Impact and implementation challenges of the Basel framework for emerging, developing and small economies.
Frait, Jan ; Tomsik, Vladimir
INTRODUCTION
In response to the global financial crisis, the Basel Committee on
Banking Supervision (BCBS) introduced two sets of reforms to the
international capital framework for banks. The 'Basel 2.5'
package of reforms (BCBS, 2009) included measures to strengthen the
trading book capital requirements under Basel II and enhance the three
pillars of the Basel II framework. Basel III (BCBS, 2010b) introduced
two additional capital buffers: a capital conservation buffer of 2.5%
that should be applied across the board, and a countercyclical buffer,
which should be applied during periods of high credit growth. In
addition to the level of capital, Basel III addresses the issue of its
quality through its focus on common equity. Capital loss absorption is
dealt with by the point of non-viability clause that provides relevant
authorities with discretion for a write-off or conversion to common
shares if the bank is judged to be non-viable. The capital framework was
also supplemented by a non-risk-based leverage ratio. There is also
substantial strengthening of the counterparty credit risk framework.
Most of Basel III relates to Pillar 1 measures (minimum capital
requirements), but there are also implications for Pillar 2 (further
requirements by supervisor related to risks not covered by Pillar 1) and
Pillar 3 (set of disclosure requirements). Basel III also introduced two
required liquidity ratios: the liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) and the
net stable funding ratio (NSFR).
The Basel III as well as Basel II standards are designed primarily
for large internationally operating banking institutions with a focus on
their activities in BCBS member states. They set minimum regulatory
standards and respect the need to set the overall standards in various
jurisdictions according to local conditions. Nevertheless, the Basel
standards are to a large extent reflected in the regulations in BCBS
non-member countries too. The prime focus of this paper is the impact of
Basel III changes to the capital and liquidity frameworks on emerging
market and developing economies, and specifically also on small
economies. For simplicity, we label this group as emerging market and
smaller economies (EMSEs).
The EMSEs are a rather heterogeneous group. Some of the countries
have their own currencies, some are members of currency unions, while
others utilize the currencies of other economies. Some are members of
the European Union (EU), which imposes extensive regulatory requirements
designed outside the scope of EMSEs. Furthermore, it is obvious that
jurisdictions within this group differ substantially and will continue
to do so. Despite all these differences, the EMSEs also have some common
features. Their financial markets are typically more volatile than those
of large advanced economies, as is their GDP growth, which is meanwhile
higher on average than that of advanced economies. They also typically
experience stronger credit growth because their financial sectors are in
the process of financial deepening. They usually have lower credit
ratings and shallower government bond markets, which in some cases
implies a lack of high-quality liquid assets (HQLA), a lack of adequate
collateral and so on. And they face a whole range of home-host issues,
as many globally significant financial institutions operate branches or
subsidiaries in EMSEs.
The presence of branches and subsidiaries of multinational banks is
the most important feature of EMSEs' banking sectors. Whether
multinational banks operate in a particular jurisdiction as a branch or
subsidiary creates striking differences. Nevertheless, as Mayes and
Granlund (2008) explain, both ways will inevitably pose problems for the
regulatory and supervisory authorities in both home and host countries.
(1) As to the choice of a multinational bank regarding preferred
organizational form, Cerutti et al. (2007) find that banks are more
likely to operate as branches in countries that have higher taxes and
lower regulatory restrictions on bank entry and on foreign branches.
Subsidiary operations are preferred by banks seeking to penetrate host
markets by establishing large retail operations. These findings are to a
large extent confirmed by Fiechter et al. (2011). They conclude that
banks with significant wholesale operations tend to prefer a more
centralized branch model that provides them the flexibility to manage
liquidity and credit risks globally and to serve the needs of large
clients. The funding costs for the wholesale group are likely to be
lower under the branch structure, given the flexibility to move funds to
where they are most needed. A subsidiary structure, in contrast,
constrains the banking group's ability to transfer funds across
borders and hence may be less suitable for wholesale activities.
However, they also find that, given the diversity of business lines and
the varying objectives and stages of financial development of different
countries, there is no one obvious structure that is best suited to all
cases for cross-border expansion.
EMSEs are impacted by the Basel III framework in three ways. First,
there is an indirect impact of the implementation of the framework at
the consolidated level by jurisdictions that are home to international
banks. This involves increased cross-border cooperation challenges, and
it is all the more important for countries who are hosts to branches or
subsidiaries that may represent a small fraction of the consolidated
group but are locally systemic. Second, there is the indirect impact of
the reactions of international banks to implementation. In this case,
there is the concern that as international banks change their business
and deleverage, their exposures to EMSEs might be unduly reduced.
Finally, there is the direct impact on EMSEs of implementing the Basel
III framework in their own jurisdictions. There are many papers and
studies looking at the economic effects and impacts of the Basel III
framework in advanced economies using macroeconomic models (see the
section 'Basel III, regulatory capital and its quality'). The
implied changes in volumes and prices of credit constitute the driving
forces in these approaches. In contrast, studies focusing on more
detailed effects stemming from changes in individual regulatory
parameters often specific to emerging and small economies are scarce.
This paper intends to provide a contribution in this direction.
The structure of the paper is as follows. The next section surveys
the analyses on the economic effects of the Basel III framework and the
potential consequences of new capital regulations in EMSEs. The section
after that considers the issues associated with the introduction of
macroprudential capital buffers. The following section discusses the
implications of new regulation of banks' trading exposures for
affiliates of multinational banks. The subsequent section turns
attention to the sensitive issue of regulatory treatment of sovereign
exposure from both the micro- and the macroprudential perspective. The
next section explains potential risks associated with the accelerated
move of the EMSEs' banks to advanced approaches to modelling
financial risks. The penultimate section describes impacts of the new
liquidity framework while the final section concludes.
Before proceeding to these topics, let us note that we agree on the
importance and adequacy of most of the changes that are contained in
Basel III. However, we deliberately focus mainly on challenges and
risks, especially on the identification of possible unintended
consequences of the new rules. This is not to say that the unintended
consequences prevail over the intended ones. Furthermore, not all the
issues discussed here are related directly to Basel III, and not all the
unintended consequences are specific exclusively to the EMSE countries.
Many of the proposed rules were discussed long before the establishment
of the new regulatory framework. However, the creation of the new
framework gives new relevance to these issues and consequences.
BASEL III, REGULATORY CAPITAL AND ITS QUALITY
The changes in the capital framework that constitute the core of
Basel III are just one, though the most important, component of the
post-crisis regulatory overhaul. These changes concern not only the
traditional part of banking regulation, capital requirements for
covering risks faced by the individual institutions that stand at the
centre of the Basel II accord. Basel III also contains parts of the new
economic policies labelled 'macroprudential policy' that are
designed to prevent or mitigate risks of a systemic nature. This
reflects recognition that liberalized financial markets have created a
favourable environment for endogenous 'boom and bust' cycles.
