Adopting the euro: an introduction to four country studies.
Watson, C. Maxwell
INTRODUCTION
Country by country; issue by issue ... The four studies that
follow--in which authors from Croatia, Estonia, Hungary and Poland
discuss the adoption of the euro in their economies--could carry this
common caption. The question they address is one of the most momentous
in the post-transition economic history of their countries: abandoning
monetary autonomy in the interests of ever fuller integration in the
European Union economy.
It is an issue that some studies have dealt with in generic terms
across the region. By contrast, the particular merit of the studies
presented here is that--while sharing many elements of a common analytic
framework--they probe issues which the authors identify as particularly
germane in their own economy.
How important is the fiscal issue in Hungary, and what lessons
emerge from financial markets' recent judgments on this? Does de
facto euroisation tilt the balance of the arguments, down the road, for
Croatia? Could overheating be a worry even with Estonia's balanced
budget and flexible labour market? Are cyclical risks in Poland
significant, and how do they measure against long-run gains from
adopting the euro? These are among the issues that these authors come to
grips with in their analyses.
Three of these countries will, of course, join the European Union
in May 2004, and for them, in principle, the adoption of the euro is not
a choice but an obligation. All four authors, indeed, see strong
attractions in euro area membership. But timing remains an issue. And in
arriving at their judgements on timing, they surface important
qualifications in terms of policy prerequisites to be fulfilled--and of
economic and financial risks along the road. Advocates and opponents of
early euro area membership alike will find challenging points of view,
and an encouragement to look at the issues in terms of specifics not
generalities ...
COSTS OF ABANDONING MONETARY AUTONOMY
The Optimal Currency Area (OCA) literature is a natural starting
point, as these authors weigh the costs of losing monetary autonomy
against long-run gains from euro adoption. They all touch on the issues
of asymmetric shocks and real sector adjustment mechanisms, which are of
key importance where national monetary autonomy has been surrendered.
They note on the favourable side the extent of existing integration with
the euro area--and the likelihood of a further, endogenous increase
after joining monetary union. But they also surface some significant
qualifications on these real sector issues:
* Ross and Lattemae report a strong positive correlation between
shocks affecting Estonia and the euro area--as well as high flexibility
in the labour market and the real economy generally. This leads them to
view the costs of euro adoption--in OCA terms--as not really relevant
for Estonia. But they warn against overestimating the degree of
integration of the new members as a group with the euro area, noting
differences among their economies.
* Vujcic recalls that business cycle analyses have typically been
static, and based on limited data--qualifying their relevance to the
future. Indeed, he points out, the ECB's current monetary policy
would hardly meet Croatia's needs at a time of buoyant economic
activity and rapid credit growth. Borowski, meanwhile, notes that for
Poland intra-industry trade--which would underpin the durability of
business cycle convergence--is still relatively modest.
* Borowski also mentions that the amplitude of business cycles has
been much wider in Poland than in the euro area--raising a question
whether the stance of the ECB would be adequate to address such swings.
His study concludes that there would indeed be a likelihood of wider
output swings, but that this involves relatively modest costs for the
Polish economy.
* The studies on Croatia, Hungary and Poland consider their
national labour markets to be less flexible than could be desired,
reflecting mainly rigidities in wage bargaining--and this injects a
cautionary note as regards the smoothness of real economy adjustment
under the euro.
The balance of these considerations is reflected in the
authors' overall judgements on real sector factors. If the
counterfactual of existing constraints on monetary policy were ignored,
then all the studies except that on Estonia would see distinct costs in
abandoning monetary autonomy in terms of exposure to shocks, the risks
of wider output swings, or labour market rigidities.
This said, the four countries' present exchange regimes and
environments substantially affect the authors' assessments of
opportunity cost. The studies on Estonia and Croatia underscore existing
constraints on policy:
* Ross and Lattemae consider that, given the present CBA arrangement, there would be no opportunity costs in adopting the euro:
the economy has already adjusted to a rigid regime.
