The new geography of global income inequality.
Anderson, Kathryn
The New Geography of Global Income Inequality Glenn Firebaugh
Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, 2003, 257pp.
Comparative Economic Studies (2007) 49, 326-329.
doi:10.1057/palgrave.ces.8100197
Globalisation and technological innovations in communication and
transportation promoted rapid growth and economic opportunity for many
people in the world. Some countries that stagnated in the 1970s and
1980s flourished in the 1990s, with economic growth at unprecedented
levels. The economies of many other countries stagnated in the 1990s,
and political discontent increased. The collapse of the Doha Round,
protests in the United Nations, calls for military interventions, and
the increase in support for socialist Latin American politicians are all
indicators of the economic bifurcation that we see today. In his very
careful analysis, Firebaugh addresses these sensitive issues and brings
together the most recent data, methodologies, and literature to measure
and explain the recent development of the global distribution of income.
Firebaugh's book focuses on the measurement of global income
inequality and the change in the between- and within-country components
of income inequality during the last 20 years. His work complements
recent empirical work on global income inequality by Sala-i-Martin
(2002a), Li et al. (1998), and others and the new theory of economic
geography (Fujita et al., 1999).
After reviewing the literature on global inequality in the 19th and
20th centuries, he presents new evidence on the change in inequality
since 1990. Over the last two centuries, the world experienced a large
increase in real average per capita income; on an average, people in all
regions of the world are economically better off today than they were in
the 19th and early 20th centuries. At the same time, the distribution of
income changed dramatically. Rich nations disproportionately benefited
from real income growth, and overall global inequality worsened until
the middle of the 20th century. Between-nation inequality increased and
within-nation inequality decreased during this period of time. In the
second half of the 20th century, inequality between countries stabilized
until about 1990 and declined thereafter. Within-nation inequality
increased, but Firebaugh estimates an overall improvement in global
inequality in the late 1990s. He argues that the causes of these changes
in inequality were industrialisation, the movement out of low-income
agriculture in the largest lower income nations such as China, and the
rise of the information-based economy.
Firebaugh's conclusions are dependent on whether the measure
of between-nation inequality is unweighted or weighted by population
share. The unweighted Theil index of between-nation inequality indicates
that income inequality between nations in the 1990s increased
significantly. More states of all sizes fell behind the global average
during the 1990s than rose above it. Many of the economies that did not
benefit from globalisation were in sub-Saharan Africa. If the measure of
between-national inequality is calculated using population weights--so
that inequality is estimated among persons--then he finds
between-country inequality fell in the 1990s. Asia--especially China and
India--is the region responsible for this improvement in between-country
inequality. Because of the Asia turnaround, relatively more people in
the world apparently gained than lost from globalisation. Firebaugh
estimates that if Asia had experienced the same economic trend in the
1990s as Africa, income inequality between nations would have increased
using weighted inequality measures. Because of the disparity in the
economic progress of large and small low-income countries, it is not
surprising that we see so much dissension among nations in trade
negotiations, global economic policy, and foreign affairs.
Firebaugh takes great care in the measurement of between-nation
inequality over time, and he presents a variety of robustness checks
that make his results even more compelling. He compares the trends in
three inequality measures: Theil, mean logarithmic deviation or entropy
measure, and the Gini coefficient. He uses the best and most complete
macroeconomic data available to date and presents the reader with a
clear discussion of the problems inherent in cross-country comparisons.
His preferred estimate of income is adjusted for purchasing power parity (PPP) or world prices, but for comparison he presents results using the
United Nations' Human Development Index. His basic conclusions
about the patterns of weighted and unweighted between-nation inequality
are robust to most of these measurement issues, but the sizes of the
effects (point and interval) are quite sensitive to measurement. Three
excellent chapters comprise the best, non-technical discussion I have
read on inequality measurement and are a must-read for those unfamiliar
with the concepts.
Firebaugh includes a thorough, non-technical discussion of the
possible causes of the inequality changes he has measured. His
conclusions about the role of manufacturing growth in income inequality
are supported by reason and data on relative sectoral growth between and
within countries. Although he does not model income growth formally or
use multivariate statistical analysis to measure the relative importance
of manufacturing expansion for income inequality, his descriptive
evidence is convincing. In the future, a more controlled evaluation of
the causal paths should be pursued.
The weakest part of the analysis in this book is the measurement of
within-country inequality. Firebaugh uses quintile data on income to
measure the within-country variation in income, but this approach
assumes that all persons within the quintile have the same level of
income. In a recent paper, Sala-i-Martin (2002b) estimates
country-specific income distributions using kernel density estimation,
which allows for variation in income within quintiles, and he finds
larger within-country inequality when variation within quintiles is
allowed. The general patterns over time of declining between-country
inequality and increasing within-country inequality are evident in the
quintile and kernel density estimates of inequality, but the measure of
within-country inequality is smaller in the 1990s when the quintile
estimate is used. This comparison suggests that Firebaugh's
within-country inequality and overall inequality measures may be biased
downward.
Firebaugh's estimates are also sensitive to price
assumptions--foreign exchange rates (FX) or PPP. He rejects the exchange
rate measure of national income because exchange rates value only goods
that are traded across countries and ignore the purchasing power of
untraded goods. However, PPP-adjusted inequality measures are also
biased because the standard PPP conversion as in the Penn World Tables
ignores the ability of poor consumers to substitute towards cheaper
goods and services in the local economy. Dowrick and Akmal (2005)
compare estimates of global inequality on a variety of measures in the
1990s using FX, PPP as in the Penn World Tables, and an intermediate
(Afriat) method that they label 'true income'. In comparison
to the 'true income' inequality, they find a significant
downward bias in the measures of overall inequality using PPP-adjusted
income and an upward bias in FX-adjusted inequality. They also find that
the magnitude of the substitution bias inherent in PPP increased over
time as the price structures across countries became less similar. The
Dowrick and Akmal results are not definitive but do illustrate the
problems inherent in cross-country comparisons of economic well being.
In summary, The New Geography of Global Income Inequality is an
excellent study of the global trends in income inequality. The results
are provocative and raise many questions about future economic
development. The book should be required reading for anyone interested
in the measurement of global inequality; it complements the new theories
of economic geography and recent empirical research on spatial
inequality and growth. It should be on reading lists for undergraduate
and graduate economics courses in labour and human resource economics
and economic development. I recommend it to all of my students who are
interested in the study of global inequality.
Kathryn Anderson
Vanderbilt University, Nashville, Tennessee, USA
REFERENCES
Dowrick, S and Akmal, M. 2005: Contradictory trends in global
income inequality: A tale of two biases. Review of Income and Wealth
51(2): 201-229.
Fujita, M, Krugman, P and Venables, Anthony J. 1999: The Spatial
Economy: Cities, Regions, and International Trade. The MIT Press:
Cambridge, MA.
Li, H, Squire, L and Zou, H-f. 1998: Explaining international and
intertemporal variations in income inequality. Economic Journal
108(446): 26-43.
Sala-i-Martin, X. 2002a: The "disturbing' rise off global
income inequality. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
#8904: Cambridge, MA.
Sala-i-Martin, X. 2002b: The world distribution of income
(estimated from individual country distributions). National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper #8933: Cambridge, MA.