The new framework thus takes into account both micro- and
macroprudential concerns and struggles to achieve robustness as a key to
avoiding financial sector vulnerability. For a bank-based system,
robustness will be achieved via a high loss absorbency capacity, strong
liquidity and brakes on credit booms. Loss absorption should cover
potential losses through sufficient provisions against loan impairment,
through capital cushions, and cyclical losses through countercyclical
capital buffers. There should also be a cross-section risk component
consisting of capital add-ons for systemically important institutions.
Strong liquidity is essential for limiting the fragility of liabilities.
Impact studies of Basel III were naturally a part of its
preparation. The focus was mostly on the estimates of macroeconomic
effects in advanced economies. BCBS has advocated Basel III on the basis
of the Long-Term Economic Impact (LEI) Report (BCBS, 2010c), which
focuses on the long-term effects while ignoring transitional costs. The
study admits the higher cost of external finance (higher lending rates),
nevertheless, the overall balance of cost and benefits is rather
positive up to a 15% of capital adequacy ratio. This result is mainly
because of the high perceived benefits of a reduced probability of a
financial crisis. BCBS has also arranged for a study of transitional
effects of Basel III implementation by the MAG (Macroeconomic Assessment
Group). This study (MAG, 2010) assumed that banks face higher costs when
funding assets by capital than by deposits or by debt. The initial
effect of Basel III introduction is an increase in lending rates.
However, in the long run the banks get less risky, the costs of funding
go downwards, lending rates decline and supply of credit is restored.
The result is that in the short run the costs are low and in the long
run they disappear. When new liquidity requirements are added, the costs
go a bit further, but the overall picture is not affected. This positive
view of the long-term effects has been confirmed by Angelini et al.
(2011), Slovik and Cournede (2011), Kashyap et al. (2010), Miles et al.
(2011) and Admati et al. (2011).
Even though the impact studies and estimates of the effects were
targeted at the advanced economies, they should hold for the EMSEs as
well. In addition, the short-term negative effects on lending rates
could be even lower here than in advanced economies since most EMSEs
will not have great difficulties in complying with the new definition of
capital in Basel III. This is because the banks in EMSEs generally
maintain capital levels in excess of internationally agreed regulatory
minimums and their capital base is typically dominated by common shares
and retained earnings (labelled Core Tier 1, CT1; or Common Equity Tier
1, CET1). Nevertheless, there may be several implementation challenges.
First of all, implementation of Basel III will generate a need for some
capital replenishment. Reasons for this include: (i) banks in EMSEs
inevitably need to issue additional capital given their relatively fast
economic growth and the pivotal role played by banks; (ii) higher
minimum regulatory capital requirements at the international level will
likely lead banks in EMSEs to build up capital to maintain buffers
against a relatively higher degree of macroeconomic and market
volatility; and (iii) internationally active banks often use the
sovereign credit rating of the host jurisdiction as the credit ceiling
or the risk floor for all the exposures incurred by their subsidiaries.
EMSEs with lower credit ratings could thus find their banking
system with higher capital levels than in advanced economies, regardless
of whether banks in the latter are more exposed to other systemic risks.
The eligibility criteria for Tier 1 (common equity, retained
earnings, reserves, non-redeemable preferred stock and other capital not
secured by the issuer) and Tier 2 (hybrid instruments and subordinated
debt) may turn out to be non-trivial. This applies in particular to the
requirement that all these instruments have a 'point of
non-viability clause', that is, all regulatory capital instruments
should be able to absorb losses in the event that the issuing bank
reaches a point of non-viability. In addition, once the clause is
triggered, supervisors may face potential governance issues when
conversion brings in shareholders that may not be appropriate. More
broadly, the change of ownership structure may have implications for the
viability of the institution going forward. It should be expected that
the supervisor has the authority to replace management or to require
some other change in management deemed necessary to ensure that the
institution operates in a prudent manner. Basel III establishes a
requirement that the terms of capital instruments must allow, at the
option of the regulatory authority, for them to be written off or
converted into common shares in the event that a bank is unable to
support itself in the private market in the absence of such conversions.
During the recent financial crisis, some troubled banks never reached
the insolvency point where the subordinated instruments would have
performed as capital because governments provided support to avoid the
liquidation of these banks. It is clear that, if such support had not
been provided, these banks would have failed and subordinated creditors
would have received payment only after all depositors and senior
creditors had been paid in full.
Basel III allows for certain debt instruments issued by banks to be
included in additional Tier 1 and Tier 2 capital, subject to a set of
inclusion criteria. Such policy will inevitably create a bias against
those banks that are constrained by their market experience and
credibility and thus face higher costs in issuing capital. As EMSEs
generally lack local infrastructure to facilitate the issuing of
structured capital instruments in domestic markets, local banks are
faced with difficult, if not impossible, challenges to raise less costly
capital. In addition, Basel III allows the instruments issued by
subsidiaries to be included in the consolidated group's capital
where the pre-specified trigger event is linked to the non-viability
condition determined by both home and host authorities. In practice,
there is a tendency for the internationally active banks to include
their subsidiaries' issuance in the group's capital as these
banks manage their risks and maximize their expected risk-adjusted
returns by consolidating the group-wide assets and liabilities.
Therefore, an immediate consequence of such policy is the potential for
complications if the non-viability conditions determined by the home and
host authorities are different. In addition, the possible conversion of
structured instruments issued by subsidiaries into equity may lead to
the potential dilution of shareholder holdings of both subsidiaries and
their parent banks if the issuance is included in the group's
capital, which will add to both supervision and management
complications. All these potential complications will make capital
issuance by subsidiaries a less desirable choice for both bank managers
and investors.
Basel III also requires the banks to deduct from their common
equity capital most of their assets with weaker loss-absorbing features
such as minority interests, goodwill and deferred tax assets, as well as
some investments or rights. In general, the use of innovative capital
instruments and Tier 2 instruments is limited and most of the capital is
composed of CET1 and reserves. While overall goodwill is the largest
element of deductions for advanced economies, for emerging countries
that participate in the quantitative impact study, the deduction of
deferred tax assets seems to weight relatively more. In part, this may
be because of provisioning and accounting legal frameworks;
forward-looking provisions, for instance, frequently are not recognized
by tax authorities and create deferred tax assets. For example, the
deduction of deferred tax assets proposed by Basel III seems to weigh
relatively more in EMSEs than in advanced economies. This may be partly
because of provisioning and accounting legal frameworks, for example,
forward-looking provisions frequently are not recognized by tax
authorities and generate deferred tax assets. The World Bank (2013)
estimates that the share of assets with less loss-absorbing
characteristics to be deducted from CT1 capital is relatively small on
average for banks in emerging and developing economies, except in the
Latin America and Caribbean region. The proportion of CT1 capital to be
deducted nevertheless varies greatly across banks. If applied
immediately, the deductions combined with market risk adjustments (Basel
2.5 and trading exposures) would lower the CT1 ratio by about 1-3
percentage points on average. The overall impact on the CT1 ratio is the
largest for Latin America, the Middle East and North Africa, and Europe
and Central Asia.
