savings has
resulted in rapidly and persistently increasing external debt (see Table
3).
As we have noted, it is not unusual for EMCs to rely on external
savings and thus run current account deficits. In addition to the
problem of the quality of emerging market borrowing discussed in the
previous section (ie, the maturity and currency composition), there was
another factor that increased Argentina's vulnerability and
contributed to the crisis. Although Argentina became very open to
capital flows in the 1990s, it remained relatively closed to trade
flows. (11) Argentina's exports in the 1990s were very low, not
even reaching 10 percent of GDP. Argentina's long-term reliance on
external financing and the rapid growth of its external debt were not
accompanied by matching rapid increases in competitiveness and export
growth that would permit servicing the growing external debt and thereby
maintain Argentina's access to international capital markets (Table
4).
This lack of openness became a major weakness. Measured in terms of
GDP, Argentina's external debt never reached excessive levels
(before the currency depreciation). In 1999, it was over 50 percent of
GDP, high but not excessive. However, by the end of the 1990s,
Argentina's external debt reached more than 400 percent of its
annual exports. Argentina's external debt continued to increase,
but its ability to increase foreign currency revenues from exports of
goods and services was growing more slowly.
In short, its 10-year sojourn under the CBA did not change
Argentina's status very much as an emerging market country, with
all the attendant weaknesses and vulnerabilities. The CBA allowed
Argentina to import financial stability, and thereby enabled Argentina
to access the international capital market and increase its external
borrowing. Meanwhile the stock of external debt was increasing, and the
economy remained vulnerable to external shocks. It remained mostly
closed to foreign trade, which made it hard to offset changes in the
capital account balance by adjusting the current account balance. Such
adjustments were made still more difficult by the currency regime, which
precluded nominal devaluation of the currency.
Brazil and the float
The recent developments in Brazil illustrate that even a successful
exit from the pegged currency regime may not make the country immune to
original sin-related fragilities. Brazil's exit from its exchange
rate peg in early 1999 was relatively painless. In spite of replacing
the peg with a currency regime described as a managed float, Brazil
exhibits the standard 'fear of float' syndrome. It tries to
prevent large exchange rate fluctuations, seeks to limit depreciation
when the currency is under pressure, and is unable to pursue an
independent monetary policy. Brazil's monetary policy is strongly
procyclical. Why cannot a country with a floating exchange rate benefit
from the pursuit of an independent monetary policy?
The main reason is Brazil's exposure to external
vulnerabilities similar to Argentina's. Brazil's external debt
is relatively large, and its economy is relatively closed. In 2001,
Brazilian exports of goods and services were only about 13 percent of
GDP, and although its external debt was about 42 percent of GDP, it was
over 300 percent of its exports. Brazil's public sector is also
financially vulnerable. A large part of Brazil's public debt (about
80 percent by the end of 2002) is indexed either to SELIC interest rate
(central bank's policy rate) and thus sensitive to central
bank's interest rate changes, or to the currency's exchange
rate, and thus sensitive to exchange rate fluctuations. Currency
depreciation and high interest rates explain why the net public
debt-to-GDP ratio has risen from 35 percent in 1997 to about 55 percent
in 2002. (12)
The political uncertainty that preceded the presidential elections
in October 2002 illustrates the policy dilemmas created by this
vulnerable structure of public debt. The polls that suggested that the
presidential elections might be won by a candidate who is less favoured
by the markets have administered a significant shock to a market
confidence, which has contributed both to a weakening of the Brazilian
currency and to a significant widening of the spread on Brazilian debt.
(13) As a result, the monetary authorities had to choose between two
unpalatable alternatives. The first alternative was to respond to the
increased market uncertainty by raising interest rates to prevent a
sharp currency depreciation but increasing the costs of servicing that
part of the public debt that is indexed to the SELIC interest rate. The
second alternative was to keep policy interest rate low and let the
currency to depreciate, which would result in an increase in the cost of
servicing that part of the external debt that is linked to the exchange
rate. Letting currency depreciate would also carry the risks of
increasing inflation (and inflationary expectations), which would cause
higher market interest rates to reflect the higher inflation premium.
Moreover, higher inflation would require higher policy interest rates in
the future to bring inflation back down.