* Vujcic reports that, in Croatia, the high degree of euroisation
leaves monetary policy heavily circumscribed. Exchange rate fluctuations
have major effects on corporate balance sheets, and thus on banks--who
have transformed currency into credit risk. From a stability
perspective, large prudential overheads result; and the required high
level of banks' liquid exchange reserves leads to wide spreads. The
chance to reduce these costs is argued to support strongly the case for
early euroisation--real sector rigidities notwithstanding.
In the case of Estonia, Ross and Lattemae's arguments on real
sector flexibility--and the adaptation of the economy to a rigid
regime--are clearly of fundamental importance. In Croatia, monetary
policy is not claimed by Vujcic to be wholly immobilised, however: it is
circumscribed to the extent that it is almost too potent. In terms of
achieving low inflation monetary policy has so far been very
effective--even if heterodox measures have at times been needed. As
regards prudential issues, these will remain crucial in all
circumstances--perhaps particularly under the hypothesis of monetary
union, when the external current account constraint transforms into a
more subtle financial sector constraint.
Turning to Hungary and Poland, the existing regimes are obviously
very different from Estonia and Croatia. They enjoy substantial and full
exchange rate flexibility, respectively, under their present frameworks.
However, the two studies diverge in assessing opportunity costs:
* The Hungarian study expresses concern that moving from the
present wide band towards and into ERM2 could increase existing risks of
volatility in capital flows. Csermely sees a risk that markets might
abruptly re-evaluate fiscal policy in a country, leading to exchange
rate pressures. She would favour moving quickly into ERM2, in order to
tap the long-run benefits of euro adoption, if credible fiscal
consolidation could be assured--and she also mentions in this connection
the importance of commitment to a sound financial system. But absent
firm policy resolve, she sees if anything a case for shifting in the
opposite direction--to a free float.
* The study on Poland takes a different and more pessimistic view
of floating. It sees the exchange rate flexibility of the present
inflation targeting regime as a source of instability, particularly
given an alleged need for more time to build the credibility of monetary
policy. In Borowski's view, Poland has low opportunity costs in
losing monetary autonomy--despite rigidities in the labour market and
some concerns about output swings. Moving to adopt the euro would, in
his view, enhance stability by cutting short the process of credibility.
The balance of Borowski's arguments on this point is
challengeable. Many observers would see fiscal tensions as contributing
substantially to instability--and share the view of Csermely that such
tensions argue for a flexible exchange rate. One can argue that the
situation should engender fear of fiscal tensions more than fear of
floating! Meanwhile, Csermely's view of the euro--as something of a
safe haven in a volatile world--is one that needs to be considered more
fully, below, in connection with the evolving financial market
environment.
RISK PREMIA, CAPITAL FLOWS AND THE FINANCIAL SECTOR
All the studies anticipate that euro adoption would trigger further
declines in risk premia. This would reflect elimination of currency risk
and improved liquidity. It would reflect the mitigation of external
current account risks both in a mechanical sense, under monetary union,
and in the more fundamental sense of reducing country risk as monetary
autonomy is abandoned and fiscal policy-makers commit to the Stability
and Growth Pact.
Borowski analyses the impact of lower risk premia on output in
Poland. This is indeed the main driver of his conclusion about the
long-run net gains from adopting the euro. He suggests a total long-run
output gain, illustratively, of perhaps 4-14 percent of GDP. Within
this, the long-run impact of transactions cost savings is put at only
some 0.3 percent of GDP. All of the remaining impact is attributed to
interest rate/risk premia effects. Borowski concludes, however, with an
important word of caution: 'It must be remembered ... that
potential costs of the euro adoption in Poland may be incurred shortly
after the EMU accession, whereas it would take decades for the benefits
to fully accrue. Hence, the euro is a project which seems appealing to
long-distance runners, rather than those for whom the choice between
waiting or being impatient rarely tilts towards the former.' This
raise en garde appears wholly justified.
The other authors also expect that a decline in risk premia will
further stimulate the inflow of capital--increasing available savings.