Difficulties associated with the deductions and eligibility
criteria for Tier 1 and Tier 2 instruments under Basel III may create
pressure on EMSEs to implement changes to their legal frameworks. In the
case of the eligibility criteria for Tier 1 and Tier 2 instruments, the
national legal and regulatory frameworks should be consistent to ensure
that the non-viability clause is effective. While the criteria driving
the trigger for conversions or write-offs can in principle be set out a
priori in broad terms, allowing for better pricing of the instruments
and helping to reduce market uncertainty and the legal risk to
supervisors, the decision as to whether a bank can continue on its own
will ultimately always be a judgement call. As a result, supervisors
need to be given sufficient powers to be able to make such decisions.
EMSEs may also need to take actions to cultivate domestic markets
for the issuance of structured capital instruments, including: (i)
having in place legal and institutional arrangements to enable the
issuance of Basel III-recognized capital instruments; (ii) defining a
priori criteria for the triggering of the point of non-viability, which
may help boost market confidence and acceptance for issuance of
structural capital instruments; (iii) having an enabling tax environment
where the capital instruments issued by banks are typically
tax-deductible and are not subject to withholding tax; and (iv)
designing the terms of capital instruments to make such instruments
suitable for a broad range of investors. If foreign bank subsidiaries
operating in EMSEs issue capital, and this is included in the
consolidated group's capital, authorities may need to impose
certain regulatory requirements to avoid capital being used to cover
losses of parent banks while simultaneously harming the confidence in
the stability of subsidiaries. Enhanced communication between home and
host regulators needs to be encouraged and should cover, among other
issues, regular information sharing about the performance of related
parent banks and subsidiaries and related resolution plans.
MACROPRUDENTIAL CAPITAL BUFFERS
The supervisory powers to implement the mandatory capital
conservation and countercyclical buffers (CCyBs) will be essential to
ensure effective implementation of Basel III. The values of the buffers
themselves may not present any particular difficulties for EMSEs. The
supervisory powers to implement these buffers may be more problematic.
With the capital conservation and counter-cyclical buffers in place, the
restrictions on the distribution of profits in cases of non-compliance
with these capital buffers should be automatic and imposed on banks
through requirements set forth by national legislation. The buffers
cannot function as desired if the supervisor does not have sufficient
power to restrict the distribution of profits, or if authorities do not
have the will to activate the various triggers. Many countries are still
struggling to create such powers for their regulators. In many EMSEs
that have not yet implemented Pillar 2 of Basel II, the development of
supervisory judgement that is crucial for Basel II and Basel III may be
lacking. In addition, there are complex issues related to the
interaction of these buffers, other additional buffers and Pillar 2. For
instance, several countries already include additional Pillar 2 capital
requirements for banks that are considered systemically important or to
cover idiosyncratic risks. Authorities will need to consider whether
these Pillar 2 charges overlap with the Basel III buffers. Supervisors
need to assess whether the Pillar 2 add-ons could safely be drawn down
in times of crisis. If this is not the case, such add-ons should be
considered a minimum requirement for the bank.
Similar issues arise when discussing the calibration of the CCyB.
The actual implementation of a CCyB in countries with underdeveloped
credit markets seems to be more complex than what was proposed by the
BCBS; finding the right indicators of systemic risk and establishing a
framework to calculate the adequate levels of CCyB countries is still a
work in progress (Drehmann et ai, 2010). In many EMSEs, it may not be
adequate to mechanistically apply the recommended methodology by
measuring excessive growth on the basis of deviations from the actual
approximation of the long-term trend of credit relative to GDP. (2) The
framework allows flexibility for supervisors to use judgement in
defining other indicators, and the BCBS has published principles that
can be used to assist supervisors to identify the build-up of systemic
risk (BCBS, 2010a). EMSEs have often been well ahead in terms of
applying macroprudential logic in their policies (Hahm et al, 2012;
Moreno, 2011). Some had already implemented countercyclical and other
macroprudential measures such as loan-to-value ratio on mortgage loans,
debt-to-income ratio on credit cards and personal loans, and
countercyclical provisioning, and now are working on how these measures
will interact with the buffer and what their cumulative effect might be.
Changes in the CCyB in EMSEs may also precipitate capital flows. As the
volume of liquidity in a domestic banking sector is reduced because of
the introduction of the CCyB, the result could be excessive liquidity
outflows to other parts of the financial system, including to financial
markets abroad. Even though the potential size of the flows induced by
the CCyB itself may be limited, in combination with swings in monetary
policy the effect could be sizeable.
In setting the CCyB and other macroprudential tools, the
supervisors should use the flexibility provided by the framework to use
judgement and/or undertake a comprehensive analysis to improve the
understanding of credit cycles rather than mechanically relying on
credit to GDP de-trending. The principal task is for them to make their
own informed judgements about the equilibrium or sustainable level of
credit in the economy. Subsequently, a set of forward-looking indicators
providing information on the possible materialization of systemic risk
resulting from currently emerging financial imbalances has to be
employed for a thorough assessment. The CCyB may help the authorities to
lean against the expansionary phase of the cycle by raising the cost of
credit and therefore slowing down lending if they conclude that the
stock of credit has grown to excessive levels relative to the
benchmarks. Nevertheless, this potentially moderating effect on the
expansionary phase of the credit cycle should be viewed as a positive
side benefit rather than as the primary aim of the CCyB regime. The
quantitative impact of the CCyB per se may be rather weak during a
credit boom. Its major contribution is to help maintain the flow of
credit in the economy when the broader financial system experiences
distress after a credit boom and to assist in ensuring a smooth landing
for both the banking sector and the real economy. No single policy tool
used in isolation can tame credit booms. Therefore, other
macroprudential tools, including as sector-specific ones, that could be
used to enhance banks' resilience to credit booms should explicitly
be set out in Basel standards.
BASEL 2.5 AND TRADING EXPOSURES
The capital requirements of Basel 2.5 were set to increase the
resilience of banks against market risk in their trading books through a
significant increase in the respective capital charge (BCBS, 2009). BCBS
indicated that market risk capital requirements associated with Basel
2.5 will increase by an estimated average of three- to four-fold for
large internationally active banks. (3) As regards EMSEs, two issues
should be highlighted. The criteria for estimating risk-weighted assets
(RWA) for exposures of local subsidiaries in host countries are decided
by parent banks and home country supervisors. Global banks manage their
risks and estimate RWA by consolidating all their subsidiaries'
assets and liabilities at their parent bank. Hence, assets held by
subsidiaries result in capital charges for the group as a whole. The
highest credit quality risk for a host country local bank, domestic
sovereign debt, could be transformed through the process of balance
sheet consolidation into a parent bank's foreign sovereign risk
exposure. A foreign sovereign risk exposure denominated in foreign
currency is often assigned a much higher RWA than a domestic sovereign
exposure denominated and financed in local currency.