Despite weakening economic growth, the central bank has decided to
tighten monetary policy and raised interest rates sharply, from 17
percent in October 2002 to 26.5 percent in February 2003, but this did
not prevent a currency from weakening. Combination of higher SELIC rate
and a more depreciated currency contributed to an increase in net public
debt to GDP ratio by about 5 percentage points in 2002. In turn,
continued rise in the debt burden weighed further on market confidence.
Only the clear statement and policy steps of the new administration
indicating the continuity of stability-oriented policy and the
determination to continue servicing Brazil's external debt have
alleviated somewhat the dilemma as they helped to improve market
confidence in early 2003. However, even though Brazil's spreads
fell to below 800 points in May, Brazil still remains vulnerable to any
future adverse shocks and the floating currency regime will not insulate it from these.
Panama and dollarisation
What about the opposite end of the spectrum of currency regimes?
Could dollarisation improve economic performance and bring the desired
stability and policy credibility? So far, there is little long-term
empirical evidence about the operation of dollarised economies. Panama
is an exception and has therefore been thoroughly analysed. The
supporters of dollarisation point to Panama's history of low
inflation and relatively strong growth. Furthermore, Panama is the only
country in Latin America that has been able to issue 30-year mortgages.
Not everything is perfect in Panama, however. A more sceptical
analysis of Panama's performance is worth quoting: 'In spite
of not having a central bank, or a currency of its own, for years Panama
failed to maintain fiscal discipline. Initially, these large deficits
were financed through borrowing from abroad. And when foreign debt
became too high, the IMF stepped in with fresh resources. And when it
was not enough, Panama restructured its debt.' (Edwards, 2001). If
this experience looks familiar, it is not surprising. It could as well
be applied to Argentina's experience under the CBA in the 1990s.
The similarities underscore the point that regardless of the currency
regime, a government that does not have the political courage or will to
adjust public spending to available resources will always find some ways
to finance spending in excess of its resources, and in the process will
make its economy vulnerable to adverse shocks and undermine its
long-term growth performance.
Another country in the region that has introduced dollarisation,
Ecuador, has not yet accumulated enough experience with this currency
regime to permit drawing definitive conclusions. However, Ecuador's
problems in the first years of dollarisation only confirmed that a
change in the currency regime per se, even introduction of
dollarisation, does not guarantee a pursuit of disciplined policies.
These observations may leave one with a rather pessimistic conclusions about the prospects of EMCs. But even though original sin
can have long-lasting and serious consequences for EMCs, it is not
something they are doomed to live with forever. To obtain a better
understanding of what policies can help them achieve a rapid redemption
from original sin, it may be useful to look at a different group of
EMCs.
ACCESSION COUNTRIES IN EUROPE: A DIFFERENT STORY?
The problems of Latin American countries with various exchange rate
arrangements, discussed in the previous part, are not typical of all
EMCs. The accession countries of Central and Eastern Europe seem much
less vulnerable to adverse shocks or changes in financial markets'
sentiment--regardless of their currency arrangements.
Table 5 shows that in terms of GDP, the level of the external debts
and current account deficits of the accession countries is relatively
high, generally similar to what we see in the countries of Latin
America.
Accordingly, one might assume that these countries suffer from
problems similar to those of Argentina, Brazil, and other countries in
Latin America, that is, that they would be vulnerable to an adverse
external environment, that the price of their external debt would
increase with investors' increasing aversion to risk, that they
would find international borrowing more difficult to obtain during times
of adverse external shocks, that their currencies would be weakening,
and that they would be unable to pursue independent monetary policies
and countercyclical fiscal policies.
However, the reality is somewhat different. Even though these
economies are very open to capital flows, there is little evidence of
external vulnerability we saw in some Latin American countries. Although
they have suffered temporary contagion from financial crises elsewhere,
particularly the Russian crisis of 1998, this contagion was limited in
scope and duration. Their asset prices suffered only a relatively small
and temporary setback (International Monetary Fund, 1999, Chapter III).
The relative absence among these countries of vulnerability to
turbulences in the world economy and in other EMCs is illustrated by the
behaviour of their external borrowing spreads, shown in Table 6.
The relative resilience to adverse external conditions of the
financial indicators of the countries of Central and Eastern Europe
means that when the accession countries need to borrow abroad at all,
they can do so on much better terms than countries in Latin America.
Table 7 shows the coupon rates of latest bond issues in domestic
currency and in the euro for selected countries in the region.