However, Ross and Lattemae point out the need for vigilance as regards
financial stability. The credibility-enhancing effects of EH accession
are 'vast' for the candidate countries, they note, and this
may result in overly optimistic market expectations concerning economic
growth and the rate of return on invested assets--bringing about changes
in the structure and volume of capital flows or in resource allocation in the economy. The latter, they are concerned, could lead to
'outright overheating' or 'an uneasy mix of
policies.'
Csermely, too, discusses capital market exuberance. In Hungary, she
suggests, markets have tended to overestimate policy-makers' fiscal
resolve. Hence strong capital inflows may be punctuated by sharp
reversals. But if fiscal policy is robust, then, as already noted, she
urges taking the risks of a leap into ERM2, in order to reach the shore
of the euro-safe haven. Two elements in Csermely's prescription
need to be separated out, however: awareness of the policy and market
rigours of the passage up to and through ERM2; and confidence that euro
area membership will shield the economy to some extent from financial
market vicissitudes.
On this second point, one should enter a word of caution.
Eliminating the exchange rate thermometer does not entail immunity
against economic fever. To an important extent, the capital market
variability that concerns Csermely and the other authors relates to
fluctuating perceptions of domestic risk. These fluctuations will not
disappear when the euro is adopted. Rather, risks will be transformed.
Over time, the premium demanded by market participants will continue to
fluctuate--as will capital inflows--reflecting both policy fundamentals
and market imperfections such as bubbles and overshooting.
When explicit variability in the exchange rate ceases, the risk
premium may well decline initially in a response, as these studies
assume. But as real activity then accelerates, the path of the risk
premium--and of the real exchange rate--over the medium term is harder
to foresee. There is a strong possibility that capital inflows, together
with rapidly growing domestic credit, could lead over the medium term to
substantial appreciation of the implicit real effective exchange rate.
If that occurred, and left the implicit rate misaligned under monetary
union, then the unwinding of this through price and wage adjustment
(given asymmetries in wage flexibility) could lead to an extended period
of slow growth.
This perspective highlights the fact that the existence of a risk
premium in the acceding countries is not inherently problematic. To a
degree, it can exert a dampening influence on the inflow of capital--in
conditions where the high real returns available might otherwise lead to
a pace of capital inflow that would exacerbate risks of overheating. In
sum, caution is needed in featuring the early adoption of the euro as a
form of safe haven in a world of high real returns, fluctuating risk
premia, and perfectly mobile capital. To the extent there is protection
to be found in this capital market setting, it is for the most part more
basic--lying in efforts to achieve a benign policy mix and to foster
increased flexibility in the real economy.
Ross and Lattemae have an important message, in other words, when
they note the potential for exuberant market expectations in connection
with EU accession, with the credibility of policy regimes such as
Estonia's, and also with euro area membership in the future. This
financial market setting is one of the major challenges they see on the
road ahead, and it leads them to urge the importance of fostering
domestic saving, strengthening the financial sector, and continuing to
enhance real sector flexibility in the economies where this is needed.
MEETING THE MAASTRICHT CRITERIA
The arguments discussed so far relate to the benefits and costs of
early euro adoption. But some of the authors also discuss the
feasibility of this, in terms of meeting the Maastricht Criteria. On the
positive side, they cite impressive achievements to date in containing
fiscal imbalances and reducing inflation.
On the more cautious side, they note three issues:
* First, there is an inherent tension in reconciling nominal
exchange rate stability with the impact of productivity differentials on
consumer prices (the Balassa-Samuelson effect). Ross and Lattemae
consider that this has the potential to be an important issue--even
though the magnitude of the effect was likely overstated in some early
analyses, which did not distinguish other transition-related price
adjustments. On the one hand, they stress that rapid productivity growth
is a sign of economic strength, not weakness. On the other hand, they
wonder out loud how credibility would be affected, respectively, by
meeting the criterion due to cyclical good luck, or by policy
creativity--or alternatively delaying adoption of the euro, or
temporarily slowing real convergence. Overall, they view meeting the
formal rules of the euro club as a major issue on the road ahead. (One
should also bear in mind that heavy inflows--or strong price convergence
influences--could lead to a relative rate of CPI increase/real
appreciation that is larger than the magnitude of the strict
Balassa-Samuelson effect.)