Basel 2.5 thus produces significant increases in the RWA for
trading exposures in the financial markets of EMSEs because they usually
have greater volatility and lower global credit ratings. The report by
the Regional Consultative Group for the Americas (FSB, 2014) asserts
that capital requirements for some countries' sovereign bonds may
increase as much as sixteen-fold as a consequence of Basel 2.5. This may
thus exacerbate global banks' costs of trading exposures to EMSEs
when domestic risk exposures are transformed into foreign ones
particularly when global credit ratings are used. This increase in RWA
takes place even when the sovereign positions are registered in the
books of subsidiaries established in the same country that issues the
sovereign debt and the sovereign debt is denominated and funded in the
currency of the issuing country. Higher capital charges will also be
particularly significant for sovereign domestic debt held by large
subsidiaries of global banks because their risk positions may increase
the capital requirements for concentration risks. The effect will be the
increase in the cost of holding sovereign debt, especially in emerging
market economies in which global banks have a material presence. In some
cases this could accelerate the deleveraging process of global banks
from overseas exposures. (4)
Basel 2.5 through its impact on the RWA for trading exposures may
thus harm liquidity and create a less level playing field in the
financial markets of EMSEs. Basel 2.5 could have a negative impact on
liquidity in local financial markets through the increases in the
trading book RWA of the local subsidiaries of foreign banks for their
risk exposures in local sovereign debt. These increases would also
discourage banks from taking advantage of arbitrage opportunities in
local financial markets, decreasing their efficiency. This issue is very
important for the development of efficient financial markets in EMSEs
where global banks and their local subsidiaries are an important source
of liquidity. The requirements associated with Basel 2.5 would also
promote arbitrage between the trading and banking books. In particular,
banks could wish to move risk exposures from the trading to the banking
book as RWA for same risk exposures could be much higher when registered
in the former than in the latter (Pepe, 2013). While all exposures in
the trading book must be valued at market prices, banking book exposures
can be valued at amortized cost. Hence, this shift of exposures,
particularly of securities, from the trading to the banking book
decreases the transparency of banks' financial situation.
In some EMSEs, as well as in advanced economies, the implementation
of the credit valuation adjustment (CVA) risk charge is still under
consideration. The CVA capital charge computes the amount required to
cover the losses arising from marking to market the counterparty risk of
banks' OTC derivative portfolios. BCBS observed that two-thirds of
credit risk losses suffered by banks during the financial crisis in 2008
arose from CVA losses rather than actual defaults. (5) Strong industry
pushback and fears from corporate and pension funds that their business
costs would increase have caused regulators to create exceptions (EU
framework includes exemptions of CVA risk to trades with corporates,
sovereigns and pension funds) or postpone their decision.
In order to deal with the challenges of implementing the Basel 2.5
and III capital framework, international regulators should consider
issuing specific guidance for the appropriate use of local and global
credit ratings and the risk assessment of sovereign exposures
(denominated and funded in local currencies) in foreign subsidiaries.
When consolidating parent banks and subsidiaries' balance sheets
and assigning RWAs, guidance is needed on practices regarding the risk
weighting, at the consolidated level, of foreign subsidiaries' risk
exposures--both the currency denomination of assets/liabilities and the
legal differences between a parent bank's assets/liabilities in an
overseas branch from those of a subsidiary should be taken into account.
In addition, the regulators should re-evaluate the circumstances in
which it may be appropriate to deduct an entity from regulatory capital
rather than consolidate its exposures. The latter can be particularly
important for structurally separated entities that are systemically
important and have limited intra-group exposures.
BASEL III AND SOVEREIGN EXPOSURES
The recommendations of the previous section should not be viewed as
a call for general acceptance of zero or close to zero risk weights for
sovereign exposures. There is a case for a reconsideration of current
capital treatment of sovereign debt and for making the framework
globally more consistent instead. The Basel III framework continues to
provide preferential treatment of sovereign exposures denominated and
funded in domestic currencies. All sovereign exposures of this sort are
allowed, at national discretion, to keep the same risk weight regardless
of their ratings. Such treatment stems from the unique and central role
of government bonds in modern financial systems. These are generally
regarded as risk-free (ie, highly liquid, high-quality, HQLA) assets,
thanks mainly to the high credibility of the state as issuer and the
high quantity of debt issued. However, the preferential treatment brings
a risk of reinforcing the links between sovereign and banking sector
stresses, as became apparent in the recent global financial crisis,
especially the crisis of the euro area. In addition, as jurisdictions
may exercise national discretion to assign a zero-risk weight for
domestic sovereign exposures under the new capital and liquidity
frameworks, there could be further incentives for banks to hold domestic
sovereign exposures.
The build-up of sovereign exposures on the balance sheet of banks
beyond some point may become a relevant concern for authorities in
EMSEs. In line with the development of domestic capital markets,
sovereign debt in EMSEs is increasingly being funded in domestic
currencies. However, domestic bond markets in a number of EMSEs are
still under development, thus limiting the ability of banks to diversify
their assets. This poses several challenges, including for the
implementation of the LCR (see the section 'The Basel III liquidity
framework'). Addressing banks' sovereign exposures is
particularly pertinent for those EMSEs whose economies are dollarized,
are members of currency blocks and/or issue a significant number of
sovereign bonds denominated in foreign currency.
The approaches of international banks to recognizing sovereign risk
differ (FSB, 2014). Some banks that apply the standardized approach use
global ratings to calculate risk-weighted assets. Other banks using
internal risk-based (IRB) models do not take into account whether the
sovereign exposure is denominated and funded in local currency. As a
consequence, international banks may give asymmetric treatment to
comparable risks based on the entity in which the asset was booked. As
explained in the previous section, home countries' and host
countries' sovereign exposures thus may not always receive similar
treatment. In the process of balance sheet consolidation, host country
sovereign exposures often lose their place in the local lowest
risk-weight category, while home country sovereigns maintain it. This
creates inconsistencies when the credit quality of a given counterparty
is evaluated both by the subsidiary and by the parent office. Applying
different treatment to sovereign exposures booked in overseas
subsidiaries creates a home country bias and makes the playing field in
host countries less level.
Several principles can guide the approach aimed at limiting
excessive accumulation of sovereign exposures spurred by market and
regulatory incentives. While the authorities must recognize that banks
have legitimate motivations to hold sovereign exposures on a relatively
large scale, the approach needs to: (i) differentiate among types of
sovereign debt held by banks; (ii) be tailored to country-specific
circumstances; (iii) consider potential unintended consequences; and
(iv) be supported and informed by a robust analytical framework.