First, the countries that issued euro-denominated public debt were
able to do so at relatively long maturities--mostly 10 years--and at
reasonably low yields. Second, for countries with a CBA--Bulgaria and
Lithuania--there is not much difference in yields between domestic and
euro-denominated debt, which reflects low currency risk. For countries
with floating currencies--the Slovak Republic and Poland--their
relatively higher yields on domestic currency debt compared to the
yields on euro-denominated debt reflect a higher currency risk. (Note
that the euro-denominated Slovak bond shown in Table 8 was issued in
2000. If it were issued in 2002, market analysts estimate that the yield
would be in the range 5.5-6.0 percent.)
Third, governments of these countries have largely been able to
finance their borrowing needs from local markets, by issuing debt
denominated in domestic currency. This has an important advantage:
financing these governments' borrowing needs is less dependent on
access to the international capital markets. (14) Market capitalisation of the euro-denominated and dollar-denominated bonds is relatively small
(see Table 8). Market capitalisation of domestic currency debt is
relatively high in Poland and Hungary (around 30 percent of GDP) and
somewhat less in the Czech Republic (about 15 percent of GDP). However,
these countries have basically no restrictions on nonresident purchases
of domestic-currency government debt, and it is estimated that foreign
investors hold 30-35 percent of Hungary's outstanding local
currency bonds, 15-20 percent of Poland's, and 10-15 percent of the
Czech Republic's.
The relatively small external vulnerability of the accession
countries is also evidenced by their conduct of monetary policy.
Accession countries with flexible currency regimes are able to pursue
rather independent monetary policies. (15) To the extent that the fear
of floating is present, it is a different 'fear,' namely fear
of too strong a currency that would damage competitiveness and economic
activity. The relative independence of monetary policy in the accession
countries can be seen by comparing changes in policy interest rates in
these countries with those in the euro area. Figure 1 shows that during
a period of stable or even increasing ECB interest rates in 1999 and
2000, the central banks of the Czech Republic and Hungary were able to
reduce interest rates significantly. In fact, in July 2002, Czech
interest rates fell below euro area interest rates. Higher interest
rates in Hungary and especially in Poland were partly explained by
efforts to bring down higher inflation, but even these countries have
been able to cut domestic interest rates regardless of the ECB's
interest rate policy. (16)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
For comparison, Figure 2 shows policy rates in the United States (the targeted federal funds rate) and Brazil (SELIC rate) during the
period of Brazil's currency float. Two things stand out. First,
adjusted for the inflation differential, the difference between the two
rates is significantly greater than in the accession countries (perhaps
with some exception made for Poland). Second, when the Fed began to cut
interest rates aggressively in January 2001, the Banco Central do Brazil
not only did not follow, but instead had to increase its interest rate
significantly, so that the difference between the US and Brazilian
policy rates widened from about 10 to 25 points.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Why are the accession countries less sensitive to external
developments and to financial contagion? Why are they able to borrow at
much better terms? Why are they able to pursue relatively independent
policies (in countries with a floating currency) or why do their CBAs
seem to enjoy relatively high credibility? There are several reasons for
this relative resilience to contagion.
First, while the size of the accession countries' external
debt is not significantly different from that of countries in Latin
America when measured in terms of GDP, it is much smaller when measured
in terms of exports (see Table 9). The accession countries are much more
open, and thus their debt-to-exports ratios are generally much lower
than Latin America's (except for Poland, exports usually represent
some 50 percent or more of GDP). Therefore, for a given level of the
external debt to GDP ratio, there is less concern about the availability
of foreign currency earnings to service it. A higher degree of trade
openness also makes changes in the real exchange rate more effective as
an instrument for adjusting the current account balance. Moreover, only
a small fraction of their external debt is in the form of market
borrowing and liable to be adversely affected by changing sentiment in
the international capital market. This may reflect the fact that the
accession countries do not have long histories of involvement with the
international capital markets, and so have simply not had enough time to
build up high levels of marketable external debt. They have also
implemented the extensive privatisation programmes that have been a
welcome source of financing.
Second, while the accession countries are generally no less
dependent on external savings than the countries of Latin America, as
shown by their relatively large current account deficits, they are able
to cover a large part of these deficits with non-debt-creating foreign
direct investment. Reliance on foreign direct investment is not without
its risks and problems, but it is clearly a less risky form of capital
inflows than debt-creating instruments. (17) Table 10 compares the
extent to which net inflow of foreign direct investment covers the
current account deficits of Argentina, Brazil and accession countries.