* A second issue is fiscal discipline. Csermely cautions that the
last few years witnessed a less disciplined fiscal policy in Hungary,
which set back the disinflation calendar. It remains to be established
that current consolidation plans will be successfully carried
through--'a major uncertainty to meeting the Maastricht criteria on
time.' Vujcic observes that Croatia has made important progress
with fiscal consolidation, though he acknowledges some inevitable
uncertainty about the future. Ross and Lattemae note Estonia's very
strong fiscal track record, which has kept it 'well within the
intellectual framework of the Stability and Growth Pact.'
* A third issue relates to the interest rate criterion, where Ross
and Lattemae observe that there are no domestic rates fulfilling the
required maturity band, given the absence of a government bond market in
Estonia; but this does not appear to them a fundamental problem.
Csermely notes the strong performance, over time, of Hungarian
government bonds.
A fiscal question that does not surface directly in these studies
is a more normative one. Csermely, and also Ross and Lattemae, note that
over the past decade there was no conflict between real and nominal
convergence. Indeed, fiscal consolidation and disinflation were good for
growth. But the papers do not ask about the opportunity costs of meeting
the Maastricht fiscal criterion at an early date, and going on to
achieve a position close to balance under the Stability and Growth Pact.
Given expenditure pressures in areas such as infrastructure, and the
level of taxes on labour income in some countries, this deserves serious
study.
CHALLENGES AND TENSIONS
Should the scale tilt--in Borowski's phrase--toward waiting or
towards impatience? These papers contribute in a lively and candid
manner to the debate. Inevitably, their conclusions differ--sometimes
reflecting differences in economic structure, sometimes more profoundly:
* Borowski and Csermely are not in agreement, clearly, on the
extent to which flexible exchange regimes are a source of instability,
or a safety valve to help handle it, in contexts where elements of
policy credibility are not fully established. (For this commenter, it
has to be said, history sides with the latter--safety valve--view.)
* Csermely sees capital flow volatility at its worst in connection
with ERM2 entry, but then abating with the passage toward the euro. But
Ross and Lattemae warn--surely with some justification--that credible
nonflexible regimes (such as Estonia's currency board, or, by
extension, euro area membership) may actually contribute to the
emergence of overoptimism among market participants about risk-adjusted
real returns. Far from a safe haven, this would feature euro adoption as
a setting which will have financial market as well as institutional
rigours--placing strong demands on policy and on the flexibility of the
real economy.
* The stress that Ross and Lattemae lay in their study on the
fundamental importance of real sector flexibility and fiscal discipline
recall that these factors, along with financial sector robustness, must
weigh very heavily in the balance when contemplating monetary union.
This emphasis contrasts with some views in the other studies--including
the preponderant weight given to the monetary and prudential costs of
currency substitution in Vujcic's paper.
* Finally, the Estonia study takes very seriously the potential
difficulty of observing the 'rules of the game' in time for
early euro area entry, and raises a question about the credibility costs
of trying to finesse these rules, for example, by creativity in managing
the path of inflation. Where Csermely is concerned mainly about policy
assignment problems, the Estonia study sees a more fundamental tension
between real convergence, nominal convergence, and stability in the
nominal exchange rate. Thus it concludes that 'there are questions
about ... ability to fit into the club rules that cannot be
overlooked.'
These differences of perspective should stimulate further research
on the technical and policy-related dimensions of euro adoption.
Certainly, policymakers will find much to reflect on as they digest
these four different renderings of the opportunities and challenges
ahead.
C. MAXWELL WATSON
Wolfson College, University of Oxford, Linton Road, Oxford OX2 6UD,
UK. E-mail:
[email protected]