A potential menu of approaches to address sovereign risk build-up
includes: (i) sovereign risk capital buffers, such as incremental
capital charges on sovereign exposures under Pillar 1 or concentration
charges under Pillar 2; (ii) more robust and consistent
cross-jurisdictional application of the Pillar 2 supervisory review
process to address risks associated with excessive concentration; (iii)
a limit on the size of sovereign debt exposures, possibly as a
percentage of total assets or capital; and (iv) supply-side measures to
promote sovereign risk diversification, such as vehicles or funds for
sovereigns to collectively pool liabilities, as well as initiatives
aimed at developing domestic and regional bond markets. The authorities
in individual jurisdictions should not apply the measures to sovereign
exposures unilaterally, unless these are identified as a significant
threat to financial stability. The changes to regulatory treatment of
sovereign exposures should preferably be considered and adopted on a
globally consistent basis.
The international regulators should study differences in the
implementation of the Basel framework for international banks and
consider developing guidance in order to achieve consistent
implementation of capital standards, and avoid arbitrage and asymmetric
treatment of similar exposures. Consolidation practices and home country
regulation should avoid a home country bias: sovereign exposures
denominated and funded in local currency at overseas subsidiaries should
receive the same treatment applied by head offices to sovereign
exposures of the home country sovereign denominated in their domestic
currencies and funded locally. At the same time, mechanistic use of CRA
global sovereign ratings should be discouraged.
ADVANCED APPROACHES TO MODELLING FINANCIAL RISKS
One of the potential consequences of the move towards higher
capital requirements of Basel III is that banks in EMSEs could move to
the IRB approaches without being ready and respond to higher capital
requirements by not revealing and recognizing all potential risks
associated with their balance sheets. The higher requirements may create
an incentive for banks to move to the use of the more advanced risk
measurement techniques of Basel II in the hope of saving on capital by
achieving lower implicit risk weights with the same balance sheets. (6)
This would create pressure on supervisors to approve such practices even
if a bank is not ready (eg by citing reputational concerns). Similarly,
some banks may change their stringent approach to provisioning in a way
that would lead to the creation of lower provisions relative to expected
losses. Such a possibility is given by the diverse accounting approaches
across jurisdictions and also by the discretion in applying the
accounting rules (see Bikker and Metzemakers, 2005; Angklomkliew et al,
2009; Packer and Zhu, 2012). Both directions could put somewhat
arbitrary cushions against expected and unexpected losses. In addition,
an incorrect or manipulative use of IRB methods and accounting rules
could weaken consistency and comparability due to excessive variation in
risk measurement without better management of the underlying risks.
There is a need to guard against the risk of banks moving in haste
to the IRB approach under improper incentives. The IRB approaches, if
applied inappropriately, may enable banks to manipulate their RWA
numbers to lower risk weights. Only the gradual development of
risk-sensitive approaches to regulatory capital calculations and risk
management can lead to better risk capture and adequate preparation by
both banks and supervisors to address possible future challenges with
building internal models. Authorities have to take a conservative and
prudent view on reviewing and approving IRB applications by banks. Host
supervisors should actively verify and approve the models developed by
parent banks, taking into account the specific features of the host
country market. The supervisors need to be able to validate highly
technical mathematical models as well as to find a right balance of
models with qualitative features of the IRB approach.
The relevance of concerns regarding manipulation with risk weights
has been confirmed in advanced economies. In recent years, bank equity
analysts have frequently remarked on the difficulty of understanding
differences in risk-weighted assets and coverage of impaired assets by
provisions both across banks and through time. The BCBS (2013b) study on
the regulatory consistency of risk-weighted assets in the banking book
drawing on supervisory data from more than 100 major banks found that up
to three quarters of the considerable variation across banks in average
RWAs for credit risk in the banking book is consistent with the spirit
of the risk-based capital framework, that is, it can be explained by
differences in the composition of banks' assets. The rest of the
variation is, however, driven by diversity in banks and supervisory
practices. Some of this stems from supervisory choices at the national
level, due either to discretion permitted under the Basel framework or
deviation in national implementation from Basel standards. The
differences in practices also result from banks' choices under the
IRB framework, that is, varying IRB approaches used by banks,
conservative adjustments to IRB parameter estimates and differences in
banks' modelling choices. In some cases, variations may also
reflect differences in interpretation of the Basel framework.
Therefore, priorities for progressive movement to more
sophisticated approaches within the Basel framework (eg IRB approaches)
should be established. Supervisory authorities should ensure robustness,
reliability and transparency of prudential outcomes from the adoption of
Basel standards, including the Core Principles for Effective Banking
Supervision (Basel Core Principles). In this context, Pillar 3 should be
seen as a tool for meeting the needs of investors and counterparties.
Decisions on the pace of the implementation would need to consider
particular characteristics of banks and banking systems, as well as
supervisory constraints. For example, some countries have considered the
adoption of a more rules-based approach to Pillar 2 requirements as a
way forward in the presence of legal frameworks that significantly limit
supervisory powers. When considering the capital framework for smaller
and less sophisticated banks, authorities should be aware that Basel
standards are designed primarily for large international banks. However,
when the majority of the banking sector is owned by these large
institutions, supervisory authorities in EMSEs should build
relationships with the home authorities of their largest banks and, upon
agreement with the home authority, participate in relevant discussions
on model validation within supervisory colleges.
In addition to proper calculation of risk-weighted assets,
transparent and consistent accounting is crucially important for the
robustness of prudential outcomes, even though it is not directly linked
to the Basel standards. The recent financial crisis highlighted that
having provisions commensurate with expected losses is one of the
building blocks of resilience of the banking sector in particular.
Provisioning is important not only because the provisions serve as a
buffer against expected loan losses, but also because they provide
significant information on how banks price credit risk. There are
significant differences across jurisdictions as to the factual approach
to provisioning. The desired state is that all banks regulated in line
with Basel standards use the International Financial Reporting Standards
(IFRS). This is not the case now, even though significant progress has
been made in this area. Nevertheless, even such a state would not
guarantee adequate provisioning for asset impairment. Further
improvements in the IFRS that would limit, among other things, existing
procyclicality, are crucially needed (Frait and Komarkova, 2013).
THE BASEL III LIQUIDITY FRAMEWORK
Basel III is the first accord that attempts to set a comprehensive
quantitative framework for regulating the banks' liquidity (BCBS,
2010d). The LCR is designed to improve banks' resilience to
short-term liquidity shocks through holding a reserve of HQLA. The NSFR
should ensure that long-term assets are funded primarily by long-term,
stable funding. Previously, national practices and experiences of
liquidity requirements differed. Nevertheless, many countries, including
some EMSEs, had developed approaches based on the concept of banks
holding stocks of liquid assets to withstand stressed periods (for
examples, see CGFS, 2010).
Implementation of the new liquidity framework will be challenging
for some EMSEs. Different macroeconomic and financial environments in
these countries, such as the lack of availability of diversified HQLAs,
the higher share of foreign currency-denominated banking assets and
liabilities, and unique characteristics of depositors, would pose
specific challenges for implementing the LCR appropriately. In
jurisdictions with limited availability of HQLAs, concentration risk,
particularly to sovereign debt (a 'Level 1' asset), can easily
emerge. The LCR requires banks to hold a diversified portfolio of HQLA
that can be liquidated in a stress event to cover the outflow of
liabilities, but the room for diversification will be limited in many
EMSEs with limited access to other HQLA than sovereign debt.