While Argentina and Brazil were also able to finance their current
account deficits from net inflow of foreign direct investment, they
still had to devote a significant part of their export revenues to
servicing previously accumulated external debt and had to resort to more
external borrowing to refinance maturing debt.
Third, and closely related, domestic savings in accession countries
are generally much higher than in Argentina and Brazil (and other Latin
American countries as well). To the extent that higher growth requires
higher investment, low domestic savings force countries to rely more on
external savings as a source of financing investment spending. This has
two consequences: first, when for some reason foreign savings become
less available, investment has to be cut unless domestic savings
increase. This could result in increased output volatility. Second,
prolonged extensive reliance on foreign savings in the form of
debt-creating capital inflows can result in increased debt burden and
external vulnerability. This is the case particularly when economies
remain relatively closed to trade flows and do not generate enough
foreign currency earnings to service, without problems, external debt.
It is exactly this interaction of low domestic savings and reliance on
external savings (that is, opening to capital flows) and low share of
exports in national output that makes any currency regime vulnerable, as
in case of Argentina and Brazil. This contrasts with the combination of
relatively high domestic savings and large openness to trade flows that
makes most accession countries less vulnerable to adverse market
sentiment.
Fourth, and perhaps most important, the accession countries benefit
from the confidence-building effects of their future EU/EMU accession.
The EU/ EMU membership requirements ensure that they will pursue
macroeconomic policies and structural reforms that will produce
financial stability and solid economic performance. The prospect of
EU/EMU membership serves as an important policy anchor and disciplining
influence, and thus helps increase the credibility of policy in the
accession countries. This holds regardless of which exchange rate regime
is in place. For countries with CBAs (Bulgaria, Estonia, Lithuania),
EU/EMU membership provides guarantees that their exit from the CBA will
be from a position of strength (since they must meet the strict
qualification criteria for EMU membership), rather than from a position
of weakness and crisis. For countries with flexible currency regimes, it
helps anchor inflation expectations, and thus limits exchange rate
fluctuations.
In short, the accession countries have entered a virtuous circle:
future EU/EMU membership provides an anchor for economic policies,
improves policy credibility, and contributes to positive expectations
about future economic performance. This promotes the development of
local financial markets and reduces dependence on external financing.
Less need of external financing, together with large inflows of FDI, is
rewarded with better access to the international capital markets. The
favourable terms and diminished need for external financing make it
possible to avoid the build-up of external weaknesses that increase
economies' vulnerability to adverse external shocks.
This is not to deny that the prospect of EMU membership does not
bring temporary policy problems of its own, such as the unstable capital
flows and exchange rate fluctuations that precede EMU entry and
enroisation, but as long as the underlying policies are sound, these
problems should be manageable.
CONCLUSION
After the collapse during the past decade of pegged currency
regimes in many EMCs, a consensus has emerged that the so-called soft
peg regimes are not suitable for EMCs that have and become integrated
into the international capital market. There seems to be a further
consensus that these unsuitable regimes should be replaced by one or
another of the so-called 'corner solutions'--a floating
currency, or the hard peg in the form of a CBA, or dollarisation, or
membership in a monetary union--as the appropriate regime for an EMC.
The collapse of the CBA in Argentina has raised new questions about
the optimal currency arrangements for EMCs. Argentina's experience
has shown that even a CBA may not deliver the degree of policy
discipline and stability that its proponents had hoped for. We have also
briefly discussed the experience of Brazil with a managed float and
Panama with dollarisation--to emphasise the point that a floating
currency does not necessarily provide room for an independent monetary
policy, and that using someone else's currency does not establish
necessary policy discipline or prevent a build-up of financial
vulnerability.
The conclusion is that no particular currency arrangement can per
se explain why a country finds itself vulnerable to shifts in market
sentiment that cause large fluctuations in economic activity, and why it
is unable to pursue independent policies to smooth out these
fluctuations. These vulnerabilities result not from a particular
currency arrangement, but rather from low domestic savings, heavy
reliance on external savings, and borrowing needs that often cause a
build-up of external debt. Economies that are not sufficiently open to
trade and rely on external borrowing will attain unsustainability sooner
rather than later.
We have discussed why EMCs suffer from vulnerabilities that make
the operation of any exchange rate regime potentially difficult, but
different EMCs suffer from these vulnerabilities in different degree. We
have compared the rather negative experience of the countries in Latin
America with the experience of accession countries in Central and
Eastern Europe. The accession countries were relatively untouched by
recent financial crises and turbulence in the international capital
markets. They continued to enjoy good access to external borrowing, and
the prices of their financial assets, including the exchange rate,
suggests no loss of credibility.
The relatively strong credibility and resilience of the accession
countries to external shocks does not depend on their choice of a
currency regime. The currency regimes of the accession countries vary
widely. For countries with CBAs or currency band, it is important to
have a clearly defined exit strategy. For the accession countries this
means their entry into the EMU. The EMU entry provides an important
signal of the commitment to pursue disciplined policies. To countries
with a flexible currency regime, this commitment serves as a potent
nominal anchor that helps them to achieve and maintain price stability,
and promotes the development of local financial markets that make them
less dependent on external financing, and thus less vulnerable to
exchange rate movements. This allows them to pursue relatively
independent monetary policy tailored to the needs of their domestic
economies.
The success of the process of EU/EMU accession for the candidate
countries could provide an important lesson for the EMCs that have
trouble establishing the credibility of their policies and therefore
remain unduly sensitive to conditions in the international capital
markets. Replacing the domestic currencies with the dollar or some other
currency is not the same as joining EMU. The advantage of EMU membership
is not just that it brings to its new members a stable currency enjoying
high credibility. It also means membership in a club with strict rules
for maintaining stability-oriented policies, which is something that
dollarisation alone cannot accomplish.
Table 1: Argentina: public sector balance
and public debt (in percent of GDP) (a)
1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
Consolidated -3.2 -0.5 -0.8 -2.3 -2.3
Federal govt -2.5 -0.2 0.9 -0.5 -0.9
Provincial govt -0.7 -0.2 -0.8 -0.9 -1.4
Public debt $bn 64.7 68.8 77.6 90.3 101.5
In percent of GDP 35.8 30.3 30.1 32.1 36.3
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Consolidated -3.2 -2.1 -2.1 -4.2 -3.6
Federal govt -2.5 -1.6 -1.3 -2.5 -2.4
Provincial govt -0.7 -0.5 -0.8 -1.6 -1.1
Public debt $bn 114.4 111.6 123.5 133.9 144.8
In percent of GDP 38.5 38.1 41.3 47.3 50.8
Source: IMF
(a) Balance of federal and provincial governments does not always
add up to the consolidated balance due to the operation of trust
funds and some other items that affect consolidated balance.
Table 2: Argentina: savings, investment
(in percent of GDP) and GDP growth rate
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Domestic savings 17.1 18.6 19.7 16.2 15.9 15.5 13.9 13.5
External savings 4.1 4.8 0.9 2.7 4.7 5.6 5.1 4.1
Domestic investment 21.2 23.4 20.6 18.9 20.6 21.1 19.0 17.6
Real GDP 6.0 7.1 -4.4 5.5 8.1 3.9 3.4 -0.5
Source: The Economist Intelligence Unit Country Report
Table 3: Argentina: external debt and debt service (a)
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Debt/GDP 27.7 27.8 39.2 42.0 45.7 48.6 53.7 52.7
Debt/exports 395.4 368 336.2 338.6 358.7 379.0 435.7 487.9
Debt service/
exports 36.8 31.8 30.4 39.5 50.2 57.5 75.8 93.5
Source: The Economist Intelligence Unit Country Report
(a) Data here for Argentina are not directly comparable with those
in Table 4, because Table 4 uses a present value of external debt,
while this table uses a nominal value.
Table 4: External debt and debt service, 1998 (a)
Debt service/
Debt/GDP Debt/exports (b) exports (b)
Argentina 52 406 58.2
Brazil 29 340 74.1
Mexico 41 111 20.8
Indonesia 169 252 33.0
Thailand 76 123 19.2
Korea 43 84 12.9
Czech Republic 45 71 15.2
Hungary 63 107 27.3
Russia 62 186 12.1
Source: The World Bank (2000), World Development Indicators
(a) Present value of debt.
(b) Exports of goods and services.