Furthermore, yields on HQLAs will typically be lower than other
securities, implying a cost to banks' profit margins. Greater use
of 'Level 2' HQLA, which are less traded in the markets, such
as corporate debt, by banks could introduce greater volatility in market
risk and increase exposure to credit risk.
Expanding the supply of HQLA through the alternative treatment in
the framework would address the problem, at least partially. The LCR
framework provides three options to address an insufficient supply of
'Alternative Liquid Asset' (ALA) treatment, with different
pros and cons. The first option is to use a contractual committed
liquidity facility (CLF) provided by the central bank. (7) This option
has the advantage of avoiding incentives for banks to change their asset
portfolios. However, calibration is challenging as it must balance the
potential for banks' overreliance on the facility with making the
cost of the CLF unduly prohibitive. Central banks must be able to honour
a CLF commitment and consider carefully how such a facility would affect
monetary policy operations. Foreign currency HQLA, Option 2, can be a
practical solution when banks already hold substantial numbers of such
assets, but a premium must be placed on strong management of foreign
exchange risk. A strong currency risk control framework, including
quantitative regulatory requirements such as net foreign open position
limits, should be a pre-requisite. Types of eligible assets need to be
limited and haircuts must be conservative, based on historical
experiences during stressed periods. Additional use of lower-quality
HQLA (Level 2) with a higher haircut, Option 3, may be viable when
sovereign debt is scarce but capital markets are well developed.
Although this option enables banks to diversify away from sovereign
bonds and alleviate pressures from their prices, the true liquidity
profile of such Level 2 assets, particularly during times of stress,
needs to be assessed and conservative haircuts must be set. Furthermore,
supervisors must guard against Level 2 assets crowding out Level 1
assets for higher yields the former typically have.
Introducing new instruments that are included in HQLA is a further
option. An option considered by some advanced economies is the covered
bond, which provided a stable source of funding during the recent
crisis.
However, risks must be carefully assessed when introducing new
instruments. For example, covered bonds encumber assets, potentially
prejudicing depositors and unsecured creditors in the event of
resolution; mitigation would be to set limits on total asset encumbrance
or covered bond issuance. (8)
For some EMSEs, the LCR may increase foreign currency risk if banks
meet LCR shortfalls in domestic currency with foreign currency assets.
Currency convertibility in the LCR framework for dollarized countries
needs further guidance. It is questionable, for example, whether it is
prudent to allow surplus in dollar LCR to cover a shortfall LCR in the
domestic currency and vice versa. Furthermore, while Basel III does not
require the LCR to be met currency by currency, monitoring and reporting
of relevant currencies forms part of the LCR framework and banks may
feel under pressure to meet the LCR in all individual currencies, thus
increasing demand for foreign currency HQLA. This may in turn affect the
price and availability of such assets.
Banks in EMSEs generally rely heavily on deposits for funding,
putting a premium on applying appropriate run-off rates to deposits. (9)
While this funding pattern broadly reduces the HQLA requirement, close
attention needs to be paid to the breakdown of deposits to ensure that
low run-off rates are suitable and reflect local conditions. This means
not only must the authorities set run-off factors that are appropriate
in their jurisdiction but they also must be satisfied that banks are
capable of distinguishing correctly between different types of deposit
liability, taking account of followings. Probabilities of funding
run-off in some countries could differ substantially from those assumed
in the LCR framework. Typical examples could be smaller jurisdictions
where non-resident deposits or cross-border mobility of deposits is a
major feature. This heightens the need for national discretion in EMSEs
in calibrating run-off rates for certain types of liability. The
applicable run-off rates for deposits range from 3% to 100% depending on
the stability of the deposit's characteristics, making it vital for
banks to categorize funding accurately to generate a meaningful LCR
figure. A bank must have systems that can distinguish the relevant
criteria in its deposit base, such as identifying retail and small
business deposits, tracking insured deposits from uninsured funds and
distinguishing operational deposits from other wholesale deposits. Where
supervisors doubt the banks' operational and systems capabilities,
they should impose more conservative definitions and assumptions.
Enhanced liquidity requirements could affect the way international
banking groups hold liquid reserves in their different levels of group
structures (CGFS, 2010). There are concerns among authorities of EMSEs
that the availability of group-level liquidity to foreign subsidiaries,
including deposits placed by them to parent banks, would be affected by
the implementation of the LCR. These authorities are also worried that
the efforts by home supervisors to improve those groups'
resolvability, including the preparation of recovery and resolution
plans as well as application of structural measures on bank activities,
could result in banks 'compartmentalizing' their different
operations, which may weaken the ownership chain and the availability of
group liquidity and capital support.
The LCR implementation demands careful planning and dedicated
resources. Transition to the LCR, which is relatively more sophisticated
than most existing Basel methodologies, could pose a substantial
challenge for many countries. Authorities in these jurisdictions may
wish to consider the following issues when implementing liquidity
standards. Jurisdictions must determine the scope of LCR coverage. For
internationally active banks in BCBS member jurisdictions, the LCR is
mandatory. For the more advanced banks in EMSEs where a similar
methodology already exists, there is considerable value in implementing
the LCR and applying it to banks that have material cross-border
activities. For jurisdictions where an LCR-like rule does not exist and
cross-border activities are minimal, the aim should be to move to the
LCR framework gradually to give banks time to improve their capacity.
During this transition, consideration should be given as to whether the
LCR parameters are sufficiently stringent or need to be tightened as
appropriate to the local context.
Jurisdictions must also assess national discretions and ALA options
in the context of their own systems. A first step is to understand the
availability and characteristics of liquid assets and the liquidity
characteristics of banks' sources of funding. The pros and cons of
the ALA options must be carefully assessed. The flexibility the LCR
framework offers in terms of the ALA and national discretions should
enable an orderly transition based on careful consideration of
quantitative impact study (QIS) information and stringent application of
criteria for ALA treatment. Nevertheless, the Basel framework provides
stringent criteria and processes for jurisdictions to be qualified for
the ALA treatment, including periodic self-assessment and independent
peer review. EMSEs should strive to adhere to these as much as possible.
It is advisable for supervisors to monitor the LCR by currency
irrespective of the importance of foreign currency in banks'
balance sheets. Such information allows the supervisor to identify any
potential currency mismatches and to consider the liquidity risk in
foreign currencies. A QIS is needed to design the LCR appropriately for
EMSEs. The QIS must provide granular data, such as numbers of different
types of HQLA that banks hold, or banks ability to categorize deposits
based on their stability. Fluent two-way communication mechanisms with
the banks, such as workshops, are recommended to ensure that banks
understand the standard, and authorities understand the banks'
capacities so that adjustments to local standards, criteria, haircuts
and run-off rates can be made where appropriate.
Further guidance by the regulators will be important to ease
transition for EMSEs. Areas for further guidance include: the use of
ALAs in countries with less developed capital markets, the treatment of
currency convertibility in the LCR framework for dollarized economies
and the exercise of national discretion in applying run-off rates for
deposits. The regulators should further encourage home supervisors to
reach understandings with international banking groups and host
supervisors on group-wide liquidity management. Absent such
understandings, including on the provision of centrally held liquidity
to subsidiaries and branches, host supervisors may be compelled to
require subsidiaries and branches to retain minimum liquidity at the
local level to protect their national financial stability. (10) More
generally, the international regulators should place a stronger emphasis
on consolidated supervision by the home supervisor while maintaining
close communication with the host supervisor, and encourage a wider
sense of continuing responsibility for group-wide banking operations.
Market-wide solutions like those adopted in the EU should be explored
and could help home supervisors avoid retrenching and becoming more
inward-looking. In addition, more flexible treatment of deposits placed
by foreign subsidiaries should be allowed to reflect the nature of the
underlying depositors, which would reflect the reality of the business
model of these foreign subsidiaries and support the continued
diversification of funding.
CONCLUSIONS
In this paper we have discussed the impact of changes to the
capital and liquidity frameworks brought about by the Basel III accord
on emerging market, developing and small economies (EMSEs). Even though
we believe that Basel III will deliver significant benefits over the
longer time horizon, our intention was to identify challenges, potential
unintended consequences of the new rules and their adverse economic
effects. Some of them are associated with the presence of branches and
subsidiaries of multinational banks in EMSEs' banking sectors, and
resulting home-host relations and conflicts.
We surveyed the analyses on the macroeconomic effects of Basel III
framework and potential consequences of new capital and liquidity
regulations, as well as issues associated with the introduction of
macroprudential capital buffers. As to the specific areas, we looked at
implications of new regulation of banks' exposures in trading book,
regulatory treatment of sovereign exposures and potential risks
associated with an accelerated move to advanced approaches to modelling
financial risks.
We identified several key areas of concern for both banks and
regulators. Potentially most pressing are increases in risk-weighted
assets for exposures in trading books located at foreign affiliates of
multinational banks. The effect will be the increase in the cost of
holding sovereign debt, especially in emerging market economies, which
could lead to partial deleveraging of global banks from overseas
exposures. To mitigate such risks, both national and international
regulators should promote consistent application of rules in various
parts of multinational banks, especially the ones regarding local
sovereign exposures denominated and funded in local currency, and assess
the methods of consolidation practices regarding the risk weighting of
foreign subsidiaries' exposures.
The challenges may also be generated by the need for capital
replenishments and required capital deductions, especially in
jurisdictions with weaker governance and less developed financial
markets. The condition that regulatory capital instruments should be
able to absorb losses in the event that the issuing bank reaches a point
of non-viability may create governance issues, for example, when
conversion brings in shareholders that may not be suitable. Coping with
these issues requires strengthening legal and institutional arrangements
to enable smoother issuance of capital instruments, and also
encouragement of the provision of adequate supervisory powers.
Enhanced liquidity requirements may run against limited
availability of truly liquid assets that at the same time are of high
quality in a number of jurisdictions. In such jurisdictions,
concentration risk, particularly to sovereign debt, deemed both liquid
and of high quality, can easily emerge. The new regulation could also
encourage groups to hold liquid reserves at the parent level. However,
it may not always be clear when and how these reserves should be made
available, while deposits placed at a parent bank by foreign
subsidiaries could become subject to bail-in arrangements. The
implementation of liquidity standards thus demands careful planning and
proper assessment of alternative sources of high-quality liquid assets
in the context of concrete jurisdictions. If such assets are sought
abroad, special attention will have to be paid to currency mismatches
and liquidity risk in foreign currencies.
Overall, when transitioning away from Basel I, EMSEs could usefully
take into account some guiding principles. Capital requirements are only
one part of a good supervisory framework. First, the effective
implementation of the regulatory framework for capital definition,
buffers and disclosures depends on sufficient powers and resources. In
this sense, countries that have successfully implemented Pillar 2 and
Pillar 3 of the Basel II framework would be better placed to implement
Basel III as well. Compliance with Basel Core Principles for Effective
Banking Supervision (BCP) should be a priority for all countries,
advanced or developing. A lack of supervisory powers, capacity and
independence in supervision is a greater hurdle to safe banking systems
and effective supervision than solvency alone. Second, a progressive
movement towards implementing elements of Basel II and III could be
beneficial - these represent a higher level of requirements for both
banks' risk management and supervisors' review. Implementation
planning should start by building capacity to manage the process
effectively. Decisions on the pace of the implementation would need to
consider particular characteristics of banks and banking systems, as
well as supervisory constraints. Some countries have considered the
adoption of a more rules-based approach to Pillar 2 requirements as the
way forward in legal frameworks where interpretation powers of
supervisors may be limited. Third, there are elements of Basel III that
could be implemented in Basel 1 countries, even if Basel II has not been
implemented. While some requirements of Basel III regarding the
denominator of the capital adequacy ratio are directly linked to the
Basel II securitization framework, the enhanced definition of capital,
the buffers and enhanced disclosures could be introduced without Pillar
1 of Basel II as a prerequisite. Ensuring that the capital base is of
good quality and market discipline is functioning should be a
supervisory goal independent of the capital regime adopted.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank Rudy Araujo, Pascual
O'Dogherty, Karl Cordewener, Ju Quan Tan, Jong Ku Kang, Tae Soo
Kang, Samsiah Yunus, Lixing Zhang, Bryan Stirewalt, Michaela Erbenova,
Christopher Wilson, Alejandro Lopez Mejia, John Aspden and Jan Kubicek.
They note that the paper represents their own views and not necessarily
those of the Czech National Bank. All errors and omissions remain
entirely the fault of the authors. Part of the research behind this
paper was supported by the Grant Agency of the Czech Republic within
Project No. 13-08549S. The paper reflects the discussions of the
workstream analytical and research group set up by the Basel
Consultative Group of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision.
REFERENCES
Admati, A, DeMarzo, P, Hellwig, M and Pfleiderer, P. 2011:
Fallacies, irrelevant facts, and myths in the discussion of capital
regulation: Why bank equity is not expensive. Stanford Graduate School
of Business research paper no. 2065, Palo Alto, CA.
Aiyar, S and Jain-Chandra, S. 2012: The domestic credit supply
response to international bank deleveraging: Is Asia different? IMF
working paper 12/258, International Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
Angelini, P, Clerc, L, Curdia, V, Gambacorta, L, Gerali, A,
Locarno, A, Motto, R, Roeger, W, Van den Heuvel, S and Vlcek, J. 2011:
BASEL III: Long-term impact on economic performance and fluctuations.