Table 5: Accession countries: indicators of external vulnerability
(in percent of GDP)
Total external debt Current account balance
1998 1999 2000 2001 1998 1999 2000 2001
Czech Republic 40.4 44.8 42.6 36.6 -2.4 -3.0 -4.5 -4.8
Estonia 53.3 58.7 59.4 61.0 -9.2 -5.8 -6.8 -6.8
Hungary 55.8 64.5 66.8 65.1 -4.8 -4.4 -2.9 -2.1
Latvia 50.9 57.5 65.7 73.5 -10.7 -9.8 -6.9 -9.7
Lithuania 34.8 42.4 42.9 44.8 -12.1 -11.2 -6.0 -6.7
Poland 37.3 42.2 44.0 39.5 -4.3 -7.5 -6.3 -4.0
Slovak Republic 55.9 53.4 56.7 53.9 -10.0 -5.0 -3.6 -5.4
Slovenia 24.1 26.9 34.3 36.0 -0.8 -3.9 -3.3 -0.8
Source: IMF
Table 6: Selected countries: sovereign debt spreads
1998 1999 2000 2001 Oct 2002 Dec 2002
Poland 198 199 197 185 250 210
Hungary 155 107 116 78 x x
Argentina 705 548 773 1566 7000 6150
Brazil 825 920 749 863 2200 1460
Source: Bloomberg
Table 7: Selected transition economies: yield on government debt
(in percent)
Local currency Euro
Bulgaria 10Y BGL 7.75% (April 02) 10Y [euro] 7.5% (March 02)
Croatia 7Y HRK 6.25% (Jan 02) 7Y [euro] 6.25% (Feb 02)
Hungary 10Y HUF 7.1% (May 02) 10Y [euro] 5.625% (June 01)
Lithuania 10Y LIT 6.15% (March 02) 10Y [euro] 5.875% (May 02)
Poland l0Y PLZ 8.1% (May 02) 10Y [euro] 5.5% (March 02)
Slovak Republic 10Y SK 7.3% (May 02) 10Y [euro] 7.375% (2000)
Source: Bloomberg
Table 8: Selected transition economies: market capitalisation in
billions (May 2002)
In local currency Of euro bonds Of dollar bonds
($ equivalent) (in [euro]) (in $)
Bulgaria 0.8 1.1 3.8 (a)
Czech Republic 8.0 0.0 0.0
Croatia 2.0 2.5 1.1
Hungary 17.0 3.0 1.5
Poland 40.0 2.1 3.7 (a)
Slovak Republic 6.0 1.5 0.5
Source: Bloomberg
(a) Old Brady bonds.
Table 9: Accession countries: external debt in percent of exports
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Czech Republic 66.6 69 68.3 64.3 56.4 50.9
Estonia 52.5 70.9 70.1 71.9 62.6 65.5
Hungary 138.6 96.2 102.3 106.7 94.9 94.6
Latvia 80 96 99.3 131.1 144.1 161.6
Lithuania 57 63.2 74.8 107.1 95.6 87
Poland 170.8 160.4 175 218.8 214.6 104.2
Slovakia 70.4 83.8 81.8 86.3 76.5 74.5
Slovenia 38 39.4 44.2 51.3 58.1 59.5
Source: European Bank for Reconstruction and Developments (2002)
Table 10: Net FDI inflow in percent of current account deficit
1998 1999 2000 2001
Argentina 32.1 65 121.3 70.2
Brazil 86.5 112.5 133.3 97
Czech Republic 276.9 442.8 185.2 185
Estonia 120 89.8 110.2 101
Hungary 65.2 81 84.6 191
Latvia 45 48.5 81.1 23.1
Lithuania 71 40 54.4 78.6
Poland 73.5 54.3 81 93
Slovakia 17.6 64 300 83.3
Slovenia 166.7 17.5 18.3 340
Source: European Bank for Reconstruction and Developments (2002),
International Monetary Fund (2002)
Table 11: Gross domestic savings in percent of GDP
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Argentina 15.2 13.8 13.1 12.5 18.8
Brazil 15.3 15.4 17.6 16.4 16.0
Czech Republic 27.3 15.4 24.4 25.3 25.4
Estonia 20.1 19.8 18.3 20.2 20.7
Hungary 24.8 14.4 27.2 24.5 24.0
Latvia 18 17.1 19.8 18.9 19.3
Lithuania 12.3 11.5 14.6 17 16.6
Poland 21.9 18.9 19.9 18.5 18.9
Slovakia 25 23.4 22.8 22.9 22.5
Slovenia 25.4 26.9 24.2 24.7 24.7
Source: IMF
(1) The views expressed here are author's own and do not
reflect the official position of the IMF.