BIS working papers no. 338, Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
Angklomkliew, S, George, J and Packer, F.. 2009: Issues and
developments in loan loss provisioning: The case of Asia. BIS Quarterly
Review, Bank for International Settlements, Basel, http://www.bis
.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt0912h.pdf.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2009: Guidelines for
computing capital for incremental risk in the trading book. Bank for
International Settlements: Basel.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2010a: Guidance for
national authorities operating the countercyclical buffer. Bank for
International Settlements: Basel.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2010b: Basel III: A global
regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems. Bank
for International Settlements: Basel.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2010c: An assessment of the
long-term impact of stronger capital and liquidity requirements. (LEI
Report), Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2010d: Basel III:
International framework for liquidity risk measurement, standards and
monitoring. Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2013a: Report on the
regulatory consistency of risk-weighted assets for market risk. Bank for
International Settlements: Basel.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2013b: Report on the
regulatory consistency of risk-weighted assets in the banking book. Bank
for International Settlements: Basel.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2013c: The regulatory
framework: Balancing risk sensitivity, simplicity and comparability. BIS
discussion paper, Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
Bikker, J and Metzemakers, P. 2005: Bank provisioning behaviour and
procyclicality. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions
and Money 15(2): 141-157.
Calzolari, G and Loranth, G. 2001: On the regulation of
multinational banks. Rivista di Politico Economica 91(4): 275-304.
Calzolari, G and Loranth, G. 2005: Regulation of multinational
banks: A theoretical inquiry. ECB working paper series no. 431, European
Central Bank: Frankfurt am Main.
Cerutti, E, Dell'Ariccia, G and Perfa, MSM. 2007: How banks go
abroad: Branches or subsidiaries? Journal of Banking and Finance 31 (6):
1669-1692.
CGFS. 2010: Funding patterns and liquidity management of
internationally active banks, Committee on the Global Financial System
papers no. 39, Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
De Haas, R and Van Lelyveld, I. 2014: Multinational banks and the
global financial crisis: Weathering the perfect storm? EBRD working
paper no. 135, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development: London.
Drehmann, M, Borio, C, Gambacorta, L, Jimenez, G and Trucharte, C.
2010: Countercyclical capital buffers: Exploring options. BIS working
papers no. 317, Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
European Banking Authority. 2013: Summary report on comparability
and pro-cyclicality of the IRB approach. EBA Report, European Banking
Authority: London.
Feyen, E, Kibuuka, K and Oetker-Robe, I. 2012: European bank
deleveraging: Implications for emerging market countries. World Bank
economic premise, no. 79, World Bank: Washington DC.
Fiechter, J, Otker-Robe, I, Ilyina, A, Hsu, M., Santos, A and
Surti, J. 2011: Subsidiaries or branches: Does one aize fit all? IMF
staff discussion paper, International Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
Financial Stability Board. 2014: Regional consultative group for
the Americas report on the effect on host countries of balance sheet
consolidation and risk management practices by global banks. Financial
Stability Board, Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
Frait, J and Komarkova, Z. 2013: Loan loss provisioning in selected
European banking sectors: Do banks really behave in a procyclical way?
Czech Journal of Economics and Finance 63 (4): 308-326.
Gersl, A and Seidler, J. 2011: Excessive credit growth as an
indicator of financial (in)stability and its use in macroprudential
policy. Financial stability report 2010/2011, Czech National Bank:
Prague.
Hahm, JH, Mishkin, F, Shin, HS and Shin, K. 2012: Macroprudential
policies in open emerging economies. NBER working paper no. 17780,
National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA.
Herman, K and Rai, K. 2010: The global credit crunch and foreign
banks' lending to emerging markets: Why did Latin America fare
better? IMF working paper 10/102, International Monetary Fund:
Washington DC.
Kashyap, A, Stein, J and Hanson, S. 2010: An analysis of the impact
of 'substantially heightened' capital requirements on large
financial institutions. Working paper, Harvard Business School, Boston,
MA.
MAG. 2010: Assessing the macroeconomic impact of the transition to
stronger capital and liquidity requirements, Macroeconomic Assessment
Group established by Financial Stability Board and the Basel Committee
on Banking Supervision, Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
Mayes, D and Granlund, P. 2008: Polar approaches to regulating
cross-border banking: Nordic and antipodean routes to financial
stability. European Business Organization Law Review 9(01): 63-95.
Miles, D, Yang, J and Marcheggiano, G. 2011: Optimal bank capital.
External MPC Unit discussion paper no. 31, Bank of England: London.
Moreno, R. 2011: Policymaking from a 'macroprudential'
perspective in emerging market economies. BIS working paper no. 336,
Bank for International Settlements: Basel.
Packer, F and Zhu, H. 2012: Loan loss provisioning practices of
Asian banks. BIS working paper no. 375, Bank for International
Settlements: Basel.
Pepe, G. 2013: Basel 2.5: Potential benefits and unintended
consequences. Questioni di Economia e Finanza no 154, Banca
D'Italia: Rome.
Slovik, P and Cournede, B. 2011: Macroeconomic impact of Basel III.
OECD economics department working papers no. 844, Organization for
Economic Co-operation and Development: Paris.
World Bank. 2013: Global Financial Development Report 2013:
Rethinking the role of the state in finance. Box 2.5 Impact of the Basel
III Implementation in Developing Economies. World Bank: Washington DC.
(1) The issues regarding the functioning and regulation of
multinational banks are discussed in Calzolari and Loranth (2001). How
regulatory intervention depends on the liability structure and insurance
arrangements for non-local depositors is investigated in Calzolari and
Loranth (2005).
(2) See, for example, Gersl and Seidler (2011). The BCBS itself
pointed out that aggregate private sector credit-to-GDP gap might not be
a good indicator for all jurisdictions (BCBS, 2010a).
(3) Press release from 10 June 2010 'Adjustments to the Basel
II market risk framework announced by the Basel Committee'.
(4) The issue of deleveraging is covered, for example, in Aiyar and
Jain-Chandra (2012), Feyen et al. (2012) and Herman and Rai (2010).
(5) 'During the financial crisis, however, roughly two-thirds
of losses attributed to counter-party credit risk were due to CVA losses
and only about one-third were due to actual defaults', Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision, Press release, 1 June 2011.
(6) Such risk has been studied intensively by regulatory
authorities in recent years. (See, eg, BCBS, 2013a, 2013b, 2013c; EBA,
2013).
(7) Australia and South Africa have introduced this option.
(8) Covered bonds have been introduced in countries such as
Australia, Belgium and Italy, among others.
(9) For example, banks in Malaysia, the Philippines and Saudi
Arabia enjoy very high levels of deposits, over 80% of their total
funding.
(10) There is some evidence that during the last crisis, parent
institutions were not, in a number of cases, a particular source of
strength for their affiliates (De Haas and Van Lelyveld, 2014).
JAN FRAIT [1,2] & VLADIMIR TOMSIK [2,3]
[1] University of Finance and Administration, Estonska 500, Prague,
CZ 10100, Czech Republic. E-mail:
[email protected]
[2] Czech National Bank, Na Prikope 28, Prague, CZ 11503, Czech
Republic. E-mail:
[email protected]
[3] Newton College, Rasinova 2, Brno, CZ 50200, Czech Republic.