(2) As Larrain and Velasco (2001) observe, 'a good deal of
enthusiasm over currency boards owes to the experience of one country,
Argentina, over a fairly brief period of time. All other experiences,
except for Hong Kong's, have been too short-lived to be
informative.'
(3) For examples of the agnostic approach to currency regimes, see
Cooper (1999) and Frankel (1999). Steve Hanke is one of the strongest
proponents of CBA or dollarisation, but many economists seem to prefer
the float. For arguments against CBAs, see Roubini (2001). For a
comprehensive discussion of various views on optimal exchange rate
arrangements, see Goldstein (2002).
(4) For example, Masson (2001) argues that there were frequent
crossings between the different exchange rate regimes in the 1990s,
rather than a shift from middle to corner regimes. See also Calvo and
Reinhart (2000).
(5) Being an emerging market is like being a teenager. The
innocence of childhood is gradually being lost, but the mature judgement
of adulthood is not yet well enough established to guide the teenager
through this sensitive period when he/she becomes exposed to the
temptations and pitfalls of life.
(6) Moreover, faced with an adverse external shock, EMCs with a
large share of debt denominated in foreign currency and/or of short-term
debt will not be able to pursue the same shock-mitigating policies used
by advanced economies with well-established policy credibility and
better developed financial markets. Often, EMCs must pursue procyclical
policies to avoid a loss of confidence and financial instability, in
spite of the cost to output and employment. See Mishkin (1996).
(7) Eichengreen et al. (2002) recently proposed another solution to
the original sin problem: the World Bank and other developments banks
would sponsor a mechanism that would allow the EMCs to issue more debt
in their own currencies. However, the main problem with this mechanism
is that it does not provide strong incentives to address the fundamental
weaknesses and problems of EMCs leading to the original sin problem.
(8) This conclusion holds for very open economies, where changes in
the exchange rate have a strong effect on domestic prices. The obvious
question is whether a fixed (and therefore stable) exchange rate is more
helpful in overcoming the original sin problem. Again the prospects are
not promising, as shown by the experience of Argentina. The CBA helped
speed the establishment of price stability and growth, and allowed
Argentina to borrow abroad, but even a decade of exchange rate stability
could not improve Argentina's credibility enough to redeem it from
its original sin. The former central bank governor Pedro Pou (1999)
complained in 1999, before the crisis escalated, that despite having
played by the currency board's rules for 9 years, Argentina could
not borrow in domestic currency from international investors except at
short-term maturities.
(9) To illustrate, if domestic savings are being used to finance
investments equal to 30 percent of GDP, and the country is also using
external savings (running a current account deficit) equal to 5 percent
of GDP, then external savings are financing one-seventh of total
domestic investments (which equal 35 percent of GDP). If domestic
savings can finance investments worth only 15 percent of GDP, then the
same amount of external savings would be financing one-fourth of total
domestic investment.
(10) However, Baer (2001) correctly observes that it is not only
the return, but also the variance (risk) that determines investors'
willingness to invest in EMCs. High risk can partly or fully cancel the
attractiveness of a high return.
(11) It can be assumed that the low level of domestic savings was
an important factor pushing Argentina towards the liberalisation of
capital flows.
(12) Moreover, sonic authors argue that net debt may underestimate
the extent of vulnerability of Brazil's public sector because its
assets may not be as liquid as its liabilities. A more realistic
appraisal of liquidity of government assets could imply a higher level
of net debt. For a discussion of this issue, see Goldstein (2003).
(13) The Brazilian currency, the real, has lost 35 percent of its
value in 2002, while the benchmark C-bond fell from about $83 in early
2002 to the low of $49 in mid-October 2002, with spread on Brazilian
debt rising to about 2500 points.
(14) At present, the Czech Republic has no outstanding foreign
currency-denominated sovereign bond, even though there are indications
that demand for such an instrument would be high. In late 2001, Hungary
changed its borrowing strategy from borrowing in foreign currency to
borrowing in local currency, and in November 2001, it issued a heavily
oversubscribed 15-year Hungarian forint bond.
(15) Of course, it is another question whether the independent
conduct of monetary policy brings the desired results. Butter and Grafe
(2002) warn that in most accession countries, underdeveloped debt
markets will prevent monetary policy from being very effective for
stabilising output. However, local debt markets are developing rapidly,
at least in the more advanced transition countries.
(16) However, at the end of 2002 and in early 2003, Hungary faced a
different problem, increased tension between its commitment to keep
exchange rate within the [+ or -] 15 percent fluctuation band and
meeting its inflation target. For a more detailed discussion, see Jonas
and Mishkin (2003).
(17) Baer (2001) discusses some of the potential problems connected
with FDI inflows.
REFERENCES
Baer, GD. 2001: Risk and capital flows to the emerging markets.
Paper presented at the Conference organized by the Croatian National
Bank, Dubrovnik, 28-30 June 2001.
Buiter, WH, and Grafe, C. 2002: Anchor, float or abandon ship:
Exchange rate regimes for the accession economies. Paper prepared for
the 10th Anniversary Conference of the European Bank for Reconstruction
and Development, London, 13-14 December 2001.
Calvo, G and Reinhart, C. 2000: Fear of floating. NBER Working
paper no. 7993, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Catao, L and Terroned, M. 2000: Determinants of dollarization: The
banking side. IMF Working Paper no. 146, IMF: Washington, DC.
Cooper, R. 1999: Exchange rate choices. In: Little, JS and Olivei,
GP (eds). Rethinking the International Monetary System. Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston Conference Series No. 43, Boston, Massachusetts.
Edwards, S. 2001: Dollarization and economic performance: An
empirical investigation. NBER Working paper no. 8274, Cambridge,
Massachusetts.
Eichengreen, B. 1998: Toward a new international financial
architecture. Institute of international Economics: Washington, DC.
Eichengreen, B and Hausmann, R. 1999: Exchange rates and financial
fragility. NBER Working paper no. 7418, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Eichengreen, B, Hausmann, R and Panizza, U. 2002: Original Sin: The
Pain, the Mystery and the Road to Redemption, Mimeo University of
Berkeley, California.
European Bank for Reconstruction and Developments. 2002: Transition
Report 2002.
Fischer S. 2001: Exchange rate regimes: Is the bipolar view
correct? Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(2): 3-24.
Frankel, JA. 1999: No single currency regime is right for all
countries or at all times. NBER Working paper no. 7338, Cambridge,
Massachusetts.
Goldstein, M. 2002: Managed floating plus and the great currency
regime debate. Paper presented at the IMF Institute Economics Training
Seminar, January 2002, Washington, DC.
Goldstein, M. 2005: Debt sustainability, Brazil and the IMF.
Institute of International Economics, Working Paper 03-1, Washington,
DC.
International Monetary Fund, 1999: International capital markets:
Developments, prospects and policy issues. IMF: Washington, DC, Chapter
III.
International Monetary Fund. 2002: World Economic Outlook, April
Chapter 2.
Jonas, J and Mishkin, FS. 2003: Inflation targeting in transition
economies: Experience and prospects. Paper presented at the NBER
Inflation Targeting Conference, Bal Harbor, FL, 21-23 January 2003.
Larrain, F and Velasco, A. 2001: Exchange rate policy in emerging
markets: The case for floating. Paper presented at the Conference
"When is a National Currency a Luxury?" London Business
School, 16-17 March 2001, London.
Lipschitz, L, Lane, T and Mourmouras, A. 2002: Capital flows to
transition economies: Master or servant? IMF Working paper no. 11, IMF:
Washington, DC.
Lucas, R. 1990: Why doesn't capital flow from rich to poor
countries? American Economic Review 80(2): 92-96.
Masson, P. 2001: Exchange rate regime transitions. Journal of
Development Economics 64:571-86
Mishkin, F. 1996: Understanding financial crises: A developing
country perspective. NBER Working paper no. 5600, Cambridge,
Massachusetts.
Mussa, M. 2002: Argentina and the Fund: From triumph to tragedy.
Institute for International Economics: Washington, DC.
Pou, P. 1999: Is globalization really to blame? In: Little, JS and
Olivei, GP (eds). Rethinking the International Monetary System. Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston, Conference Series No. 43, Boston, Massachusetts.
Roubini, N. 2001: The case against currency boards: Debunking 10
myths about the benefits of currency boards. See
http://www.stern.nyu.edu/globalmacro/CurrencyBoardsRoubini.html.
JIRI JONAS (1)
International Monetary Fund, Office 11-302, 700 19th Street NW,
Washington, DC 20431, USA. E-mail:
[email protected]